Select Committee on Environmental Audit Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 200-215)

MR ANDREW SIMMS AND MR DAVID WOODWARD

5 MAY 2006

  Q200  Chairman: I wonder if there is any relatively brief report—that is a whole new area of inquiry which the Committee might want look at in its later inquiries—on that particular subject that you could send us or refer us to? We would be very grateful.

  Mr Woodward: I will have to think about that. I am not sure there is anything which brings together all of those components very effectively.

  Q201  Chairman: Can we briefly move on to Africa and agriculture. In your Africa Report one of the main conclusions was there needs to be: " . . . dramatically increased small-scale agriculture and an approach to farming based on maximum appropriate diversification". How does this fit in with the greater emphasis being put on agricultural production for exports which is coming from DFID? I notice in one of their recent reports on the benefits to the trade they cite an example of Ethiopia growing roses for export to the European market, I think, which seems to me slightly incongruous. Those seem to be the things that they were prepared to laud in their report. Is that the right and appropriate kind of thing that Ethiopians should be doing?

  Mr Simms: There are a number of things to say about them, and we may both have something to say on that. First of all, there are some obvious anomalies around the rise of luxury horticulture, partly because on a very simple level, sometimes at the local level, there may be a competition for natural resources, there may be competition for access to water, and luxury horticultural products, and flowers in particular, are enormously thirsty plants. There are other questions about the balance of benefits from that type of agriculture which filter back or do not filter back to the local community and what the balance of benefits there is. In facing a future in which the resilience and the coping strategies of these subsistence agricultural based economies are seriously under threat, first and foremost should be the circumstances in which their own livelihoods can be secured. There are a number of questions you would want to ask about the characteristics of an agricultural economy to identify what is going to be more resilient than something else. Typically, issues of productivity are going to be very important because if rainfall drops productivity is threatened. We know for a fact that more diverse multi-cropping systems are more productive than mono-cropping systems, and the characteristics of the export market are usually dominated, because of the kind of technology involved, by mono-cropping systems. I think a vision of development based upon secure livelihoods in a subsistence agricultural economy, that the characteristics of that economy are not those which immediately leap to mind when you think of luxury horticultural products perhaps flown to Britain, et cetera, where the benefits going back to the local economy are themselves questionable. There are some very serious questions to be asked there about what model of agriculture is going to give people the most secure foundations for coping in an increasingly hostile climate.

  Mr Woodward: Again, I want to come back to the global level. In a sense, there are two different issues, one is what does it make sense for an individual country to do, given the circumstances that we have at present and the system that we have at present? and the other is, what is the collective effect of those individually rational actions? Within a very trade-focused system the model which is applied is effectively assuming that the global economy is a bottomless pit into which one can dump unlimited amounts of a relatively narrow range of products. Again, if you look at sub-Saharan Africa, there is a fairly narrow range of products in which they have a potential comparative advantage, which largely comes down to natural resources, primary agricultural commodities, and a few labour intensive manufactures, such as textiles. For the individual country, it makes sense to export more and more, because that will have a relatively limited impact on the world price. But if you apply that to an entire continent, or to the entire of the developing world, the effect is to flood the world market and depress prices. Looking at, for example, cocoa producers as a whole, if one country doubles its output it will very nearly double its export revenues. If they all double their output they will probably half their export revenues because the world price will fall faster than the overall production increases. What we have is a model of competitive development in terms of exports. It is not enough for a country to export more, they have to increase their exports by more than everybody else, and by a large enough margin beyond everybody else to offset the price fall.

  Mr Simms: I will briefly interject to say what the outcome of those kinds of circumstances is. In the 1980s, the decline in terms of trade for the least developed countries in terms of its financial impact was roughly equivalent to the scale of the least developed country debt which we are still living with today.

  Q202  Chairman: You have called for Africa to be free from this one-size-fits-all approach to development, how do you see that change coming about? Will it be from Africa internally or does it have to come from outside?

  Mr Woodward: To a great extent I think it is about policy space. Again, over the last 25 years the extent of discretion which countries have over their own policies has been substantially reduced through IMF and World Bank programmes, in conditionality, through the dependency that has been created by the debt crisis and by its continuing effects, by WTO agreements and by pressure on countries to negotiate bilateral trade and investment agreements. The scope for an individual country to break with the model—unless you happen to be Venezuela and you have large quantities of oil, that makes a big difference—each individual country has an incentive to play along with the system, and that undermines the potential for solidarity among countries. One could dream about that and move towards solidarity among sub-Saharan African countries to develop collectively an alternative approach, but as long as the system as a whole is skewing their incentives and limiting their policy scope, that is going to be relatively limited. One could look towards a regional move in that direction, but we need to create the conditions in which that can happen, because those conditions do not exist at present.

  Q203  Chairman: You have also called for assistance for Africa to leapfrog dirty developments, which I assume is all the fossil fuels that are causing so much of the climate change problem. How can they do that and still develop because they do not seem, from my own personal perspective, to be getting very much assistance at all? The clean development mechanism is not delivering very much for them, for example.

  Mr Simms: That is right. I should put it into context by saying that even if it was the case that on a per capita basis emissions in Africa, and especially sub-Saharan Africa, increased dramatically they would still be light years away from the level of per capita emissions that you see in middle income countries or the advanced industrialised economies. Emissions from continents like Africa are not a problem in the global picture at the moment, however there are countless other benefits from looking at providing the energy for development in a different pattern, in a more decentralised pattern, in a way in which communities have greater control over their own power supplies. There are countless reports of large-scale grid failures and of the access to energy being restricted to elite and relatively small minorities in developing countries. Part of the call for the leapfrogging dirty development is also a positive call for a better model in which the people who need it can get access to energy. Africa is rich in natural energy resources, and the scope for renewables there is enormous. Perhaps only very slightly tongue in cheek we pointed out that the scale of subsidies going to the fossil fuel industries just within the OECD countries at the moment was substantially greater than the entire OECD's contribution to bilateral aid, and that one step might be to make the resources available for developing countries to develop in a climate friendly and climate proof fashion at least equal to the scale of subsidies going to our own domestic fossil fuel industries. There is a question of resources, there is a question of roll-out and there is a question which is quite similar to the one in terms of making resources available through the agricultural extension services to small scale farmers in Africa. It is not that the technology is not there, in fact, the scale of innovation—I am part of a judging panel of something called the Ashden Sustainable Energy Awards—we are seeing at the local level in many African countries is incredibly impressive. What they lack are the resources for roll-out. I feel energy has been the poor relation of development policies. Development policy agendas tend to be dominated by the traditional concerns of health and education. It is sometimes missed that you need energy to run all these things. I think we can benefit a lot from pushing energy up the Development Agenda.

  Q204  Chairman: Did the World Bank's extractive industries review make any difference or is it yet to deliver?

  Mr Simms: The review itself came up with some quite profound recommendations which would have seriously changed the nature of the Bank's energy lending portfolio. It was a great disappointment that the Bank hierarchy rejected its more ambitious proposals for phasing-out money going to dirty energy industries. I think the review itself has been a missed opportunity. It was a very good and quite comprehensive review and it is a great shame that its more important recommendations were quietly shelved.

  Q205  David Howarth: Turning to DFID's approach, which you have been very critical of in print and in your submission to us. You have been talking about their outward oriented neo-liberal approach and presumably that is the story you told about cocoa, that would be the meaning of that. Can you say a bit more about that because the cocoa example must be quite an unusual one? The conditions under which it is true that income falls when capacity expands are quite specific, are they not, the elasticity and so on? Can you talk about other sectors of the economy and why that approach does not work?

  Mr Woodward: They are quite specific but they are specific to most primary commodities and, most particularly, tropical agricultural commodities and also some mineral commodities like copper, for example, which Africa has. If you have price inelastic demand then that will be the case. That applies across a large proportion of Africa's exports at present.

  Q206  David Howarth: You are saying that this approach of prioritising export-led growth does not work for the type of commodities that developing countries are going to specialise in?

  Mr Woodward: Exactly so. As I say, it might make sense for one individual country, but not to do it as a blanket approach, which is essentially what the IMF and the World Bank have been doing since the structural adjustment came in in the early 1980s. They were in a position to exert some kind of co-ordinating role, so as to encourage developing countries to act in their collective interest rather than in their individual interest, instead of which they pursued exactly the opposite approach. To a great extent they are still doing it 25 years on.

  Q207  David Howarth: You have also pointed to some extraordinary distribution problems with the growth-led approach. The figures you quoted, I think, in your report of Growth Isn't Working was that only 60 cents of each $100 per capita growth went to the poor in the 1990s, that is 0.6%, which is extraordinarily low, and that was way down from the 73% in the 1980s. These are extraordinary figures. Can I ask you how they were arrived at and how robust they are?

  Mr Woodward: In terms of robustness, the first thing to say is that poverty data are less than perfect—more so than most economic data. There is always a danger in the tendency to think, "Here is a number, therefore we will believe it". There is a degree approximation. The data which we used is from the World Bank's own data set, so it is the generally accepted and used data. Essentially, what we did was combine two sets of data both from the World Bank, one set of data on the gross national income of the world as a whole, and we looked at how much that increased over 1981-90 and then 1990-2001, then we looked at their POVCAL data set to see how much the incomes of the poor, below the $1-a-day line and below the $2-a-day line, increased over the same period. Then we took the increase in the incomes of the poor households as a percentage of the overall income in gross national income globally.

  Q208  David Howarth: Is there any indication that is continuing into the present decade?

  Mr Woodward: It is very difficult to tell. Unfortunately there is also a very long time lag, because of the nature of the data in the poverty data. I think there is a good chance it is continuing.

  Q209  David Howarth: What hypotheses do you have to explain that trend if it is the trend?

  Mr Woodward: Again, to a great extent, it comes back to development paradigm that we have been developing over the last 25 years. In effect, what we have done is to step away from policies which are directly aimed at reducing poverty or providing free health and education services and social provision and social protection, in order to increase economic growth. We have sacrificed those distributional concerns in order to promote growth, but at the global level we have not seen any increase in growth. The result is, firstly, we do not have any more growth and, secondly, we have a sharp reduction in the share of that growth which is going to poor households.

  Q210  David Howarth: How does your solution then work? You looked upon a regionalisation solution, which must be a reversal of what one might call the crude globalisation policies followed by the WTO, the World Bank and IMF. How does that help?

  Mr Woodward: In terms of what we are proposing, a great deal of it is about changing mentality. A lot of the problem is about this fixation we have developed with economic growth as the be all and end all. The idea is "If you have more growth, you have more resources with which you can do what you like", but the way you get that growth is by limiting what you can do with those resources. You are always prioritising next year's growth over current redistribution. For me, a lot of it is about getting away from that fixation about growth, because economic growth is not in itself good. It is good if it contributes to improving people's lives and remaining within our environmental means. If we want to achieve poverty eradication, then we need to prioritise poverty eradication and not go for economic growth on the assumption that poverty eradication will somehow come about as a by-product of that. On the current trends, if we continue with the present rate of economic growth, the present distribution of the benefits of growth and the present rate of reduction of the carbon intensity production and we go on like that until 2050, on the one hand, we will be at four times the sustainable level of carbon emissions in 2050. Instead of falling by 60% they will have increased by 60%. And, at the same time, we will still have 550 million people, including a quarter of the population of sub-Saharan Africa, below the $1-a-day poverty line. The way we are going is simply not going to eradicate poverty or come anywhere near it in the next 45 years, neither is it compatible with what we need to do in terms of climate change. Even if we reduce the carbon intensity production, it is still not going to be enough. If you look at the effects of the oil price shocks of the 1970s and compare the rate of change for carbon intensity production between the 1960s and the 1980s, over two decades, it was a fall of 1% per decade. If we were to double that rate of improvement, so we do that every decade from now on, and to continue that indefinitely, we would still be 50% above the sustainable rate of carbon emissions in 2050 and we would still have the problem of 550 million people in poverty. This technological optimism is not a solution.

  Mr Simms: I would underline that by saying that every single scenario looking at the likely trajectories of climate change shows that we will be moving in the direction of triggering irreversible feedback mechanisms in the environment which will basically move the problem of global warming beyond the wit of our political masters to do anything about it. Every single economic scenario that I have seen at any rate of growth in the global economy pushes us beyond that point.

  Q211  David Howarth: That raises a number of different points and I will take them in order. There still needs to be change in the global economic structures and is that not really difficult to achieve? You talk about the reform of global economic structures as a necessary element of what you are talking about, but the way these things work there are all sorts of vetoes that will stop that even if it is unrealistic to expect that sort of change and we would find some way of adapting what we have got rather than just calling for a radical solution which is not likely to happen.

  Mr Simms: Again, we will probably both say something about that. Suffice to say, obviously where you have got the major institutions involved—David has seen this at first hand—you have got to get the turkeys to vote for Christmas in terms of getting that change and there are, no doubt, major institutional blocks. In terms of whether it is realistic to hope for that or not, I suppose I would fall back on the notion that is it realistic to not plan for the necessity of that happening because the other reality that you are left with is an entirely unacceptable, unsupportable and environmentally unsustainable one, so we have to try every strategy in the book to get it to come about. There is often a belief in my sector very much that change is a rational policy process and I feel that we have been let down on that on a number of occasions. The challenge I accept to us is that we are going to have to get far more creative in making our point and trying to get the message across because it is not really working at the moment.

  Mr Woodward: I would agree. As you say, it is profoundly difficult. It is the constant dilemma of political reform that you have to get the changes to an undemocratic system through that system and that is a slow and painful process. Having said that, it is a process that we have achieved at the national level, that is why we are sitting here today. But there are quite fundamental problems in the whole system of global economic governance, that the IMF and the World Bank have a majority of votes coming from the developed countries, even though the developed countries are only one-sixth of the world's population and the IMF and World Bank policies hardly impact on us at all. They have far greater impact on those five-sixths of the world's population who are under-represented. In the WTO, the formal rules, are much more democratic but the process by which things happen effectively ignores the rules completely, and most of the decisions are taken behind closed doors in secret meetings with arm twisting and inducements, in a process which would be regarded as scandalous at the national level. In terms of achieving change, I think we need to highlight the double standards. It is going to be a slow process, but I think by drawing the contrast between the way in which the international institutions operate and the basic minimum standards that we expect at the country level, we can create a pressure for real change. We would not think about operating a national government system as we operate the voting structures of the IMF and the World Bank where people's votes are weighted according to their income. As a result, Mozambique, whose economy has been virtually run by the IMF and the World Bank for the last 15 or 20 years, has a population of about 19 million, but they have fewer votes in the IMF and the World Bank than Iceland, with a population of 300,000 who are virtually unaffected. That is clearly undemocratic, and scandalously undemocratic. Yes, it is a slow process, but I think if we can highlight those double standards then there is the potential for change. I think not changing is not an option. As long as we go on in the way we are, we are in deep, deep trouble.

  Mr Simms: It is almost as if we are prepared to accept at the international level a form of governance which is perhaps more akin to pre-civil war England than we are here. On a more positive note- it sounds terribly negative—perhaps there is a lot more to be made which is capable of shaming some of the industrialised economies into better performance by looking at some of the best practice in developing countries. For example, there are substantial areas, whole islands in the Sunderbans in southern India, where they are committed to shifting to 100% renewable energy and are well on the way. Some of the greatest innovations in terms of running your economy on clean energy lines are happening in the developing world. There are good new stories out there but there are these huge blocks at the macro-level.

  Q212  David Howarth: On the one hand, you are optimistic in a way about the changing institutions but the other thing you said was you were very pessimistic about technical change being able to solve the problem of the relationship between economic growth and climate change. Can you say a bit more about that because it sounds to me as if the conclusion you want to draw from that is that convergence and contraction is not going to work just applied to carbon, what you are calling for is something almost impossible to sell, which is convergence and contraction in terms of economic welfare, or at least as a first contention it would be fine.

  Mr Simms: I would answer that by saying I think we have got a very easy sell because what we are selling is a planet fit for sustaining human life. We produced another report recently called the UK Interdependence Report in which we showed how Britain's dependence for its lifestyle relied upon importing increasingly large amounts of very real resources from the rest of the world, obviously leaving less for other people, and this idea of living within ones means, which on a financial level we might take for granted, we seem to not consider in the same way environmentally. There is no doubt at the moment that on the best available information we are overstretching our bio-capacity certainly and the only way to solve that is at the global level. The problem is we run up against the laws of physics when we trust to technological solutions to our problems, that against a backcloth of an ever-growing global economy any increases in technological efficiency or energy efficiency are simply overwhelmed by our total rising levels of consumption. There are basic laws of physics that you run up against when you are doing that.

  Q213  David Howarth: You could have economic growth in the exchange of services which produce no further burden on the physical environment at all?

  Mr Simms: That is theoretically possible, but it reminds me of the myth of the paper-free office that we thought IT was going to deliver to us, and our consumption of paper has gone ever up and up and up. There was some research done in the Netherlands which showed that the rise of internet shopping, for example, had increased the burden of traffic on our roads. In theory these things are possible but in practice they do not seem to happen. We need to measure what matters, I suppose. The problem is, as we all know, it is a very long debate, GNP/GDP are incredibly crude indicators, they really do not tell you very much. They tell you that when it rains you get wet, they do not tell you whether you are going to drown in a flood or whether you are getting enough water for the plants to grow in your garden. I think we need far more intelligent indicators that give us a clearer picture of where we are going wrong and where we are going right. Again, no data streams are perfect and there is an awful lot to be done to improve the quality of statistics at the international level, whether it is coming through the UN institutions or the Bank and the Fund, but on the best available information we know that we are already overreaching our bio-capacity in a range of areas, whether it is in fisheries or in soil lost through particular forms of agriculture, and we need to do something about that. If we mean what we say about meeting the Millennium Development Goals and the new deal that is promised to poor countries in the global economy at every single G8 Summit that I have been to going back more than a decade, then I see economies like the UK's like a car badly parked in a supermarket car park taking up more than just one parking space. If there is going to be room for people from sub-Saharan Africa to draw in and go shopping we have got to tidy up our act and release some space, release some environmental space, in order that they do have the environmental space to develop. It is also quite right to say that is an issue which is not restricted to our use of fossil fuels, it is an issue which touches many other areas of life as well.

  Q214  Mr Vaizey: I was going to ask what you thought of Hilary Benn and Richard Laing's rejoinder to your Guardian article?

  Mr Woodward: I have to say, I was not terribly convinced, which is perhaps not terribly surprising in the circumstances. I do not think they have fully addressed the issue. The issue primarily is around global economic growth. If we were to adopt policies which seriously and directly addressed poverty, that would almost inevitably produce growth in any case in sub-Saharan Africa. I do not have a problem with sub-Saharan African economies growing, the main problem is with the model that we have, which relies on global economic growth for poverty reduction, because the links are too tenuous. Effectively, what we have is a situation where poverty reduction is seen as depending on growth in developing countries and developing countries' growth has been made increasingly dependent on growth in developed countries. We have created a need for developed countries to go on growing more and more and more, whereas—and this comes back to something Mr Howarth was saying—the increase in income within developed countries is not really contributing to an increase in well-being. So we are not calling for contraction and convergence in terms of well-being, because for the bulk of the population—something like 80-85% of the population of the developed countries who account for maybe half of the world's income—further increases in absolute income do not contribute to an increase in well-being. We want to increase our incomes much more for our relative income than for absolute income; it is more about status. If nobody had a car, having a car would be a great thing, it is only because everybody has got cars that we want three Porsches. We are on what is called a "hedonic treadmill". We are all trying to increase our relative income but by doing so we all increase overall income, which does not leave any of us better off. It is getting away from that need for ever faster growth in developed country economies. In order to do that, we have to first break that dependency. If we just switch the global economy into reverse gear now, without doing anything else, that would be disastrous, because we have spent 25 years creating a dependency on growth in the developing countries. We have to create the conditions in which that can happen.

  Q215  Mr Vaizey: When the White Paper is published would you like to see Hilary Benn do a spectacular u-turn and say, "I am wrong"?

  Mr Woodward: I would love to, but I am not holding my breath. There is a need to recognise that we are facing a fundamental problem here: that the way we are going we are not going to eradicate poverty and we are not going to deal with climate change. Eradicating poverty is a moral imperative. The level and depth of poverty in the world today is absolutely scandalous. Nearly half the world's population live below the $2-a-day line. The $2-a-day line is equivalent to, in the UK, 19 people living on a single minimum wage with no access to free health or education, or benefits, or borrowing, or access to savings, or anything else. Nearly half of the world's population is living below that level. A sixth of the world's population is living below half of that level of income. That is scandalous. That is a moral imperative. But, at the same time, dealing with climate change is a practical necessity. If we do not deal with climate change we are in serious trouble and we are very quickly going to get into the situation where it becomes an irreversible process with catastrophic consequences. Part of the reason why technology does not look like being enough is that we have left it too long. If we had started taking serious measures ten or 20 years ago, we might have been able to do something about it. Now, the longer we leave it, the more drastic the measures will be that we will need to take in order to tackle the problem effectively. Again, part of the problem comes back to the global economic governance system, that we do not have effective mechanisms at the global level which allow countries to take collective decisions in their genuine collective interest from a long-term perspective. If we had, then we would not have got into this mess.

  Mr Simms: I would summarise by saying that climate change in the context of development is a different order of concern to questions of health and education which are, of course, incredibly important, but one can argue whether a health budget should be increased by £10 million or £20 million or £30 million. When we are talking about climate change, we are talking about averting a point at which the problem moves beyond our wit to control it. If you look back over the last 25 years, some of the poorest countries in the world have been expected to go through profound re-engineering of their economies in the face of financial debts, many of which we would argue were dubious and as much the fault of the lending institutions as they were of the countries that took the loans. Now we are faced with a different kind of debt, we are faced with an ecological debt, and it is up to us to hold a mirror up to ourselves and ask in our far more comfortable and protected societies, "Are we prepared to face the level of re-engineering of our own economies to deal with our ecological debt that we have expected some of the poorest countries in the world to do in the face of far more questionable financial debt?"

  Chairman: Thank you very much for that very enlightening session. We may have a couple more questions, if we can send them in writing to you, that would be great. Thank you very much.





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2006
Prepared 16 August 2006