Select Committee on Environmental Audit Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 500-516)

DR DIETER HELM

16 NOVEMBER 2005

  Q500 Chairman: Who makes the decision? Are industry and the Government getting involved, because the whole benefit of your approach is that it keeps the Government out of these sorts of decisions. Who does take the decision?

  Dr Helm: Lots of these particular forms of costs are costs that will be reflected by properly pricing the different bits; for example, the cost of intermittency is priced through the market, the cost of the transmission systems required to back up the wind should be passed through to wind. They are not at the moment, but they should. In some senses that is both good regulation and properly designed markets. Residual risks in areas like water companies, electricity distribution companies, have ring-fencing, special administrative provisions etc. It could be a regulatory issue, it could be for regulatory bodies, it could be for the energy agency to do so but, remember, I have got capacity auctions going on here, so the contract form that people bid for would specify that these things have to be covered. I do not think it is rocket science. I think in contracting terms normally these sorts of things go on. My guess is it would probably be either the organiser of the capacity auction or the energy agency, or both.

  Q501 Emily Thornberry: I am concerned about your reliance on this idea of auctioning long-term carbon contracts, because, for the same sorts of reasons, we have just had, have we not, the fiasco of the new generation of mobile phone technology and people bidding too high, and then those who bid too high going bankrupt. The same could happen here, could it not? You could have people bidding for long-term carbon contracts and then simply going bankrupt. Your system is so dependent on these things—

  Dr Helm: It is clearly my fault for not explaining the concept correctly. What you bid for in a long-term carbon contract is you bid for a price to be paid for the tonnes of carbon actually saved. If we had a contract for 2015 to 2030, wind might put in £4 per tonne, nuclear might put in £5 or £2, somebody else might put £10 in per tonne. This is an obligation for HMT to pay whatever the lowest bid is for carbon. In my proposal, of course, this is not a public expenditure constraint because the Government then sells the contract in to the Emissions Trading Scheme when and as the Emissions Trading Scheme after 2012 is further developed. Somebody has got to pay for the carbon emission reduction. If you have a nuclear obligation, a renewables obligation for wind, the customer is underwriting the cost for those carbon reductiona. In my world, I am using emissions trading in the long run to be a mechanism by which carbon is financed. The problem is, we do not have an emissions trading regime beyond 2012 yet, nor are we likely to have the binding targets required to get there.

  Q502 Emily Thornberry: But I do not follow, you see, why if someone bids for this contract, let us say nuclear bids for those contracts, and they simply bid for too low a price—

  Dr Helm: There are two possibilities. It is very important to understand what I am saving the Government underwriting if there was to be a nuclear programme. In the renewables obligation and in a nuclear obligation, you basically underwrite all the costs of a project. They are passed through to the customers. In my world, I did not want the Treasury, or anybody else, any customer, to underwrite the construction costs or how long it takes for the plant to produce the output or its performance. That is what we underpinned in the event of Dungeness B when it took 22 years to produce a spark. All I want to underwrite is the carbon cost. If the station does not come on on time, it does not get paid until it comes on and if it never comes on, it never gets paid. In other words, this is only a payment for actual carbon saved when it occurs. When that occurs, given the way carbon objectives are going and the constraints—remember, this is not the entire carbon reduction requirement being auctioned, it is only a part—there will be lots of companies desperate to buy permits to pollute as they did under the emissions trading, so these are the natural counterparts to those contracts. Wind would have a problem too if wind bids for these contracts and it wins the contract and it does not work, or it is intermittent and its forecast is 30% and it turns out to be 15%, it is going to be a shortfall. Of course, what does that do to the project developer? They might go bust.

  Q503 Emily Thornberry: What does it do to the country if it goes bust? You are talking about the importance of securing our supply and yet you are setting this up.

  Dr Helm: No, you cannot have investment in base-load capacity of the electricity system without risk. Any form of investment might not work. If you thought that recklessly international companies were bidding to do things where they were clearly going to go bust in the process of doing it, this would be something that would give you immense concern. The corollary of that is, never ever take the risk of investing in a long term, large scale base-load power station system, because it might not work. That is true, but we are not given the luxury of being able to say that we have dead cert technologies which are definitely going to produce in 2016 or 2018. It is a risk that has to be taken, that it might not work and that is why in general one prefers, for example, technology which is second generation rather than first; for example you would, if you were doing nuclear power, want to choose well known PWRs rather than the latest cutting edge innovation. That was the mistake that was made in the 1970s picking the AGRs. In wind turbines, you clearly do not want the latest design that someone says might work in 15 years' time; you want something that is predictable, because you want that security. You cannot avoid risk. You cannot have investment in the power stations by the private sector of any form without there being risk involved. The question is, is the risk priced properly? You may take the view that the risk of a particular technology is so great that you want to rule it out. Where I come from, I could see risks with all these technologies and I would not want to be faced with the huge mountain of climate change to address to rule out any technologies purely on that kind of risk but it does have a price.

  Chairman: I am conscious of the need to move on.

  Q504 Mark Pritchard: Do you think that the climate change debate would be better served by knowing more about energy efficiency, both on the transmission of energy, the supply side, but also on the demand side, from the consumers and indeed, a big customer, such as the Government, which is perhaps the worst offender, of whatever political complexion? Just look at the energy efficiency of the Palace of Westminster across the road. Do you think we need to hear more from Government and, indeed, the industry on efficiency?

  Dr Helm: Clearly at this point we need to consider and hear a lot about lots of the possible options. On energy efficiency I have a particular, very strong view. We need to have a debate which is not based on the premise that energy efficiency is free and the net present value of a very large amount of energy reduction could be done at zero cost. The debate that is being led by the energy efficiency lobby, to convince people that the costs of these types of energy demand reduction are just trivial in total burden, has misled us quite considerably. Indeed, I would say that is why we are in the mess we are in on the Climate Change Review, because it has suddenly been realised that the objective of energy efficiency would require quite substantial public expenditure and, of course, the Energy White Paper leads us to believe that there is not any public expenditure of substance that is required. So I think that a grown up debate, in which people are told, this is not a free lunch, it is expensive, may be the best possible way forward. I do not rule that out at all, but I think people have been systematically led to believe that it is all much more rosy than it actually is.

  Q505 Mark Pritchard: My supplementary is, the Energy Minister last week in the House suggested that the lights would not go out in Britain this winter unless we had a 1:50 winter. Is that your view?

  Dr Helm: My view is that that is not even the most important question.

  Q506 Mark Pritchard: Sorry, that is the question that I asked.

  Dr Helm: I am going to answer it. Supply will always equal demand in electricity; there is a physical requirement that the system must balance. The question is, at what price? That is what I mean by the question. If you say, is there a security of supply problem this winter? Yes. Is there a security of supply problem even if the lights do not go out? Yes. It is in the price. That is our security of supply crisis. That is what happens when supply and demand come close together. If we lose the power for a couple of days, that would be very serious but we are already having the impact of that security of supply problem right now, and that is the price that everyone is paying.

  Q507 Mr Hurd: May I bring you back to climate change piece and two specific questions about your idea of auctioning long-term carbon contracts. Just to be clear, are you suggesting that this is something that a British Government would be struggling to meet, that its climate change targets should consider on a unilateral basis, or does this idea only fly on the precondition that there is a new international, multilateral agreement on carbon reductions post-2012?

  Dr Helm: The answer to that is it would always be better to do it internationally, because global warming is an international problem not a domestic one, but note that I want the contracts to be a lot less than the amount of reductions we will have to make in almost any scenario. We do not have the luxury of saying, "Let's forget about what base-load we invest in. Let's build some coal plants and gas plants because we will think about how to solve this problem when we get there." We will have to reduce emissions anyway and some chunk of that will relate to the replacement of the base-load of the electricity system, which is the decision to make now. Therefore I think the UK should pursue a long-term carbon contract cautious policy in any event, to get the incentives right now, because this is the historical moment when our base-load energy electricity production is turned over. If you do not do it now, what you are going to have is a lot of gas stations which are going to last for the next 20 or 30 years and you have missed the opportunity, because the cost of closing stations that are in mid-life is enormously greater than using that unique opportunity, decade opportunities, when the capital stock rotates.

  Q508 Mr Hurd: May I ask you to expand on what value you see the carbon contract idea adding to the concept of emissions trading which has started and which it is argued is not going far enough because of the absence of a framework of long-term carbon contracts? Should not Government be focused on making the emissions trading work? What value does carbon contracts add to emissions trading?

  Dr Helm: The problem with emissions trading is the emissions trading regime is very short-term. It has virtually no effect on investment as it currently is and it has no effect on R&D, because the time horizon that we know for the emissions permits goes to 2008. It is completely irrelevant to the investment cycle and to R&D. What you want to do is give long-term signals to this market. In 2012 there are no internationally yet known targets at all, and without targets you cannot have emissions trading, full stop.

  Q509 Mr Hurd: My point is that if you could get those targets, would not emissions trading get you where you want to get to? In that context, do not these contracts just complicate the picture?

  Dr Helm: If you had long-term emissions targets, you would have long-term carbon contracts, QED. It just happens. I have devised this as a second best. I do not think governments are going to agree quick enough what the target is going to be and we need to get our own investment and know what those are going to be. Note one other characteristic of my carbon contract world: it gives the Treasury a fantastic incentive to promote the continuation of emissions trading afterwards, because that is the way it unbundles these contracts into the market and gets out of any liability it has.

  Q510 Mr Hurd: What sorts of signal would the UK be sending if we basically said we do not believe in the pace at which emissions trading is working; we want to replace it with our own system of carbon contracts?

  Dr Helm: It is not replacing—it is perfectly consistent with emissions trading; and that is the distinction. Remember, what is your alternative? You can have a renewables obligation or are you going to have a nuclear obligation if it is nuclear power you want to do? These are all long-term carbon contracts. They are just in the renewables obligation and a nuclear obligation, a very expensive way of doing it, because you are underwriting not only the long-term carbon, but the construction costs and the performance costs as well. The world in which there are not any targets going forward and no long-term carbon contracts, the world to compare that with is a world where there is neither that, nor a renewables obligation, nor a nuclear obligation, and all the wind collapses as well. It is not a luxury choice we have. We are in an investment phase, it is a risky phase, we have got to get the incentive structure right and get on with it. The contracts are just a much more economically efficient way than the renewables obligation or a nuclear obligation of achieving that. They do not pick winners either, which the renewables obligation most certainly does, and so would a nuclear obligation.

  Q511 Dr Turner: Would your carbon contracts deal with emerging technologies? It seems to me that they are a great disincentive, that they simply do not recognise the possibility of bringing forward new technologies, particularly marine technologies, which have great potential but at the moment obviously cannot compete at a commercial rate. Is not your carbon contract idea far too rigid to deal with those?

  Dr Helm: No. The problem of emerging technology is further out. First of all, I do not imagine this is a one off game of contracts. There will be repeated contracts going out into the future. It tells people there is going to be a carbon price. It gives them more certainty about a carbon price in the long run which should encourage R&D, but it is not enough, because the other problem that emerging technologies have is the classic R&D problem: no market will—

  Q512 Dr Turner: Your paper does not seem to take account of that.

  Dr Helm: No, it is complementary to this. Nothing in my paper says we should not have a very coherent R&D policy as well, but if you want to encourage people to go and invest in R&D for non-carbon technologies, it is a good way to do it, to tell them that we are devising a system that is giving a long-term price signal to carbon. Put it the other way round: supposing we do not, we do not have any signal for carbon prices. What we are saying is politically the framework going forward is one which may not reward carbon properly.

  Q513 Dr Turner: I agree with you; we need a carbon price signal, but this is not the only possible carbon price signal that we could use. You have not answered my point, because let us say R&D is financed separately, but the actual cost reductions that you get only come with commercial use on a reasonably large scale and your carbon contracts just do not allow for that.

  Dr Helm: When it becomes commercial, that is fine.

  Q514 Dr Turner: It cannot become commercial until it has been there.

  Dr Helm: I am thoroughly with you on that. That has always been a problem with developing any new technologies in the energy sector and that is why people have demonstration plants, they have support for that, that is why the discussion of the hydrogen plant in Scotland is on the basis of what kind of support framework would go out with it. The core of this is you still need a price of carbon and what my system does is to give you a price of carbon going forward and that is incredibly important to investors in R&D as in other technologies. It is not sufficient, I am with you, on that entirely.

  Q515 Emily Thornberry: Why is the Government well placed to make a decision on additional costs of that nature, but is not well placed to make a decision on what technologies we should use?

  Dr Helm: Because, in the case of R&D, the market failures are so great that it is unavoidable that you have to have some technology basis of your R&D policy. You just cannot avoid it. It is a bit of an institutional way of doing it, but once you have got up and running, proven technologies that work, it really is a question of cutting through all the lobbying, cutting through all the ways in which particular technological interests promote themselves and turning to the market and saying, "What is the price you wish to pursue?" What I find with the idea of using markets in carbon is, those technologies that think that they might not win an auction are against it, and those that think that they might win it, are in favour of it. I do not know the answer; all I know is that Government's estimates of the price of different technologies—and reflected in the White Paper really deeply in the estimates of the costs of renewables of various forms and of nuclear power—in the past historically turned out to be wrong, in some cases, staggeringly wrong. I turn to my political scientist colleagues to explain to me why people get attracted by thinking that nuclear power is too cheap to meter or they think that wind should be paid transmission costs, or whatever. I want the market to sort that out; I want investors to take over this, not taxpayers. In the case of having obligations for specific technologies, the very interesting thing is, the end result would be that customers will be told they will underwrite it, and that is just as much a cost as would be a subsidy of tax.

  Chairman: I am afraid we are going to have to end the session. There are a number of other issues that we would like to raise with you, but I am afraid that we may have to do them in writing.

  Q516 David Howarth: What is the reaction of the various promoters of different types of technology to your project? From what you just said, I think that might be rather an interesting thing to know.

  Dr Helm: At the moment the main scepticism comes from those who are interested in things like wind and in particular the types of renewable technology. I would say the nuclear industry is probably fairly sceptical too, but if the nuclear industry believes that their power plants are economic at current oil prices—and I am addressing the carbon question there—what I am really saying to the nuclear industry and the wind industry, "Well, I do not know what the costs are. You come forward with your projects. You bid. You put the price on the table." The market will not necessarily get it right, but my argument is, the Government will almost certainly get it more wrong than the market will, and history, I think, is on my side.

  Chairman: On that note we will say thank you very much indeed; it has been a very stimulating and interesting session and I am sorry we have run out of time.

  Dr Helm: There is a separate paper on the detail of carbon contracts that I can provide to the Committee.

  Chairman: That will be very helpful, too, thank you. Many thanks.





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2006
Prepared 16 April 2006