Select Committee on Education and Skills Written Evidence


Memorandum submitted by the Institute for Fiscal Studies

1.  OVERALL TRENDS IN EDUCATION EXPENDITURE

Compared to other areas of public expenditure

  The real average annual rates at which the six main areas of public expenditure—including education—have increased over time are shown in Table 1. Since Labour came to power in 1997, there have been large real increases in education spending (4.8% a year); but perhaps surprisingly this has been only the fourth fastest broad area of spending growth, after spending on the NHS (6.1% a year), Transport (5.1% a year) and Public order and Safety (4.9% a year). Education received much smaller average annual increases during the 18 years of Conservative governments from 1979-1997 (1.5%).

  Education spending, along with the other components shown in Table 1 (with the notable exception of defence) has grown much more quickly over Labour's second parliament than over its first (largely due to slow growth in the first two years of the first parliament, when the inherited spending plans were adhered to, but also due to a significant under-spend by government departments in 1999-2000).

  Table 1 also shows the real increases in public spending implied by the plans set out in the Government's 2004 Spending Review. Under these plans, spending on education would continue to grow as a share of national income, but less quickly than the average increases seen since April 1997.

As a proportion of GDP

  Since its lowest point for at least 20 years in 1999-2000 (at 4.4% of GDP), education spending has grown rapidly as a share of national income, and in 2004-05 stood at 5.4%. This share is comparable to that last seen in the early 1980s and well above the average between 1977-78 and 2004-05 of 4.95%. By 2007-08, the share is projected to reach 5.6%. Training expenditure accounts for approximately a further 0.2% of GDP (see Figure 1).

International comparisons

  The UK spent a higher share of national income on education than Japan, Italy and Germany, but a lower share than the USA and France in 2002. (Table 2). This ranking is similar if we just consider public education spending as a proportion of GDP. UK private education spending as a proportion of GDP is lower than the USA and Japan, but higher than that of France and Italy.

Table 1

INCREASES IN VARIOUS COMPONENTS OF PUBLIC SPENDING IN THE UK



Average annual real increase in spending over:
Long-term trend
Conservative
years April 1979 to March 1997
Labour years
to date April
1997 to March
2005
Labour 1st
parliament
April 1997 to
March 2001
Labour 2nd
parliament
April 2001 to
March 2005
Labour
spending plans
April 2005 to
March 2008

Social security
3.7
3.5
2.3
1.1
3.5
1.0
NHS
3.7
3.1
6.1
5.0
7.1
7.2
Education
4.0
1.5
4.8
2.7
6.8
3.8
Defence
-0.3
-0.3
1.0
1.7
0.4
1.3
Transport
n/a
0.5
5.1
-4.9
16.2
2.5
Public order &
safety
n/a
4.1
4.9
3.2
6.6
3.1
Total spending
(TME)
2.6
1.5
3.0
1.7
4.4
3.5
Current spending
2.8
1.7
2.8
1.7
3.8
2.9
Net investment
-0.2
-4.6
13.4
-2.2
31.4
16.2
National income
2.5
2.1
2.8
3.2
2.4
2.6

Source: Education spending 1996-97 to 2007-08: Authors' calculations based on Public Expenditure Statistical Analyses 2005 Tables 1.11 and 3.2, and GDP deflators from 30 June 2005.
All other figures on this table are derived from C. Emmerson and C. Frayne, April 2005 "Public Spending", IFS Election Briefing Note http://www.ifs.org.uk/bns/05ebn2.pdf, whose sources are HM Treasury, Budget 2005. HM Treasury, Public Expenditure Statistical Analyses 2005 and previous PESAs; Office for National Statistics, Blue Book; HM Treasury Public Spending Statistics; Department of Health Annual Report; Office of Health Economics; HM Treasury, 2004 Spending Review and previous Spending Reviews.
Note that the Department for Education and Skills Departmental Report 2005 cites planned real annual average growth in education spending between 2004-05 and 2007-08 of 5.0%—this figure covers just England, rather than plans for the UK as a whole.


Figure 1


Table 2

SPENDING ON EDUCATION IN SELECTED MAJOR ECONOMIES, 2002



Total Education spending,
% GDP
Public Education Spending,
% GDP
Private Education Spending,
% GDP

Japan
4.7
3.5
1.2
Italy
4.9
4.6
0.3
Germany
5.3
4.4
0.9
UK
5.9
5.0
0.9
France
6.1
5.7
0.4
USA
7.2
5.3
1.9

Source: OECD, Education at a Glance, Paris, 2005


2.  TRENDS IN ELEMENTS OF EDUCATION EXPENDITURE IN ENGLAND

Categories of education spending compared

  Table 3 shows the real average annual growth rates of the different components of education spending between 1997 and 2005 in England, also decomposed by Labour's two terms of office. The components that saw the most rapid average growth over the entire period were the Under 5's (9%), Schools' Capital (11.9%), Schools' Other (9.7%) and Further Education (5.3%). Primary and Secondary current expenditure have seen nearer to the average growth in education spending over the entire period (4.4% and 5.1% respectively). It is noteworthy that Higher Education spending has grown by an average of only 1.2% between 1997 and 2005. Equally notable is the fact that real spending on Student Support has actually fallen by an average of 3.7% per year over the period.

  The relative priorities identified above are similar across both terms, but with significant increases in most components' growth rates for the period 2001-05 compared to 1997-2001. The only exception is Further Education, which saw very low growth in Labour's first term, but has seen substantial year on year growth of more than 10% since 2001. The 10.8% average increase in administration and inspection since 2001 is also quite striking and is probably largely due to an increase in inspection activity.

  Plans going forward to 2008 are not provided on a consistent basis by spending category and so we do not analyse them here.

Table 3

EDUCATION SPENDING GROWTH 1997-2005 BY COMPONENT IN ENGLAND


Average annual real increase in spending over:
Labour years to date April 1997 to March 2005
Labour 1st parliament April 1997 to March 2001
Labour 2nd parliament April 2001 to March 2005

Schools, current
5.7%
4.8%
6.7%
Of which:
Under 5s
9.0%
7.4%
10.7%
Primary
4.4%
3.2%
5.5%
Secondary
5.1%
3.3%
6.9%
Other
9.7%
14.3%
5.4%
Schools capital
11.9%
10.5%
13.3%
FE
5.3%
1.3%
9.5%
HE
1.2%
-2.1%
4.6%
Student Support
-3.7%
-3.9%
-3.4%
Admin &
Inspection
1.4%
-7.2%
10.8%
Total
4.8%
2.8%
6.9%

Source: Authors' calculations based on Departmental Report 2005, Department for Education and Skills, Cm 6522, London:TSO, Table 12.3
From 1999-2000, a portion of local authority administration and inspection costs is delegated to schools and is included within the school current expenditure lines. These figures in part reflect the transfer of responsibilities for early years inspection from local authorities to Ofsted. This largely explains the apparent large drop in administration and inspection expenditure between 1997 and 2001 and means that the true annual average real growth rate between 1997 and 2005 is also artificially depressed.



3.  THE BALANCE OF SPENDING PER HEAD ACROSS DIFFERENT STAGES OF EDUCATION

  Figure 2 shows the revenue funding per student in England figures published by the DfES in its departmental report. However, these only decompose education spending per student into Schools (ages 3-19), Further Education and Higher Education, making more detailed analysis of spending across the life-cycle problematic. They do show that there has been steady growth in both Further Education and Schools funding per student, with little growth, if any, in Higher Education spending per student—closing the gap between Higher and Further Education spending per student. (Note that the figures DfES provide for Higher Education spending per student include private as well as public contributions to tuition fees, whereas the other categories cover only public expenditure).

  Figure 3 shows current spending per head of the population in the Under 5's, Primary and Secondary sectors in England, as opposed to current spending per student, which would not capture the increased coverage of Under 5's provision. It shows that when Labour came to power in 1997 spending per head sloped upwards by age. However, the rapid growth in the under 5's sector, as seen in Table 3, has led to the development of a U-shaped spending pattern per head across school ages. Although the Further Education and Higher Education spending per student shown in Figure 2 are not entirely comparable to the spending per head figures in Figure 3, their values do give some further support to the idea of a U-shaped spending pattern, with the most support provided at the earliest and then the later stages of the education system.

Figure 2




(Source: Departmental Report 2005, Department for Education and Skills, Cm 6522, London:TSO, Table 12.5,12.6,12.7). Figures presented in 2003-04 prices.

Figure 3



Source: Authors' calculations based on Departmental Report 2005, Department for Education and Skills, Cm 6522, London:TSO, Table 12.3 for current education spending figures. Population figures are taken from the 2001 census (from the ONS website). Figures are presented in 2003-04 prices. For example, spending per head for the under 5's was calculated by dividing expenditure on the under 5's by the total number of three and four-year-olds in the population.

International comparisons

Table 3

SPENDING PER STUDENT ON EDUCATION BY CATEGORY


Spending per student, relative to the UK
Spending per student per unit of average income, relative to UK
Under 5's
Primary
Secondary
All tertiary
Under 5's
Primary
Secondary
All tertiary

Japan
44
119
107
99
48
122
113
105
Italy
64
140
116
74
72
150
126
80
Germany
59
88
108
93
66
94
113
100
UK
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
100
France
53
98
130
78
55
100
135
83
USA
93
156
140
174
76
122
109
139

Notes: Indices for spending per student are taken from figures that were converted into US dollars using purchasing power parities. Spending per student per unit of average income is calculated as spending per student by sector as a proportion of GDP per capita. Italy's figures only include spending on public institutions and the USA's figures only include spending on public and independent private institutions.
Source: OECD, Education at a Glance, Paris, 2005


  Table 3 shows spending per student and spending per student as a proportion of GDP per capita, relative to the UK, for selected OECD countries. It shows that the UK spends slightly more per student in the primary sector than France and Germany, but quite a lot less than Japan, Italy and the USA. In the secondary sector, the UK spends much less per student compared to other OECD countries. The UK does spend more per student in the tertiary sector relative to other European countries, in absolute terms and relative to average income. However, the biggest spender per head in the tertiary sector is the USA. The most interesting result is that in comparison with other OECD countries, the UK spends substantially more per student in the under 5's category. Moreover, the under 5's is the only category where the UK outspends the USA.

  The latest OECD data on education spending also confirms that the UK has a U-shaped spending pattern across the lifecycle. Moreover, they suggest that the UK is quite unique in its U-shaped spending pattern, spending more per student than other countries in the tertiary and pre-primary sectors, but less in the primary and secondary sectors.

4.  EARLY YEARS' EDUCATION

  The Government launched its 10-year childcare strategy in December 2004. Implementing this strategy will undoubtedly mean that the trend towards increasing expenditure on the under-5s will continue.

  The Department for Education and Skills estimates that total expenditure on education for 3- and 4-year-olds is currently around £2.7 billion per year, of which approximately £1.1 billion goes towards providing free part-time nursery places.[14] We have estimated that the 10-year strategy could approximately double the annual cost of free nursery provision.

  A major challenge in implementing the strategy will be in expanding the sector whilst maintaining and improving the quality of provision. Here the development of the childcare sector workforce will be key. Although a transformation fund has been set aside to help achieve this goal, it is not clear how this will operate, nor how any incentives it puts in to place will be maintained once the transformation fund winds down.

  Another challenge will be ensuring that the new provision actually reaches the groups of children and parents the Government is trying to target. Much of the expansion in early years' services is being driven by supply-led initiatives, where the Government provides subsidies to providers to start-up or further expand their early years' provision. The Neighbourhood Nurseries Initiative and Children's Centres are examples of these. Initiatives such as these are designed to ensure that provision is set up in areas where there is perceived to be the greatest need; however a real concern is that it is still the better off parents in these areas who disproportionately gain access to these services. With demand- side initiatives such as the childcare element of the WTC, it is much easier for government to better target the subsidy at the families and children that they see as most in need, but if there are problems with take-up, or there is not suitable or affordable childcare available then again their policy objectives will not be met.

  It will also be important to monitor how the roll-out of the 10-year Childcare strategy impacts on children as they move through the education system. We are concerned that simple and relatively inexpensive mechanisms that will enable the DfES to monitor the impact of this strategy are not in place. For instance the DfES keeps individual pupil level annual census data (PLASC) data on all children in state schools, combined with data on attainment. However we feel that it is a matter of urgency that:

    —  Every 3 and 4-year-old child receiving a component of free nursery provision should be included in PLASC including children in the Private and Voluntary sectors (at present only those in free nursery education places where these nurseries are attached to schools are included). Given that all providers currently have to give LEAs information on children and hours in order to receive the subsidy, we feel that the increased administrative burden would be minimal.

    —  Foundation profile records should be collected centrally for all children starting school, not just the 1 in 10 sample as currently used by DfES. Again, there should be minimal additional cost arising from the inclusion of all children.

  These measures would ensure that DfES can use administrative data to monitor the effects of the early education system on children as they move into school and beyond; this would be of huge benefit to informed policy-making in the future.

5.  SCHOOLS

  As seen from Table 3 the UK, relative to the other OECD countries highlighted, lags behind in terms of Primary and Secondary school spending per student. From Figure 3 we see that there has been a substantial increase in spending per head in the Under 5's sector; this combined with more modest increases in Primary and Secondary schools has led to a U-shaped spending pattern across age groups. This is of particular concern since there is strong evidence that early investment in education reaps the greatest long-term benefits (Carneiro and Heckman, 2003[15]). The Government seems to have acted upon this evidence with respect to the Under 5's, but not with respect to primary schools. There is a risk that not enough investment in primary school education will lead to an inability to sustain the gains that are intended to arise from the increase in Under 5's expenditure.

  One thread of recent government policy is to encourage successful schools to expand to allow as many children as possible to gain a place. However it is important to realise that while specific funding mechanisms exist to allow successful secondary schools to apply for funding to cover the capital costs of expansion, the same is not the case for primary schools (for example, see Hansard 21 June 2005, Column 1023W).

6.  FE AND ADULT EDUCATION

  From Figure 2 we can see that the Further Education sector has enjoyed large real increases in funding since 2001, along with other areas of education spending. However we have some serious concerns about the policy emphasis on qualifications in this sector, embodied in the DfES PSA target to "reduce by at least 40% the number of adults in the workforce who lack NVQ 2, working towards this, one million adults in the workforce to achieve level 2 between 2003 and 2006."

  Whilst there is clear evidence on the returns to qualifications obtained at school and at Higher Education institutions, the current evidence suggests that many intermediate vocational qualifications, especially NVQs at Level 1 and Level 2 do not confer any wage benefits on most recipients (see Dearden, McGranahan and Sianesi, 2004[16]).

  The targeting of qualifications in this context seems in part to reflect a belief on the part of government that policy-makers are well placed to predict the country's skill needs, and that left to themselves, learners and employers will pursue the wrong skills, or not learn or train "enough". It is also, however, a manifestation of the more general audit culture in which any form of public expenditure is tied to measurable targets. Qualifications are far easier to measure than learning, but the current evidence on the lack of returns to such qualifications suggests that despite best intentions, public expenditure in this area may not be providing best value for money.

7.  HIGHER EDUCATION REFORMS

  The reforms to Higher Education funding, which are due to be fully implemented by 2006-07, will require considerable additional funds from the public sector, alongside the increase in graduate contributions through top-up fees. Based on the latest DfES cost estimates, we calculate the additional annual taxpayer costs associated with the reforms to be £1.2 billion per year. Most of this will pay for the extension to student loans, which, it should be noted, are "off balance sheet" expenditures, and will not score as spending when assessing the Chancellor's fiscal rules. The rest will pay for new student grants.

  A major concern about this expenditure is the unnecessarily complicated design of the new system of student support that it will pay for. As we set out in submission to DfES in April 2004[17], the new system will involve a combination of five different income tapers, with the maximum amount of maintenance loan of £4,405 advertised by DfES available only to students with family income of exactly £33,560. There are two main problems with this design:

    —  The unnecessary complexity of the new system is particularly concerning given how important it is for young people to be able to understand the new funding system being put in place. There is a real danger that the lack of transparency in determining eligibility to student support (in particular the split between loans and grants for any individual) will mean that the extra money being provided fails to have its desired effect in encouraging young people to stay on at university.

    —  It is also extremely concerning that compared to the system it is replacing, it is students from parental incomes between £22,100 and £26,000 who will expected to make the biggest additional net contribution to the cost of their tuition and maintenance, taking into account both new fees and student support (see Figure 4). Depending on the level of the top-up fee, and on their exact circumstances after they graduate, students from this parental income range will have to contribute around £750 more per year towards the cost of their education (compared to the "pre-White Paper" system in place in 2003-04). By comparison, those from the poorest backgrounds will be more than £1,000 better off, and those from the wealthiest backgrounds will be around just £500 worse off. This pattern arises simply because of the way that the maintenance loans and grants are due to be tapered, and could easily be avoided if the system were re-designed in a cost-neutral way. It should be noted that the £22,100-£26,000 income range is a particularly dense part of the income distribution with parents largely in the 2nd and 3rd income deciles—arguably it is exactly students from these families that the Government is trying to encourage rather than dissuade from attending university.

Figure 4



Note illustration is for student in first or second year living away from home outside of London. Calculations available from authors.

September 2005





14   Data released in response to Freedom of Information request on 16 March 2005. Back

15   Carneiro, P and Heckman, J (2003), Human Capital Policy, NBER Working Paper No 9495. Back

16   L McGranahan, B Sianesi and L Dearden, "The role of credit constraints in educational choices: evidence from the NCDS and BCS70," December 2004, CEE Discussion Paper No 48. Back

17   Dearden, L, Fitzsimons, E and Goodman, A (2004) Fine-tuning the HE reforms. http://www.ifs.org.uk/docs/fine_tuning.pdf Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2006
Prepared 9 March 2006