Select Committee on Environmental Audit Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 20-39)

MR MICHAEL ROBERTS AND MS GILLIAN SIMMONDS

5 JULY 2006

  Q20  David Howarth: That raises a lot of issues about which I am sure we will come back to over the next five minutes or so. Can I put the question in a slightly different way. In fact, this goes back to a question that Mr Challen asked. Holding all the other factors equal, ceteris paribus, what effect on business, or what evidence do you have of the effect on business, would there be of, say, the cap rising or falling by a million tons of carbon?

  Mr Roberts: I suspect you are not going to be with satisfied with this, but it does depend upon your assumptions. Let me try and make this real for you and for the Committee. The DTI commissioned some work on the impact on energy prices as a result of the Emissions Trading Scheme, and I believe that the number suggested that the impact on UK energy prices as a consequence of the ETS allocations was up to a maximum of a 25% uplift on energy prices. It is quite a difficult thing to be sure about, but that was the order of magnitude of impact. If in any way that increase is experienced to a greater degree in the UK than in other countries, then we would have a concern about the effect that would have on the competitive position particularly of energy intensive companies, and there are theories about the extent to which the UK may be more exposed than other countries, perhaps those countries which have less liberalised energy markets and where their power sector has less ability to pass through cost. There is a feeling that there may be more exposure in this country to energy price rises than other countries. I am sorry I cannot give you a straight answer, because there is no definitive evidence out there, but I am trying to give you a feel for where some of the friction lies.

  Q21  David Howarth: Are there any other examples of cost outside the rise in electricity prices? Is that the main concern that you have?

  Ms Simmonds: In principle the first phase of the Emissions Trading scheme allocated to the non-electricity sectors on a business as usual basis. In practice, not all companies will have been allocated on a business as usual basis or according to their need, and, as a consequence, some companies, some installations, are required to purchase allowances outside of the electricity generating sector if you put that to one side. I would imagine in Phase 2 we will see a similar thing because of the nature of the allocation methodology.

  Q22  David Howarth: Can I pick up a point on competitiveness as well. The Secretary of State said during the statement on Thursday, "The Government will continue to insulate international competitive sectors within the ETS from the burden of carbon reduction." Does that not mean that you have got your way? There nothing to worry about. The Government has taken on board your concerns, perhaps, in a way, which imposes a bigger burden on everybody else.

  Mr Roberts: I do not think life is quite as straightforward as that. There is quite a useful logic in what the Government has sought to do by allocating broadly according to need for energy-using companies and putting the burden of the reduction through the ETS for the UK on the generation sector. The point at which life is not quite so straightforward is the point at which power generators have to pass through the consequence, in terms of cost, in order to meet their own targets. To the extent that costs are passed through, they will be endured by all energy users, be they domestic or indeed business, and within the business community you have got some particular parts of corporate Britain, particularly the energy-intensive companies in process industries like glass, steel, cement, who will feel that increase more sharply than other parts of the economy. That is where life is not quite as simple as the Government would perhaps like us to believe.

  Q23  David Howarth: The other thing you mentioned was the importance of certainty about the future price of carbon. Do you support rules for more certainty about the future phases of the scheme through until perhaps 2025, and, if you do, do you support unilateral action by the UK to try to stabilise expectations, where the UK would say what its draft allocations would be or, on the other hand, do you think that everything should go in step with the whole of the EU, that Britain should not go it alone in announcing even draft allocations?

  Ms Simmonds: We certainly support greater certainty over a longer period and at an EU level. Politically, I think we would agree that it would be difficult to achieve long-term certainty on emissions trading at EU level on specific allocations, but a way of perhaps getting greater certainty at EU level might be around the criteria on the basis of which those allocations will be made. So, if one gets an agreement at a European level around the criteria for allocating, then perhaps we could allocate at a UK level according to those criteria and have some consistency on a European level.

  Q24  David Howarth: How about having longer phases?

  Ms Simmonds: Absolutely, we are in support of that.

  Q25  David Howarth: Another issue that will be mentioned, I am going to come back to it briefly, is about the extension of the scheme to other sectors. Gillian mentioned . Can I ask you some detail of your views on that? Should the aviation sector be brought into the scheme on the same basis as everybody else, so that there is a trading between aviation and other sectors, or should there be some of kind of special treatment for aviation and non-aviation business?

  Mr Roberts: A very good set of questions which are very much at the edge of our own understanding of what needs to be. I think, ultimately, in an ideal world you would want to see the aviation sector part of a trading arrangement which involves other sectors as well, and, of course, we have an incumbent trading arrangement and so those would be a natural set of businesses to link to an aviation trading scheme. Having said that, I think there are some important practical issues to resolve about the transition through which you get from where we are now to a situation where aviation is part of a broader trading arrangement. There is certainly a debate about the extent to which the inclusion of aviation or the linkage of aviation to existing trading arrangements might put pressure on the existing market for carbon credits. That very much, of course, depends upon what constraints are put upon aviation sector players, and no-one has yet reached a view about what exactly those might be. The other issue, of course, is about how the allocations for aviation are actually made. That issue about allocation methodology is likely to be made within the existing ETS as well as what might be an ETS with or without aviation, but that might have a material impact. Ultimately, the economic logic would be that aviation has got be playing its part inside a wider Emissions Trading Scheme with lots of others, because that is how you get the economically most efficient reduction in carbon. How you get there is going to be extremely difficult. We should sort that out sooner rather than later. To be clear, it is not a recipe for inaction.

  Q26  David Howarth: How about road transport consumers? Does there need to be a transition?

  Mr Roberts: We would be willing to consider, alongside others, the idea that in some way road transport might be part of a future set of emissions trading arrangements. Again, there are several complexities, two of which are immediately obvious. One is you have a number of individual sources of emissions, i.e. in this country 26 million vehicles on the roads, rather than a rather more manageable number of point source emissions, as you would have with the Emissions Trading Scheme, which numbers thousands rather than millions. The second is if, for example, one decided to base a road transport emissions scheme on some sort of commitment by vehicle manufacturers, the difficulty is that while the manufacturers have responsibility for the carbon emissions associated with the production of the vehicles, they have far less control over the emissions associated with the use of the vehicles, which clearly is down to individual drivers like you or I.

  Q27  David Howarth: You mentioned, I think, in passing, your concerns about the accuracy of the data on which all these policy decisions are being made, especially about the accuracy of the data being used in other countries. What do you think should be done about the accuracy of the data being used here and elsewhere to set limits? Obviously the whole scheme depends on the data being accurate and trustworthy.

  Ms Simmonds: We are hopeful that the second phase might lead to more consistent presentation of data, which, I think, is the first step that you require at EU level. If the National Allocation Plans are presented in a more consistent manner, then there may be an ability to assess and compare Member State allocations. For example, in the first phase some Member States did not present their projections, so it was very difficult to understand what the cut was against any projections. I think that is the first phase. Again, in some Member States, I would imagine, one needs a much more significant data-gathering exercise. The UK has probably better data than many other Member States, and there may be a need to level this up across the European Union.

  Q28  David Howarth: One final point. You returned to this point which I have heard Digby Jones talk about several times, the difference between how we deal with EU regulations compared to other people. Is it your view that what is going on really is some kind cynical manipulation by people abroad, or is there really across Europe countries, areas with different needs, different problems, and therefore there does need to be some variation of approach in different countries?

  Mr Roberts: Certainly different countries are at different stages of development along the low carbon path, if I can use that rather jargon-laden phrase, and therefore it is reasonable, if you are going to have a burden sharing approach to the EU reduction in carbon, as indeed we do under the Kyoto arrangements, it is reasonable to assume that different countries will have different stretch targets in terms of controlling carbon. I think that is taken as read. The trick in the game is to try and make sure that you deliver differential allocations on the basis of the best possible information and data. Within that, however, as in other walks of life, and not just in the business world or the political world, inevitably gaming goes on and people, businesses, countries, will seek to maximise their competitive position, and, as we have said before in this session, looking at the way in which some of the targets were set in Phase 1 and as they appear to be being set for Phase 2, there is reason to believe, we may be contradicted, but there is reason to believe that some may be gaming, some may be trying to maximise the beneficial position by having a laxer rather than a stricter target, and, for that reason, as in Phase 1, instead of Phase 2, we have said the Commission has got a critically important role in acting as policeman to make sure that there is some commensurate degree of effort across the 25 Member States.

  Chairman: If you would not mind, we would like you to remain. There are some more points we would like to put to you. We will have to break now to go and vote. Can I ask colleagues to be ready to resume in 15 minutes maximum.

The Committee suspended from 3.30 pm to 4.44 pm for a division in the House.

  Q29 Dr Turner: If I heard you right, Mr Roberts, in your opening remarks you said that the CBI would prefer to see a single price for carbon. Presumably you would like to see a real cost for carbon across all sectors which would guide investment policies and reactions, et cetera. At the moment, of course, we have just been talking about the Emissions Trading Scheme. We have got anything but that. Does that mean that the CBI would be receptive to an outright carbon tax policy?

  Mr Roberts: I think a carbon tax in many respects would be preferable to, for example, the Climate Change Levy, which is a bit of a misnomer in that it tackles energy rather than carbon as the externality. Whether a carbon tax would be the right way forward depends on a few things, not least what would other countries be doing with regard to their taxation policy, which brings us back to some of the earlier conversation, and I think also it would be important to understand what its overlap might be with things like emissions trading, which in some respects we regard as being more efficient as a policy tool, subject to ensuring that it is reasonably simple and administratively light.

  Q30  Dr Turner: What about a carbon tax to be allied with a concomitant carbon tax credit regime which rewarded low-carbon or non-carbon emitting behaviour? Would the CBI see any mileage in that?

  Mr Roberts: I think I would rather like to know a little bit more about how it worked before offering a comment on that.

  Q31  Dr Turner: The Science and Technology Report 2003 sets out how it would apply certainly in electricity generation.

  Mr Roberts: Do you have a view, Gillian?

  Ms Simmonds: I do not have a view, and I do not know enough about it.

  Q32  Mr Chaytor: Could I come back to the earlier question about vehicle manufacturers and road transport being within the trading scheme. Your argument is that it is more difficult in the vehicle sector because there are X million vehicles and separate point sources, but, in respect of manufacturers, although they are not directly responsible, although they cannot accurately calculate the exact emissions of all the vehicles they produce, yet each of their vehicles days is designed and built to cover a certain broad mileage over its lifecycle; so the information on average vehicle mileages for particular categories of vehicles is pretty accurate, is not it? Would that not be the basis whereby manufacturers could be brought into the trading scheme?

  Mr Roberts: I suppose that is a way of trying to get a handle on the lifetime carbon emissions associated with a vehicle, but I think it is still a pretty inaccurate one. Although we have not talked in depth to vehicle manufacturers about this particular issue, my instinct would be that they would probably want a bit more clarity on how that part of the carbon envelope of a vehicle is accounted for. The motor industry has indicated you could cut carbon emissions from the use of a vehicle by something of the order of a third through the adoption of so-called eco-driving practices; so there is quite a significant element there of the carbon envelope which is down to the behaviour of the driver, and that is the bit that is difficult to capture accurately in the way that you were suggesting, I think.

  Q33  Mr Chaytor: Yes. We could pursue this in a detailed discussion, but all I am saying is it is not just a question of the lifecycle mileage, it is the average annual mileage for particular categories of vehicles. The behaviour of the driver is almost a bonus. It is indisputable that the manufacturers have an understanding about what is the typical mileage for each kind of vehicle they produce, and that could be the basis for a discussion?

  Mr Roberts: It might be the basis for a discussion, and I am certainly aware that within this country at least the motor manufacturing industry, which does take its responsibilities seriously, is starting to think about where one goes next with regard to their contribution to the climate agenda post the current voluntary agreement, for example. Maybe the sort of proposition you mentioned would form the basis of a conversation; I think there would still be some residual concern about the degree of control, if you like, that the vehicle manufacturers would have over an element of that total carbon footprint.

  Q34  Mr Chaytor: On the previous issue that you have responded to, the carbon tax as against the Climate Change Levy, it is not necessarily either/or, is it, because the Government, if it were minded to, could simply rename the Climate Change Levy to the Climate Change Carbon Levy and make the necessary adjustments and you would have your carbon tax?

  Mr Roberts: It could do.

  Q35  Mr Chaytor: Are you actively lobbying for changes or a replacement to the Climate Change Levy in favour of a carbon tax or adjustment to the climate change levy to become a form of carbon tax?

  Mr Roberts: We have certainly said that there are ways in which what is currently the CCL could be improved, one of which would be to make sure that it does not penalise the use of nuclear on its carbon credentials, and the second would be that there is að ñneed to look at the interface between who pays theð ñClimate Change Levy within the business community at the moment and who is covered by the Emissions Trading Scheme, because from the point of view of companies who are covered by both, they feel that they are paying, in fact, not just twice, but three times over for the externality which is carbon. If you are a manufacturer, for example, you are paying through action to meet your own allocation on the ETS, the impact on your energy prices cost as a consequence of the generators' need to meet their commitments under ETS and through the CCL, even if in some cases it is a residual levy rather than a full levy, and so we think there is an argument for trying to streamline rather than applying several different policy measures.

  Q36  Mr Chaytor: Your objection is not to the levy on energy as such, your objection is to the complexity of the system that currently applies?

  Mr Roberts: To be absolutely clear, you would be hard-pressed to find many businesses or, indeed, many individuals who are in the game of asking for more taxes, and, to be clear, we are not in the game of asking for more taxes but we recognise that in certain circumstances there is an economic case for applying taxation, for example to address externalities. We think that there are improvements that can be made to CCL, and one that we have not mentioned is the extent to which the domestic energy user is exposed to the carbon externalities of energy use, which, of course, under the CCL they are not.

  Q37  Mr Chaytor: In respect of the achievement of government targets, at the moment the Government is not going to achieve its 2020 target. What specific measures would you argue for to bring the carbon emissions back on track? Are there policies you think the Government should adopt that they have not yet adopted to bring these carbon emissions down?

  Ms Simmonds: The targets are 2010 targets, or 2020 targets and the UK Climate Change Programme's focus over the next four years, so it is a very short space of time, but in our response to the Climate Change Programme Review we certainly did identify a number of additional measures that we thought could be implemented on the SME and commercial sectors as well as the domestic sectors, as Michael was mentioning before. I think on the industrial sector, as we have already been alluding to, we feel there is more an issue for streamlining the measures that are currently in place for the industrial sector. There are a number of very well thought through measures already targeted at the industrial sector. The SME sector, things such as enhancing the free loans that the Carbon Trust provides to the SME sector, which we think have worked well to date, perhaps providing more grant capital through that; VAT reductions on energy efficient products is another way of encouraging investment in energy efficiency. They are small measures but together they build up into a significant carbon reduction.

  Q38  Mr Chaytor: In terms of the domestic sector, essentially you want to revisit VAT on fuel?

  Ms Simmonds: Did we address VAT on fuel in our response?

  Mr Roberts: No. To be clear, I was pointing out a short-coming in the existing CCL, but we have not actively been suggesting that that is something to a government policy. What we have tended to focus on more is trying to secure greater emission reductions through the enforcement of energy efficiency standards in house building, where we think there is significant scope for additional benefit, and the use of things like reduced or zero Stamp Duty on energy-efficient homes.

  Q39  Mr Chaytor: Finally, can I just ask about the question of public awareness and individual behaviour. Do you think that business has a role or responsibility to contribute to the raising of the levels of public understanding about the seriousness of climate change and the necessary actions that need to be taken to mitigate it?

  Mr Roberts: It certainly does have a role, and I think leaders within this community already exercise that role, and I am sure there is scope for widening that. For example, through measures encouraged by employers in the workplace, simple things like switching computers in offices off at night-time or at weekends clearly benefits the employer in terms of reduced energy cost but helps to embed an approach within individuals which, hopefully, they will take home with them. In fact, as I understand it, Boots have actively and explicitly provided information for employees precisely because they feel this is an issue which transcends the division between the workplace and the home. Equally, businesses have a role in terms of their interface with consumers, with their customers; so what Tesco has recently announced in terms of investment in high energy-efficient supermarkets has an educational benefit, I think, for their customers, and finally, I think businesses in terms of their relationship with their shareholders who increasingly are expecting information on their environmental and carbon performance is another way, albeit by proxy, through which the business community can help stimulate a different way of thinking through society at large.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2006
Prepared 18 October 2006