Select Committee on Environmental Audit Minutes of Evidence


Memorandum submitted by the Sussex Energy Group

ABOUT THE SUSSEX ENERGY GROUP

  There is growing awareness that a transition to a sustainable energy economy is one of the main challenges facing us in the 21st Century. Although climate change is a central factor, there are several other reasons why we need to address the energy transition, including security of supply, fuel poverty and the attractions of innovations such as renewable energy resources, distributed generation and combined heat and power.

  Critically, the energy transition needs to be designed in such a way that maximises economic efficiency. An effective response requires technical ingenuity, behavioural change and virtually unprecedented political commitment. The complexities and uncertainties involved are similarly great.

  These are the challenges that the Sussex Energy Group is addressing. We undertake academically excellent and inter-disciplinary research that is also centrally relevant to the needs of policy-makers and practitioners. We pursue these questions in close interaction with a diverse group of those who will need to make the changes happen. We are supported through a five-year award from the Economic and Social Research Council but also have funding from a diverse array of other sources.

OUTLINE OF THIS RESPONSE

  This response has been written and edited jointly by Professor Gordon Mackerron, Dr Jim Watson, Dr Alister Scott and Dr Shimon Awerbuch, all of the Sussex Energy Group.

  In this response, we cover all the main areas set out in the inquiry announcement: A) The extent of the generation gap; B) Financial cost and investment considerations and C) Strategic benefits. We do not wish to include any "other issues" under D.

  Within A, we question the usefulness of the idea of a "generation gap", particularly since the time required to build new electricity supply based on gas or renewable technologies has decreased dramatically in recent years.

  Within B, two important themes we emphasise are: the impact of much greater uncertainty than commonly admitted on the reliability of generating cost estimates as the basis for major policy departures; and the role and needs of potential micro-generation innovations.

  Within C, we comment on: security of supply arguments and the different dimensions of security of supply; and the value of taking a portfolio approach to investment decision-making.

A.  THE EXTENT OF THE GENERATION GAP

What are the latest estimates of the likely shortfall in electricity generating capacity caused by the phase-out of existing nuclear power stations and some older coal plant? How do these relate to electricity demand forecasts and to the effectiveness of energy efficiency policies?

  We would question whether the idea of a "generation gap" is useful in analysing energy and security problems. Whilst it is important that public policy makers be aware of the balance between probable demand and supply for power several years ahead, expressing this in terms of a "gap" pre-judges the existence of a problem and can give rise to a false sense of urgency. It also lends itself to a "predict and provide" approach to generation investment, which has demonstrably failed in the past. For example, in the early 1980s a programme of 10 Pressurised Water Reactors was thought to be necessary to fulfil UK electricity demand. In the event, only one (Sizewell B) was built.

  The rise of gas-fired and renewable energy generation, with their short construction times relative to coal and nuclear power plants, also means that the period over which it is important to forecast the balance between demand and supply has drastically decreased. While National Grid still makes such projections seven years into the future, supply response times are now dramatically shorter than this—usually 2-3 years.

B.  FINANCIAL COST AND INVESTMENT CONSIDERATIONS

  In this section we dwell particularly on the potential for nuclear and micro-generation, both being areas where the Sussex Energy Group has conducted substantial research.

Nuclear1[1]

With regard to nuclear new build, how realistic and robust are cost estimates in the light of past experience? What impact would a major programme of investment in nuclear have on investment in renewables and energy efficiency?

  The shape of the current UK debate about new nuclear build is familiar. Climate change is serious; the UK wants to reduce carbon emissions substantially as a result; the scope for doing so via renewable energy, energy efficiency and carbon capture has limits; UK nuclear capacity will keep falling; and nuclear technology offers an established form of low-carbon energy. Therefore, the argument runs, we need to re-invest in nuclear, preferably soon.

  There may be some economic problems to overcome but decisive action on the part of Government could remove the obstacles to a new "programme". Setting aside issues of nuclear waste, the argument is a serious one and needs proper scrutiny[2]. How serious are the economic and commercial obstacles to new build, how might they be overcome and—often overlooked—what would be the wider consequences?

  Many commentators are now putting forward analyses of the economic status of new nuclear build, usually with a comparison of the status of alternatives, mainly gas-fired power and/or renewable energy. The majority suggest that the generating cost of nuclear power is similar to, or not much higher than, these alternatives. This is new: when Government declared in its February 2003 White Paper[3] that nuclear was currently an uneconomic choice, no-one seriously demurred. What has changed?

  There have been two major changes in the last two years. The first is that oil and gas prices have risen and stayed high. If these price levels were to persist over the next 10-20 years, nuclear economics would clearly improve. The problem for nuclear is that potential private investors in nuclear power are unlikely to take a bet on oil and gas prices falling. So the case for nuclear needs to rest primarily on the technology itself. This is where the second change comes in. After deadlock for a decade, a European country (Finland) has at last placed a real order for a nuclear plant, and France has decided that it will follow. Nuclear power now becomes a real prospect in Europe: if Finland, why not the UK?

Uncertain economics

  The most important single economic obstacle to nuclear power is that no-one really knows what a new nuclear plant would cost to build, and it will be impossible to know for some time. Bearing in mind that the construction cost and time of a nuclear plant are the single most important determinant of the economics, this is a serious obstacle.

  Most of the recent UK economic analyses—mainly from nuclear vendors, financial institutions and consultants—start by assuming a given construction cost for a plant. The numbers range from a frankly optimistic figure of £850/kW (vendors' estimate) to £1,625/kW from the consultants Oxera. [4]This is quite an alarming range: at £850/kW nuclear is close to economic; at £1,625/kW it is highly problematic. Some of the differences between numbers are easily explained: the Oxera number includes a range of real costs that are often ignored (eg planning, licensing and first-of-a-kind costs). It also explicitly refers to the first reactor that might be built; the vendor estimates are commonly the expected cost of the eighth or tenth reactor, or a "settled-down" cost, to which we return below.

  But there are still serious differences in cost estimates even after these factors are taken into account. These represent the serious uncertainties that remain at the heart of the economics of nuclear power.

  There are perhaps two main contending designs for new plant: the EPR from Areva in France and the AP1000 Westinghouse/BNFL design. The EPR is the plant just starting to be built in Finland, but neither design has yet been completed anywhere in the world. This creates an immediate uncertainty. Further, neither design has yet started to go through the UK safety licensing system, and different licensing requirements in different countries lead to different costs. UK history at Sizewell B is that UK licensing requirements tend to be more onerous and costly than those of other countries. This could be different in future, but again no-one would expect an investor to risk much money on it. The conclusion is clear: no single-number estimate of nuclear construction cost in UK conditions has any real meaning.

  The conventional answer to this uncertainty is that big vendors or consortia are willing to take on these financial risks of construction and—as is the case in Finland—offer a fixed price, turnkey construction contract. This certainly transfers the risk from the consumer back to the vendor, but it does not remove it. If costs turn out to be higher than the fixed price agreed, then vendors will not keep offering low, fixed prices. In the late 1960s, GE and Westinghouse signed similar fixed price deals on nuclear plant to US utilities for nuclear plant, only to retreat into cost-plus contracts when they made big losses. The same may not happen this time round—but it is possible.

Scale and scope of new nuclear

  The other major issue in construction costs is around scale and scope. Vendors argue, as they have for three decades, that bigger is better in two senses. First, to minimise cost, reactors have to be as big as possible—the EPR represents 1,600MW of power per unit, substantially bigger than any in the UK. Second, a series of identical reactors needs to be built, usually eight or 10. A first reactor, alone, will be seriously uneconomic, on almost all analyses. The decision then is not whether or not to try building a more or less novel reactor; it is whether to commit to a programme of around a minimum of 10GW (representing the capacity needed to meet around 20% of current UK maximum demand). This is a game with high stakes.

Subsidy and competition

  How could such a 10GW programme be delivered? This is a large subject in itself but most commentators agree that substantial Government intervention would be needed—to underwrite construction costs, to ensure long-term electricity sales contracts, and to cap long-term liabilities. These are all technically feasible operations, but they would entirely undermine the painfully constructed, and broadly competitive, wholesale market for electricity.

  This might be acceptable if climate change is thought to be serious, but it throws up another potentially serious obstacle. Non-nuclear electricity generators would be unlikely to sit back and accept as reasonable the "state aid" that Government support of this kind would involve. If BNFL and the new Nuclear Decommissioning Authority can be subject to an 18-month European Commission inquiry when the potential threat to fair competition is marginal, it is easy to imagine the scale of an inquiry if 10GW of nuclear capacity were to be favoured by Government on the scale needed. Such a state-aid case might well be resolved in favour of the UK Government—state aid is allowable if there are powerful reasons to do so—but it represents another obstacle.

Impacts on other options

  Further, and to finish, a large programme of nuclear power would have other consequences, especially for other means of reducing carbon emissions. The prime effect would be "crowding out" other low-carbon investments, especially renewable energy. There are at least three aspects to this. First, there would be an opportunity cost in allocating public money to nuclear at the expense of other options. Second, there would need to be some restructuring of market and regulatory rules, which might make it more difficult for decentralised options such as renewables and CHP. Third, government intervention to support nuclear would send a mixed signal, and would damage fragile investor confidence with respect to renewables.

  The nuclear choice, as currently presented, is therefore of an essentially "all-or-nothing" character, carrying large risks. The prospects for a real nuclear contribution to reducing carbon emissions would be helped if a more flexible and incremental case for nuclear investment could be plausibly constructed.

  We discuss the question of portfolios of generating technologies in more detail below under "strategic aspects".

MICRO-GENERATION

What contribution can micro-generation make, and how would it affect investment in large-scale generating capacity?

  The following comments draw on our recent response to the DTI's consultation on its micro-generation strategy[5]. The full consultation response is given at Annex A [not printed].

  The DTI's decision to develop a micro-generation strategy is welcome. The UK is in a strong position to become a world leader in micro-generation technologies. Our research shows that power exports to the grid from some technologies can be significant. If these technologies are deployed in large numbers, they could make substantial contributions to the supply mix. For example, over a million household heating boilers are replaced each year, representing a sizeable opportunity for the introduction of micro-CHP: if 50% were replaced as micro-CHP units, this would displace several hundred megawatts of central generation[6].

  However, since many of these technologies are at an early stage of development, a supportive policy framework is essential to give micro-generation the opportunity to grow. At the moment, the DTI bases its approach to micro-generation on three types of barrier: cost, information and technical. While these are important, this characterisation obscures some other important barriers, particularly those that relate to: consumer decision-making, current policies and regulations, and the fiscal regime.

  By way of illustration, there are fundamental differences between the fiscal treatment of investments in energy supply and investments on the customer's side of the meter—particularly in domestic households[7]. Consumers have no access to tax or depreciation allowances for investments in micro-generation, whilst companies investing in central generation are able to take advantage of capital allowances. Furthermore, consumers pay VAT (albeit at a reduced rate) for their investments, whilst energy supply companies are able to pass VAT on to consumers.

  In brief, our research on the economics and regulation of micro-generation raises the following implications for policy:

    —  the government should consider setting informed targets for the expansion of micro-generation, which should be backed up by a package of policies to support deployment;

    —  creative approaches to technology support should be considered including enhanced capital allowances and the extension of the settlement system so that micro-generation is given similar treatment to centralised energy investments and business energy efficiency (see below for further discussion of the settlement system issue);

    —  there is a need for schemes to provide households with easy access to impartial information and skilled installers to minimise the risks they perceive;

    —  energy service contracts could help to expand the micro-generation market by providing access to capital. The 28-day rule, which means that consumers can switch their energy supplier every four weeks, should be abolished to enable this; and

    —  metering should be upgraded when micro-generation is installed to help provide consumers with access to a range of energy services.

  It is too early to say whether—and to what extent—micro-generation will help to deliver all of the four goals of UK energy policy as set out in the 2003 White Paper: reducing carbon emissions, improving electricity reliability and security, enhancing choice for consumers and reducing fuel poverty. For example, there is not enough evidence to show that some technologies (particularly micro-CHP) can deliver significant carbon reductions when installed in an average household. This evidence will not be available until the Carbon Trust field trials have been concluded. It is also unclear whether micro-generation will reduce the load on distribution networks. If most households with micro-generation export some of their electricity, this might make distribution network management more challenging, as discussed next.

Impacts on the energy network

  The impacts of micro-generation on energy networks—particularly electricity distribution networks are contentious. A report for the government by Mott MacDonald[8] came to the broad conclusion that these impacts would be minimal in the short-to-medium term except for a few exceptional geographical areas. However, this conclusion is not shared by some distribution network companies, who are predicting that integration might be more problematic once micro-generation has grown beyond a certain threshold.

  The process of changing incentives for distribution network companies so that they find it easier to integrate distributed electricity generation sources has started, albeit slowly. The recent implementation of the 2005 price control review includes extra measures so that these companies can recoup some of the additional investment associated with this. For micro-generation however, the issues are different to larger distributed sources such as wind farms and industrial CHP. The most important is the need for simplicity. Whilst there are now connection standards for micro-generation (which mean that electricity companies do not have to inspect every installation), the process of registering new installations is overly-complex (see Annex A for more on this [not printed]).

  Another important issue that will hamper the future deployment of micro-generation is metering. Thoughts about future metering arrangements for households should not only focus on the requirements of micro-generation units. They should also consider future consumer demands for broader energy services, better pricing and more transparent bills. It is possible to install micro-generation with a standard one-way meter, and Ofgem has indicated support for this option since it can be implemented at little or no cost (Ofgem, 2005)[9]. Despite this advantage, we believe that such a minimal approach would represent a missed opportunity. The deployment of micro-generation should be seen as an opportunity to kick-start the upgrade of the UK's outdated stock of domestic meters.

  As the government noted in their recent consultation document, an import-export meter has the potential to allow consumers a fair reward for the power they export to the grid. This is especially the case if the meter can collect half-hourly data that can be fed into a modified settlement system. This would mean that for any power sold to the grid at peak times—when power is most in demand and therefore most valuable—micro-generators would receive substantially more than under a flat-rate scheme. This obviously helps with the economics of micro-generation, and therefore its likely uptake.

  Going one step further, the installation of a third meter, to measure generation, would also allow those with renewable micro-generation units to claim renewable obligation certificates (ROCs). The upgrade of metering so that it has these capabilities should be mandatory when a micro-generation unit is installed. Whilst this approach is more expensive than requiring a simple one-way meter, the cost differential is likely to fall as micro-generation deployment increases. In general the additional up-front costs for import-export meters and even import-export-generation meters are very small in relation to the total investment costs.

  The changes suggested here would introduce greater transparency and fairness into the rewards given to micro-generators and, combined with the measures suggested earlier, would help to level a playing field that is currently heavily slanted against micro-generation and in favour of centralised large-scale power production. If government is serious about micro-generation it needs to implement these sorts of measures; only then will it given the opportunity to make a substantial contribution to UK energy supplies.

C.  STRATEGIC ASPECTS

  In this section we will discuss two strategic aspects: security of supply, and the need for a portfolio approach to investments in the power sector.

Security of energy supply

  Perhaps surprisingly, security of energy supply has not received much robust analytical attention. It has many dimensions, including timescale, various sources of insecurity and then some wider dimensions of security. Although it is a vitally important issue, the label "security of supply" is often appropriated by those with a particular vested interest, often in a supply technology or fuel whose costs are too high for the private market to support.

Timescales

  In terms of timescale, there are short-term concerns (will we get through next winter without power cuts?) and long-term (will we have supplies of fossil fuels at affordable prices?), as well as the question of the lead times required for infrastructure investment, as discussed above. The economic, social and environmental characteristics of the energy system we are putting in place now clearly also have substantial implications for future generations' choices.

Sources of insecurity

  Then there are concerns around various sources of insecurity. The principal ones are around: supply; technology; and networks.

  Concerns around supply include: interruptions to the supply of individual primary fuels (gas, oil etc.); the range of fuels; and securing appropriately diverse sources of these fuels.

  Too much public debate reduces security to the issue of reliance on imports, and poses an apparently stark choice between indigenous energy (secure) and imported energy (insecure). Imported energy may be more or less secure than indigenous energy, but in the face of declining domestic availability of gas and oil, imports are as likely to be a part of the solution as a cause of problems. [10]

  All else equal, a diversity of supply sources will lead to greater security, not less. And trade, normally a major objective of economic policy, usually benefits both parties, rather than one. Policy still needs to pay attention to the security of individual supply sources, and heavy reliance on one distant source of natural gas may increase insecurity. But every other major European country imports substantial quantities of its primary energy and while this does raise security issues, it does not dominate their energy policy agenda. Potential problems of energy insecurity need to be analysed across all possible sources and need an empirical answer, not pre-judgement.

  Concerns around technology and networks include: lack of integrity of infrastructures (eg gas terminals, electricity wires), and common-mode failures in energy technologies (eg in nuclear power). As demonstrated by the fuel protests several years ago, our reliance on the efficient, "just-in-time" working of the fuel infrastructure and the relative lack of redundancy in the system mean that security of supply could be at least as threatened by the shutting of, for example, a major gas terminal as any of the other potential problems identified here. And all the major electricity supply interruptions in recent years in industrial countries (eg California, New York, Italy and, on a smaller scale, London) originated in faults in the transmission or distribution systems (wires). Inadequate investment in and—especially—maintenance of electricity transmission and distribution systems are potentially major sources of serious insecurity. Bearing in mind that gas and electricity transportation are natural monopolies and therefore subject to economic regulation, regulatory practice needs to pay close attention to the incentives it gives for adequate investment and maintenance.

  Similarly, should a widely used technology develop a generic fault, it could cause significant problems for security of supply. France's reliance on one design of nuclear power plant is a case in point, although we should stress that no problems have emerged yet.

Wider dimensions of security

  Finally, some wider dimensions of security are increasingly significant, including concerns around terrorism, vulnerability, health and environment.

  Terrorism—now a major part of Government's overall policy agenda—could have an impact through several of the above processes, especially perhaps by attacking infrastructures. These could be overseas infrastructures but insofar as terrorism may target particular countries, indigenous infrastructures could also be a target. Certain supply technologies are potentially particularly attractive as a target of terrorist action while others are innately less vulnerable. These are dimensions of security that are rarely considered in the context of energy policy.

http://politics.guardian.co.uk/green/story/0,9061,1576317,00.html and on BBC online see

http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/sci/tech/4284502.stm

PORTFOLIO PERSPECTIVES

  The second strategic aspect of energy policy that we address here is the need for policy-makers to adopt a portfolio perspective in decisions around the mix of energy supply[11].

  The need for this perspective can be illustrated through the following example from another field: why do investors often hold forms of investment, such as government bonds, that apparently offer lower rates of return than other investments such as shares? The answer can be found in finance theory, specifically portfolio theory. These well-founded and widely used ideas and associated techniques show that for any given level of risk, a diverse portfolio will be lower cost (or more profitable) than a portfolio that is dominated by one sort of investment. Financial investors deal with market risk by holding efficient, diversified portfolios.

  Unfortunately, electricity planning has long relied on the stand-alone generating costs of various technologies; this measure is inadequate. This is because these cost estimates focus on the engineering/construction aspects and fail to analyse their market risk over the life cycle. In this way, they lack economic interpretation.

  Instead, we suggest that policy towards electricity investment should take account of modern portfolio theory concepts, which reflect costs but also the risk contribution a given generating technology makes to the generating mix. Our application of portfolio techniques to the energy system consistently shows that when added to a conventional generating mix, wind and other renewables serve to lower overall generating costs. This outcome, which is predicted by finance theory, holds even if it is assumed that the stand-alone costs of wind exceed those of gas-based generation. Why should this be so?

  The explanation starts from the fact that the costs of wind and other renewables technologies are largely fixed and predictable, so they add an element of stability to the portfolio. Even more important, the costs of these technologies are also independent of (technically "uncorrelated with") fossil fuel costs, further reinforcing their stabilising effects by reducing the risk and expected cost of the overall portfolio. This result is exactly analogous to diversifying financial portfolios. Similar effects would apply to nuclear investment, but—as argued earlier—there are sizeable and nuclear-specific barriers to new nuclear investment in the UK.

  We also question the idea that gas-based generation is, on a stand-alone basis, cheaper than, for example, wind. Finance theory shows that when fuel price volatility of eg gas-based electricity generation is taken into account, the overall risk-adjusted cost of these technologies is much more than suggested by the standard engineering-based estimates. Only by making such risk adjustments can one arrive at a meaningful estimate of overall costs.

  In the annex, we show that using portfolio techniques, and based on the DTI's target 2010 overall generating cost, it would be possible in principle to increase wind's share of the total from the DTI's aspiration of 11% to as much as 54%. Similarly, holding the risk profile constant, it would be possible to increase the share of wind to 31% while decreasing the overall generating cost from 2.96p/kwh to 2.49p/kwh. These are of course modelling results and wind investment is constrained by many other factors, but they strikingly illustrate the very different results, compared to stand-alone analyses, that portfolio approaches yield.

Energy security—the oil-GDP effect

  The "oil-GDP effect" provides a further reason to wish to invest in fixed-cost renewables. Our analysis shows that fuel price volatility, and over-reliance on fossil fuels, imposes costs not just on generating technologies but on society more generally.

  This is because oil price increases and volatility dampen macroeconomic growth by raising inflation and unemployment and by depressing the value of financial and other assets. This oil-GDP effect has been reported in the academic literature for a quarter of a century, although it received little attention from the media and energy policy makers prior to the recent oil price spikes. The Oil-GDP effect is sizeable. In a recent paper, members of the Sussex Energy Group[12] estimated that a 10% increase in the global share of wind (or other renewables) could help to avoid GDP losses of $95-$176 billion as a result of lower fossil fuel costs.

Annex A

SUSSEX ENERGY GROUP RESPONSE TO GOVERNMENT CONSULTATION ON MICRO-GENERATION

  See separate file. [not printed]

Annex B

VALUING GENERATING ASSETS IN AN ENVIRONMENT OF UNCERTAINTY AND TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE

Shimon Awerbuch, PhD, Senior Fellow,SPRU Energy Group, University of Sussex,Brighton, UK

www.awerbuch.com, s.awerbuch@sussex.ac.uk

  Electricity capacity expansion questions currently focus on two principal issues:

    (i)  The kilowatt-hour cost of renewables such as wind, relative to the cost of gas turbines and, potentially, nuclear power; [13]and

    (ii)  How our century-old electricity grid might be contorted into dealing with the so-called intermittency of wind and other renewable technologies.

  In this submission I argue two principal points. First, that while electricity planning has long relied on the stand-alone generating costs of various technologies, this measure is no longer relevant. In its place, I suggest that electricity policy be based on modern portfolio theory concepts, which reflect the cost as well as the risk contribution a given generating technology makes to the generating mix. Financial investors routinely use portfolio optimisation techniques to value stocks and other additions to their holdings. These techniques consistently show that when added to a conventional generating mix, wind and other fixed-cost renewables serve to lower overall generating costs. This outcome, which is predicted by finance theory, holds even if it is assumed that the stand-alone costs of wind exceed those of gas.

  Second, I argue that the current debate about the system integration costs of wind and other variable output renewables is largely misplaced. This debate conceives of wind as a direct substitute for dispatchable fossil technologies, which it is not. As a consequence, the debate needlessly dwells on such issues as the cost of additional backup generating capacity. In my opinion, efficiently integrating wind and other new, passive, variable-output renewables will ultimately require changes our current electricity production-delivery paradigms and protocols. This is a tall order. At the very least, integration will require new parallel in-formation networks for the electricity grid and most likely new ways of charging for grid services. These must allow wind-based electricity products such as space and water heating, which naturally match this "intermittent" technology with so-called "dispatchable" load applications. The century-old concept of the grid as a system for transporting commodity electrons becomes obsolete in an environment characterised by many distributed generating sources and a diversity of load applications.

1.  THE COST OF RENEWABLE AND CONVENTIONAL TECHNOLOGIES

  Electricity policy and planning decisions should not be made on the basis of traditional engineering kilowatt-hour (kWh) cost models. Such models, developed around the time of the Model-T Ford, have been widely discarded in most industries in favour of modern asset valuation concepts.

  My own stand-alone kWh cost estimate, which have remained quite constant over the last decade, use a standard (CAPM) finance-oriented approach that reflects the cost of risk. Through periods of both low and high fossil prices and money-market rates, [14]these estimates have consistently suggested that gas generation costs more than wind and many other renewables (eg Awerbuch June 2004, June 2003, May 2003, February 2003, November 2000, April 1995, 1993). This is in stark contrast to estimates prepared by the DTI (2003), the Royal Academy of Engineering, the IEA (2005) and other national and international agencies, which generally find that gas costs less than wind. These agencies however, use calculative procedures that produce cost results with no economic interpretation; they should not be given any weight in policy-making.

  Fossil fuel prices have risen significantly over the last two years and some predict oil-price spikes in excess of $100/bbl (Reuters, 2005). Finance theory tells us that future cost streams can be meaningfully expressed only in terms of their market risk. When fuel price volatility is considered, gas-based generation is noticeably more costly than standard engineering-based estimates indicate. For example, conventional estimates such as those produced by DTI and IEA suggest that gas-based electricity costs in the range of

0.03-

0.05/kWh. The true, risk-adjusted cost is quite likely in excess of

0.06-

0.07/kWh, making many renewables generally competitive. [15]

2.  EXTERNALITY BENEFITS OF WIND: ENHANCING COST AND ENERGY SECURITY

  Risk-adjusted CAPM procedures more reliably estimate the cost of gas and wind. But even CAPM results are only as good as the underlying gas price forecasts, which could dramatically change even before this inquiry is concluded. Meaningful kWh cost estimates require unbiased gas price forecasts. But history provides little comfort that today's fossil price forecasts will be any more reliable than those of the past. Nonetheless, suppose we assume for the moment that the conventional analyses—which predict that gas generation costs less—are correct. Does this imply that we should abandon wind and other options and invest only in gas? This is the traditional "least-cost" approach to energy investment decision-making. It makes little sense in today's highly uncertain energy environment.

  Energy planners need follow financial investors, who are used to dealing with risk. No one can predict the performance of a corporate share of stock over 20 years just as no one can predict the price of gas. Financial investors deal with market risk by holding efficient, diversified portfolios. These offer the best hedge against an uncertain future. Prudent investors do not try to chase today's best performing securities; these may be the laggards of tomorrow. Rather, they balance their portfolios with a mixture of potentially high yielding securities along with low-yielding government obligations and similar "safe" investments. Policy makers must take note of this important idea. It matters little that gas might appear to be the lowest cost alternative (on the basis of conventional costing models). Even if correct today, that picture could change dramatically, suggesting that electricity planning and energy policy making in general must abandon its fixation with identifying alternatives with the lowest stand-alone cost and focus instead on developing optimal generating portfolios and strategies.

  When added to a risky, fossil-dominated generating mix, wind and other fixed-cost renewables reduce generating cost and risk, as long as the mix can be altered over time [Awerbuch 2005, February 2000, 1995, Awerbuch and Berger 2003]. This so-called portfolio effect, (eg see Brealey and Myers, 2003) holds even if wind costs more on a stand-alone basis. Wind's generating costs are uncorrelated to fossil costs which means that it diversifies the mix and reduces expected overall cost and risk the same way diversification improves the expected performance of financial portfolios.

  For example, DTI's Year-2010 target generating mix (DTI, 2004, 2003) has an overall cost of 2.96 p/kWh (Table 1). It consists of 71% fossil generation and 11% wind. By contrast, applying the same generating costs, it is possible to identify a number of optimised UK portfolios[16] which cost no more, but have wind shares of 31% to as much as 54%—three to five times as much wind as the DTI target mix. The "Equal Cost" portfolio, (Table 1) has the same cost but lower risk than the DTI target mix, yet contains 31% offshore wind, in spite of the fact that this technology is assumed to cost 75% more than gas. [17]

Table 1

DTI TARGETS VERSUS OPTIMISED GENERATING PORTFOLIOS (UK 2010)
DTI 2000-2010 Technology Generating Costs (p/kWh): Coal: 4.0/3.6—Gas: 2.0/1.9—Wind: 2.7/2.0—Offshore: ¸/3.6
Typical Optimised Portfolios
DTI 2010
Target Portfolio "Equal Cost""Equal Risk"
Portfolio Cost2.96 p/kWh 2.96 p/kWh2.49 p/kWh
Portfolio Risk .08 .04 .08
Fossil Share 71% 32% 52%
Nuclear Share 16% 12% 14%
Wind Share On-shore: 11% Offshore: 0% On-shore: 25% Offshore: 31% On-shore: 31% Offshore: 0%
Source: Awerbuch Airtricity (2005)


  These results are not meant to suggest that 50% wind shares are feasible given today's network architecture, or even that such a target cold be attained in five years. The results are presented to illustrate that stand-alone costs, even if adjusted for risk, are not necessarily a meaningful metric for evaluating energy options. Because various technology costs move in unison, (eg are correlated), intelligent energy strategy, by necessity, requires that cost interrelationships be considered. Electricity capacity planning must reflect the cost and risk of the overall portfolio.

  The UK results shown above are representative of similar, and in some ways even stronger results I have obtained for the US, the EU, as well as Mexico, Morocco, and other nations (Awerbuch, 2005, Awerbuch, Jansen and Beurskens, 2003). The portfolio approach illustrates the idea that increasing the deployment of wind, even if it is assumed to cost more, does not necessarily raise overall generating cost, as long as the generating mix can be re-optimized over time. Wind production costs are relatively fixed. This creates important cost-risk benefits for generating portfolios.

Energy Security—The Oil-GDP Effect

  Oil price increases and volatility dampen macroeconomic growth by raising inflation and unemployment and by depressing the value of financial and other assets. This so-called Oil-GDP effect has been reported in the academic literature for a quarter of a century, although it received little attention from the media and energy policy makers prior to the recent oil price spikes. The Oil-GDP effect is sizeable. In a recent paper Raphael Sauter and I (2005) estimate that a 10 percentage-point increase in the global share of wind (or other renewables) can help avoid GDP losses of $95-$176 billion (Table 2).

Table 2

WIND DEPLOYMENT OFFSETS SIZEABLE MACROECONOMIC OIL-GDP LOSSES

AVOIDED GDP LOSSES FOR 10-PERCENTAGE-POINT INCREASE IN THE WIND GENERATION SHARE (USD $BILLIONS)
USEU-15 OECDWorld
2003 GDP$10,882 $10,970$18,659$36,356
Avoided GDP Losses

High Estimate
$53 $53$90$176
Low Estimate$29$29 $49$95
Source: Awerbuch and Sauter, 2005


  These avoided losses offset 20% of the renewables investment needed to meet 2020 EU RES-E targets and 40% the OECD requirements. Our analysis suggests that each additional kW of wind helps society avoid $250 in GDP losses. Stated differently, avoided GDP losses offset 20-25% of today's investments in wind and other renewables.

  Energy security is enhanced when nations hold optimal generating mixes that minimize exposure to fossil volatility. As the last two sections have described, wind and other renewables provide a joint set of benefits: they enhance energy diversity/security while they reduce overall generating costs (Awerbuch, Stirling, Jansen and Beurskens 2006).

3.  MODERNISING POWER NETWORKS TO ACCOMMODATE 21ST CENTURY NEEDS

  Widespread debate prevails about how to manage wind's variable-output[18] and how to make it fit into today's electricity production-delivery system, designed over a century ago for dispatchable, fossil-fired central station generation. Had a different generating technology emerged in the 1890's, it would have no doubt given rise to a different set of network system architecture and protocols. But we are stuck with our system—at least for time being. System engineers have been weaned on dispatchable technologies with central control. It is difficult for them to imagine anything else: they see the challenge as making wind fit into the system. I see the challenge as rearranging the electricity production-delivery paradigm to accommodate a variety of 21st Century needs, including the integration of wind and other variable-output sources.

  Many new process technologies have faced significant impediments to their integration and were fully exploited only after underlying systems and infrastructures were extensively modified. We tend to conceptualise new technologies in terms of the capabilities and functionalities of the previous vintages that we better understand. This was true for word processing, which was initially conceived merely as a replacement for the typewriter, and is true for wind. How do engineers want to integrate wind? By making it act like a gas turbine (as much as possible) so it can be centrally dispatched by the control room operator, just the way it has been done for a nearly a century. Fully integrating wind will likely require new approaches, including different system architecture and protocols and powerful parallel information networks to manage electricity grids in a decentralized, market-responsive manner.

  We need to alter the electricity production-delivery system to better accommodate 21st century needs and capabilities. This involves adopting mass-customisation concepts from manufacturing and moving decision making to loads, which have better information about their hour-to-hour requirements than a central dispatcher. At any moment, the system's total load consists of thousands of transactions, each with a different value. Electricity to power water pumping or heating likely does not have the same value as electricity required for microchip processing (Awerbuch, March 2004, July-August 2004). Adapting to these realities will yield a more efficient, more market-oriented production-delivery paradigm under which the network operator becomes the electricity market enabler. The traditional transportation function of the network becomes obsolete in an environment characterized by a large number of distributed resources.

  Today's network is based on outmoded mass-production concepts. Electricity mass customisation will allow users to take power in the forms that best match their various applications. Implementing these ideas requires new strategies for regulating network system operators, who hold a key position in an electricity system that has been partially deregulated in the belief that markets, not regulation, produce the greatest efficiency (Awerbuch, Hyman, Vesey, 1999, Chap 3). Yet the system operator continues as a monopoly entity with no incentives to create new market-driven products or to diversify the mix to broaden consumer access to competitively priced supply markets that include traditional generation along with wind and other renewables.

  Policy-makers correctly focused on deregulating generation first. Much of the potential benefit of those policies however is lost because the essential market facilitator, the transmission operator, is naively conceived as a caretaker of the wires with no incentive to enhance overall system performance. Efficient integration and exploitation of wind may have to wait until policy-makers focus on the governance, organization, regulation and pricing structures of electricity networks.

4.  CONCLUSIONS

  CAPM-based risk-adjusted procedures suggest that at currently projected gas prices, wind and other fixed cost renewables are likely to provide electricity at lower cost. Moreover, when added to fossil-dominated generating mixes, fixed-cost renewable technologies reduce cost at any level of risk by virtue of the portfolio-effect. This holds even if they are assumed to cost more on a stand-alone basis.

  Wind and similar fixed-cost technologies enhance energy security and their deployment will help the UK avoid costly macroeconomic (GDP) consequences induced by oil price volatility. Every kW investment in wind offsets $250 USD in oil-induced GDP losses. The benefits of wind and other renewables are strong, verifiable and highly certain. Our challenge is to re-engineer the electricity production-delivery paradigm so it efficiently integrates variable-output renewables and meets other 21st century requirements.

REFERENCES

Awerbuch, S (2005), "Portfolio-Based Electricity Generation Planning: Policy Implications for Renewables and Energy Security," Mitigation and Adaptation Strategies for Climate Change, in-press

(July-August, 2004), Restructuring Electricity Networks: decentralization, mass-customization and intermittency, Cogeneration and On-Site Power Production

 (June, 2004), "Towards A Finance-Oriented Valuation of Conventional and Renewable Energy Sources in Ireland," Dublin: Sustainable Energy Ireland, June

www.sei.ie/uploads/documents/upload/publications/shimon_awerbuch_paper_Jun-25.doc

(March, 2004), "Restructuring Our Electricity Networks to Promote Decarbonization: Decentralization, Mass-Customization and Intermittent Renewables in the 21st Century," Tyndall Centre Working Paper No 49; www.tyndall.ac.uk/publications/working_papers/wp49.pdf

(June 2003) "Is gas really cheapest?" Modern Power Systems, 17-19

(February 2003) "Determining the real cost: Why renewable power is more cost-competitive than previously believed", Renewable Energy World, www.jxj.com/magsandj/rew/2003_02/real_cost.html

(May, 2003) "The True Cost of Fossil-Fired Electricity in the EU: A CAPM-based Approach," Power Economics

(February 2000) "Getting It Right: The Real Cost Impacts of a Renewables Portfolio Standard," Public Utilities Fortnightly, February 15

(November 2000), "Investing in Photovoltaics: Risk, Accounting and the Value of New Technology," Energy Policy, Special Issue, Vol 28, No 14

(1995) "New Economic Cost Perspectives For Valuing Solar Technologies," in, Karl W Bo­er, (editor) Advances in Solar Energy: An Annual Review of Research and Development, Vol 10, Boulder: ASES

(April 1995) "Market-Based IRP: It's Easy!" Electricity Journal, Vol 8, No 3, 50-67

(1993) "The Surprising Role of Risk and Discount Rates in Utility Integrated-Resource Planning," The Electricity Journal, Vol 6, No 3, (April), 20-33.

and M Berger, (2003) Energy Security and Diversity in the EU: A Mean-Variance Portfolio Approach, IEA Report Number EET/2003/03, Paris: February http://library.iea.org/dbtw-wpd/textbase/papers/2003/port.pdf

Hyman, L S and Vesey, A (1999), Unlocking the Benefits of Restructuring: A Blueprint for Transmission, Vienna, VA: PUR, Inc.

J Jansen and L Beurskens, (2003), Portfolio-based Generation Planning: Implications for Renewables and Energy Security, REEEP, British Foreign and Commonwealth Office, London, and United Nations Environment Programme, Paris,

www.sefi.unep.org/docs/xPortfolio-Based-Electricity%20Planning-UNEP-FCO-MAy-19-04.pdf

Sauter, R (2005), "Exploiting the oil-GDP Effect to support Renewables Deployment," Energy Policy, articles in press, 21 June, www.sciencedirect

Stirling, A C, Jansen J, and Beurskens, L, [2006] "Portfolio and Diversity Analysis of Energy Technologies Using Full-Spectrum Risk Measures," in: D Bodde, K Leggio and M Taylor (Eds) Understanding and Managing Business Risk in the Electric Sector, Elsevier Topics in Global Energy Regulation, Finance and Policy

Brealey, R and Myers, S (2003) Principles of Corporate Finance, McGrawHill (any edition)

Dale, L, Milborrow, D, Slark, R & Strbac, G, (2004) Total Cost Estimates for Large-scale Wind Scenarios in UK, Energy Policy, Vol 32, No 17

DENA Grid Study (February, 2005), Planning of the Grid Integration of Wind Energy in Germany Onshore and Offshore up to the Year 2020

www.ewea.org/documents/Dena%20Grid%20Study_Summary_2005-03-16_dena.pdf

DTI (2003) Economics Paper No 4, Options for a Low-Carbon Future, June

DTI (2004) DTI Energy Projections, ANNEX D: Electricity Generation by Fuel Type p 74.

http://www.dti.gov.uk/energy/inform/energy_projections/ep68_final.pdf

IEA (2005) Projected Costs of Generating Electricity, Paris, Nuclear Energy Agency—International Energy Agency—OECD.

Reuters, (2005) "Super Spike: Goldman Sachs predicts oil over $100," 31 March

3 October 2005






1   This section is largely based on G MacKerron "What price another?" Parliamentary Brief Energy Special Report, September-October 2005, pp 11-12. Back

2   G MacKerron "Nuclear power and the characteristics of `ordinariness': the case of UK energy policy" Energy Policy, 32:17, November 2004, pp 1957-1966. Back

3   DTI Our Energy Future: Creating a Low-Carbon Economy February 2003. Back

4   Oxera Financing the nuclear option: modelling the costs of new build Agenda, June 2005, Table 1. Back

5   For coverage of these ideas in the Guardian see Back

6   The precise "capacity credit" of micro-generation would depend on the technology and the operating regime. Some initial estimates can be found in Hawkes, A and Leach, M (2005) The Capacity Credit of Micro Combined Heat and Power in the UK Proceedings of the BIEE Academic Conference, Oxford 22-23 September. Back

7   Chesshire, J (2003) Energy Efficiency Projects and Policies for Step Changes in the Energy System: Developing an Agenda for Social Science Research, ESRC Seminar, Policy Studies Institute, March. Back

8   Mott MacDonald (2004) System Integration of Additional Micro-generation Report to the DTI. Back

9   Ofgem (2005) The regulatory implications of domestic-scale micro-generation-a consultation document Ofgem, April. Back

10   A very good exposition of this and other views of the security debate with respect to gas is J Stern "UK gas security: time to get serious" Energy Policy 32:17, November 2004, pp 1967-1979. Back

11   This section is a summary of fuller arguments made in Annex B. Back

12   Awerbuch, S and Sauter, R. (2005), "Exploiting the oil-GDP Effect to support Renewables Deployment," Energy Policy, articles in press, 21 June. Back

13   This is not to say that other issues, such nuclear waste are not also prominent. Back

14   Inflation expectations and money-market rates underlie CAPM-based discount rates. Back

15   The cost advantage of wind survives when system integration charges are added, eg per Dale, et al (2004) or the DENA Grid Study (2005). Back

16   An infinite number of such portfolios exist, all with different cost-risk and different technology shares. Back

17   This study focuses on wind. Nuclear output is constrained so it does not exceed 2004 levels. Back

18   The concept of wind intermittency is misleading. Wind blows a high percentage of the year, at least at better sites, although its force varies so that output is variable. There are very few days when wind ceases entirely implying that variable-output is a better concept. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2006
Prepared 16 April 2006