Figure 4
PRICE BEHAVIOUR IN HIGHLY COMPETITIVE MARKETS
15. According to economic theory, such high peak prices
should encourage developers to build new stations, or customers
to reduce their load. However, there are good reasons to believe
that such a mechanism may not operate smoothly:
Developers will recognise that, in such a visible
market, they will only be able to enjoy returns during these "spikes.
Thus the timing of the commissioning of a new station will have
a large impact on the financial performance of a new station.
Given such uncertainties, investors will require large discount
rates, effectively driving prices higher.
The timing of such a peak in the UK would not, necessarily,
coincide with any on the continent. Therefore, it may become difficult
for the Government to tolerate large rises in the price of power
when they are not mirrored by similar increases in those of British
industry's continental competitors. This might cause the Government
to intervene, such as by applying a price cap. Even if the Government
did not take such action, potential developers would believe it
would represent a risk, thereby increasing the price they would
require to see before they committed to construction.
16. Economists would also argue that a market in long
term contracts will develop, effectively smoothing the price peaks,
making them more acceptable. However, such a market has not developed,
despite liberalised markets having operated since 1990 and NETA
having operated for three years, so it is not just a question
of maturity. The reason why a liquid market in long contracts
at prices that would encourage new entry has not emerged is that
no-one would want to commit to buy power for extended periods
at prices far higher than their competitors, even though, over
the longer term, it may prove cheaper. There is an analogy with
the oil market. This market is hardly immature, but no such long
term market has developed. This is a consequence of the final
market for petroleum products being so highly competitive. The
same is true for the market for industrial power in the UK, though
to a lesser extent for supplies to the domestic sector. Therefore,
suppliers of energy in the UK are sensibly not signing such long
term contracts. Indeed, such contracts were the reason for the
demise of TXU Europe.
17. Of course, over time, suppliers' reluctance to sign
longer term, fully priced, contracts may weaken, especially in
the face of increasing demand and as they gain confidence that
various segments of their customer base are not price sensitive.
However, at present, it is highly unlikely that suppliers will
be willing to commit to purchase power for long periods at prices
that reflect new entry costs. Thus a developer building a station
in a highly competitive market will need to be confident that
the station will commission just before a "peak", if
any returns to capital are to be made. Developers naturally choose
to build plant with short construction periodsand so favour
gas plant over clean coal and nuclear. However, we are seeing
that, in this market, even gas could be problematic since power
station developers cannot be sure that they will be able to enjoy
returns to capital.
18. The obstacles to the construction of new capacity
could be removed were the suppliers willing to enter into longer
term contracts, but such willingness is only likely to emerge
if the markets are less competitive. The alternative, is to place
additional obligations on suppliers to purchase capacity.
CONCLUSION
19. It therefore appears that some changes may be required
to the wholesale power market in Britain before developers commit
to the construction of any new capacity; be it nuclear, clean
coal and perhaps even gas. Of course, the construction of renewable
forms of generation is likely to proceed, on account of the support
provided by the Renewables Obligation, but that will not satisfy
the anticipated need for base-load generation.
29 September 2005
24