Select Committee on Education and Skills Fifth Report


3  Expenditure and efficiency

29. The whole question of the effectiveness of the Government's efficiency programme arising from the Gershon review is one that we have also examined before. We have expressed concerns about the extent to which the £4.3 billion efficiency savings which the Department is working towards will be able to be reused elsewhere or, alternatively, will allow for a lower level of spending, and about the extent to which it will be possible to verify savings.[18]

30. In a report earlier this year, the NAO shed more light on the process throughout Government. It explained that the Gershon savings are both "cashable and non-cashable gains". Cashable gains consist of reductions in inputs which do not adversely affect the quality of outputs. Non-cashable gains arise where the quality of outputs increases while inputs remain the same.[19] In its reply to the Committee's previous report on public expenditure, the DfES said:

"Our efficiency initiatives are not about taking money away from the frontline, rather they are about helping the frontline to realise maximum outcomes from the resource it is allocated. As our efficiency programme stems, in the main, from initiatives designed to improve the quality of provision, we are confident that the realisation of our efficiency target will in turn improve outcomes for children and learners."[20]

31. In evidence, both the Permanent Secretary and the Secretary of State told us that all of the £4.3 billion Gershon savings, which does not include savings arising from the restructuring of the Department and the reduction in the number of staff, were non-cashable savings.[21] We noted that the DAR also describes savings as recyclable and non-recyclable, and queried whether this meant the same as cashable and non-cashable. In response, the Department sent us a helpful note:

"The Department has drawn an important distinction between cashable, where the resource freed up is money, and recyclable, where the resource freed up is productive time, to exemplify how the programme is making a difference to the frontline.

"The definitions of the terms as they are used in the Department are as follows:

  • Cashable efficiencies release financial resources whilst maintaining outputs and output quality, thereby enabling the resources that are released to be diverted to other services;
  • Non-cashable efficiency gains occur when productivity or output quality increases, either for the same resource inputs or a proportionately smaller increase in resource inputs in a way that does not release financial resources that can be deployed elsewhere;
  • Recyclable efficiencies release resource (although not necessarily financial) whilst maintaining output quality, thereby enabling the resources that are released to be diverted to other services. Clearly if the resource released is not financial it can only be diverted within the system it has been released e.g. teachers time freed up within a school; and
  • Non-recyclable efficiency gains occur when output quality or quantity increases either without reductions in resources or with a proportionately smaller increase in resource inputs in a way that does not release resources that can be deployed elsewhere.

"This means, for instance, that better procurement practices represent a cashable gain as the same products are being bought at reduced costs thereby liberating cash that can be redeployed elsewhere. However, teacher time saved in schools through workforce reform represents a non-cashable efficiency gain as teacher time rather than actual money is freed up and thereby available to be redeployed. This therefore represents a recyclable gain. Reducing drop-out rates in higher education represents a non-cashable and non-recyclable gain as successfully reducing drop out rates increases course completion rates for no extra cost but clearly will not free up any money or time resources for redistribution elsewhere."[22]

32. Taking this explanation with those offered in oral evidence it appears therefore that the DfES expects to make no cash savings through these efficiency gains, but does expect that about 75% of these non-cashable gains will be recyclable, for example allowing the more effective use of teachers' time. We welcome these recyclable gains, but we do have doubts about whether quantifying them in cash terms is in any way helpful. Money is not being redeployed elsewhere, and it is a moot point the extent to which the gain which accrues from a teaching assistant or other non-teaching staff member taking on tasks previously undertaken by teachers, and thereby freeing teachers' time for preparation or teaching, can be given a monetary value. This does not seem to be money as it is normally understood, and once again draws the DfES, and Government more widely, into arguments about what the numbers mean, rather than putting the focus on the matter in hand, namely the quality of educational provision.

33. This leads us back to another question that we have addressed previously, the measurement of productivity in education.[23] The Chairman of the Committee wrote to the Office for National Statistics to ask the nation's official statisticians about the best existing measures of education productivity. The response indicated that a definitive way of calculating that productivity is some way off:

"Productivity analysis is very complex and it is difficult for any estimate of productivity to fully capture all the outputs from education spending, but there are some obvious alternatives based on attainment output which are being considered".[24]

34. The ONS told us that there would be a consultation exercise beginning in September this year looking at both issues in education productivity and methodological issues more generally.[25] It cautioned, however, that "Measurement of the productivity of the public services is not simple and once the consultation period is complete there will be many issues to decide."[26] It appears, therefore, that there is no prospect of any resolution of these problems in the near future. In the meantime, the arguments over how effective extra investment is in terms of educational outcomes, and over the extent to which measuring efficiency savings in money terms is meaningful, will continue.

35. Given the increased level of investment that this Government has made in education, it is unfortunate that it has not yet proved possible to measure the effectiveness of that spending in providing better education and more highly qualified students. This is not to say that the investment was ineffective; but in productivity terms, we simply do not have the data to tell us one way or the other. There is a risk, in the longer term, that the inability to demonstrate a measurable link between inputs and outputs will mean that taxpayers have no way of judging whether or not public resources are being well used. Such an outcome would be bad for taxpayers and, potentially, could undermine the electorate's willingness to fund public services.


18   Education and Skills Committee, Second Report, Session 2005-06, Public Expenditure on Education and Skills, HC 479, paras 26-35. Back

19   National Audit Office, Progress in improving government efficiency, HC 802-I, 2005-06, February 2006, p 4. Back

20   Public Expenditure on Education and Skills: Government Response to the Committee's Second Report of 2005-06, HC 1132, 25 May 2006. Back

21   Q 65; Q 137 Back

22   Ev 51 Back

23   Education and Skills Committee, Second Report, Session 2005-06, Public Expenditure on Education and Skills, HC 479, para 5. Back

24   Ev 72 Back

25   ONS announced the consultation on 18 September. Back

26   Ev 72 Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2006
Prepared 26 October 2006