Select Committee on Environmental Audit Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 200-219)

MR DUNCAN BRACK, MS JADE SAUNDERS AND MS EMILY FRIPP

1 NOVEMBER 2005

  Q200  Chairman: So if we can move on to timber procurement and compare with what has happened here in the UK with CPET, with other European countries? How do you think we fare in relation to Germany, Netherlands, France and Denmark, to what they are doing?

  Mr Brack: I think we compare very well. I think the UK policy is both more effective and more worked through and has come into effect quicker than most other countries. What my concern is slightly—and I alluded to this in my written evidence—that at the moment you are seeing five EU countries develop procurement policy along slightly different lines. So everybody is developing it differently, which potentially creates barriers to people aiming to import into the EU because they have to know information about the five different schemes. I think there is a role to be played by the European Commission in helping to at least make the provision of information about procurement policies easier for people outside of the EU. The second thing, which I think is quite disappointing, is that 20 Member States out of the 25 are making no progress whatever on timber procurement, and so if it is possible for the UK and successive presidencies to encourage these countries to do something more about it as an element of the FLEGT Action Plan, then I think that would be extremely helpful. But I think that the UK itself has developed a model that is worthy of emulation by other countries.

  Q201  Chairman: But there has been some criticism from NGOs of CPET, has there not?

  Mr Brack: Yes.

  Q202  Chairman: Is that justified?

  Mr Brack: On the certification schemes and the extent to which it has judged those, I would like to hand that over to Emily, who has worked on this more than I have.

  Ms Fripp: I am not a certification expert, but the bit that I know about, the assessment side, it is reported that on the initial assessment, PEFC and SFI did fail on the criteria that Saskia was mentioning beforehand—PEFC on the unbalanced approach to standard setting and SFI on its audit systems. Both schemes responded within a three or four-month period and got back and tried to change and address the criticisms that were given by CPET. Whether they addressed them to the level that perhaps NGOs would like, I do not know; and I am not in a position to judge. But I think considering that there has been debate and pressure on those key issues for a number of years by NGOs to the certification scheme, and the fact that CPET manage to get change within a period of months—regardless of whether it is enough, the process there is for continual review—I think that is a significant impact of CPET moving forward.

  Mr Brack: Could I add briefly that the principle of CPET is an important thing, which other countries do not seem to have? You have to have some way of assessing existing certification schemes but also allowing companies that are not certified at all to prove that they are meeting the same standards. There is an important element of WTO and EU procurement rules, and therefore I think it is a very logical response to set up a body like CPET, and that possibly ought to be developed EU-wide in the long-term.

  Q203  Chairman: What would you say would be CPET's ten greatest achievements to date?

  Mr Brack: It is too soon to tell.

  Q204  Chairman: Their two greatest achievements to date?

  Mr Brack: In coming into existence. In assessing the certification schemes, I think you can certainly make criticisms of that and that is worth looking at. But in setting up a mechanism to assess alternative forms of documentation for people who are not certified, which, as I said, is an important part of any procurement rules.

  Q205  Chairman: You were saying earlier on about the five different European schemes where you had a fear that they were moving to an unlevel playing field in respect of timber procurement. I am moving on to the  WTO rules, and I am keen to question you, Mr Brack, about how you could see a sustainable timber procurement policy being compatible with WTO rules. I have read with interest the evidence you have given to us. Are you actually saying to us that if the government wanted to, if the UK wanted to, if it took the leadership role within the EU, that there would be nothing to stop the EU within the WTO coming up with just such a policy in respect of procurement?

  Mr Brack: Yes, I think so. I do not think that WTO rules are very important constraints on the EU Member States, partly because the WTO agreement on government procurement has been signed by relatively few States and by no important tropical timber exporting companies, but largely because the EU procurement rules are far more detailed. They build on the same principles as the WTO procurement agreement anyway, but they are much more important constraints for the UK and other Member States. But I think that they give enough latitude to allow Member States to impose quite tough standards for sustainability. I think a more important constraint is the lack of availability of sustainable timber in the market place. So I think again that the UK and others are right to say, "We will make sure that legal timber is the basic requirement, but above that we will go for sustainable timber where it is available." The big debate I think is about the extent to which you can incorporate social standards, for example the treatment of forest dependent people, indigenous communities within your procurement policy. It is clear that there is substantial disagreement here. The UK has interpreted so far the EU procurement directives as not allowing that. Other countries appear to interpret them as allowing that. I think it is a substantial area of uncertainty. Partly we have no idea because there has never been a dispute case on this before the European Court of Justice following from the new EU procurement directives. So the interpretation is unclear and it would be useful to have further discussion about that.

  Q206  Chairman: I am not altogether clear. Are you saying that if the UK government wished to proceed with getting approval through all the different layers of bureaucracy that it would have to go through, if it set out to achieve a sustainable timber policy of procurement that it could actually do that? Or are you not including this issue of social alongside economic and environmental in the definition of sustainable?

  Mr Brack: Yes, that is the problem. The Member States can broadly do whatever they like, but if someone thinks that they are exceeding the constraints set by EU procurement rules they would launch a dispute against them and the European Court of Justice would hear it. So to that extent we are not completely clear how the ECJ would interpret procurement directives. I think there is not much disagreement that you can impose quite high environmental standards, so the environmental angle of sustainability is not likely to cause a problem. The area of dispute is about the social element of sustainability.

  Q207  Chairman: Are you saying that that could be included as well?

  Mr Brack: I am saying that it is unclear whether it can be included. I do not know, personally. But clearly different Member States are interpreting this in different ways.

  Q208  Chairman: In terms of the contact that you have had with other European countries, what do you know about the stance of the UK government on this? Are they sympathetic to try to overcome the problems that there are in this definition of social, or do you think that there would be sufficient support to proceed and, if necessary, take whatever action needs to be taken through the WTO to get that on to the WTO agreement level?

   Mr Brack: Again, it is an EU procurement directive problem and not a WTO one. I honestly do not know; I am not sure that I could say. I think that there is sympathy within the UK Government for incorporating stronger social criteria, but they feel constrained by EU procurement directives. Other Member States do not appear to feel as constrained as the UK. So it would be helpful to discuss this further and perhaps get a legal interpretation of the procurement directives.

  Q209  Chairman: So I am right that the answers you have just given now are slightly at odds with the written submission you have given to us, that really if there was a will to do it there would be a way of doing it?

  Mr Brack: I think my written submission just said it was unclear, which it is—unclear.

  Q210  Mr Ainsworth: We have not had much evidence yet which gives us confidence that the FLEGT Action Plan and the Voluntary Partnership Agreements are going to amount to a row of beans in terms of making a practical difference. Is that your view?

  Mr Brack: No, I do not agree with that. I think a lot of the criticisms that the NGOs made in the previous talk are to some extent justified, but I think you need to see the licensing scheme that the FLEGT Action Plan is bringing in as the first step in a series of further steps, and in that sense it should be compared to any environmental agreement, where the initial agreement is often clearly inadequate to deal with the problem but it creates a step beyond which you can take further steps. For example, the Montreal Protocol on ozone depleting substances, the Kyoto Protocol on climate change—clearly their first versions were inadequate to deal with the problem, but they created the systems and the will to move beyond that in due course. So I think if the licensing scheme stopped at where it is likely to be in the first year or so, and did not proceed any further, it would not be terribly effective. But I do not think that is necessarily the case, I think it can develop and evolve. The problem is, as Saskia said in the earlier session, there is no multilateral agreement on forestry or on illegal logging under which you can bring in a licensing scheme, and other licensing schemes, again for example in the Montreal Protocol or in the Kimberley Process on conflict diamonds, have taken place within multilateral frameworks and have worked effectively to exclude illegal products, or, for the Kimberley Process, conflict diamonds, from world markets. I think they have a good record and they can work. But because there is no multilateral agreement on illegal logging you can meet that problem in two ways: one is to try to negotiate a new multilateral agreement and really there is not much political will, since the collapse of the attempts to negotiate the Forests Convention at the Earth Summit 15 years ago, for a new multilateral agreement. Or you can choose to do what the EU is trying to do, which is to build up the system from the bottom up, through bilateral agreements with individual countries. If you do that then you face the inevitable problem that there will be some countries that probably will not join your bilateral agreements and therefore potentially provide gaps, loopholes, through which illegal timber can be imported. It is true to say also that a processing country causes potentially quite a big gap. If the agreement, for example, is between Ghana and the EU, (Ghana is quite likely a first signatory) and Ghana exports primarily straight to the EU without any intermediate country, then I think the licensing system, in those circumstances, ought to work well, as long as it has things like independent monitoring built into it, which I think will be there in the partnership agreement. If you are seeing a longer chain of movements, if a country like Indonesia exports to China and then China exports to the EU, then that makes the system, as it is envisaged at the moment, much more difficult, but I think that is something that needs to be tackled and we need to think how you can deal with chains of countries exporting and shipping. In theory, conceptually, there ought not to be a problem with developing that; it needs more political will, it needs more effort, it needs a willingness to move beyond the initial system. I think that the FLEGT Action Plan—the licensing system and the partnership agreements—are setting up the first stage of that process, which we then ought to move beyond. So I am much more optimistic than the NGOs.

  Q211  Mr Ainsworth: You certainly are and it is quite refreshing to hear somebody who is optimistic about these things. Let me explore a little further how justified that optimism is. We heard just now the way that the whole licensing system had been watered down, reduced basically, and you yourself said it is very modest, it is more emblematically important than practically. I think you said that 20 out of 25 of the EU Member States are doing nothing. With that kind of political inertia how likely is it that any of this is really going to happen soon?

  Mr Brack: Two comments on that. The reference to 20 out of 25 was about procurement policy, which is separate and different from the licensing scheme. I think procurement is very important and it can come into effect faster than licensing, but it is not connected; they are different things. The licensing scheme will affect the whole of the EU, through a regulation that will apply without the need for any more national legislation. I do not agree with the comment made by WWF that it has been watered down. Actually the original text of the Action Plan referring to the licensing scheme covering a more limited number of categories of timber than has now actually proved to be the case. Because of the impact studies that the Commission carried out on the likely effect of a licensing scheme they actually extended those categories that the licensing scheme will cover to include plywood and veneer, which was not envisaged originally. So I simply think that was an inaccurate comment. I accept that again the licensing scheme will be more effective if it covers all categories of timber and timber products, including processed products, engineered wood and pulp and paper, and again that is something that they need to be prepared to move on to very rapidly. But, again, it is the first step in the process.

  Q212  Mr Ainsworth: You are currently looking at alternatives that the EU could adopt. Are there any promising signs there?

  Mr Brack: There are two elements in the Action Plan on which we are carrying out studies on behalf of the UK Government, and I think again I would agree with the NGOs in saying that the Action Plan has been rather slow in implementing some of these studies. The first one is an examination of national legislation in countries to see if there is any kind of law that might be relevant to control the import of illegal timber, for example laws on theft or receiving stolen goods or money laundering. We have not finished those studies yet—there are five or six going on in various Member States of the EU—but my preliminary conclusion would be that there are no domestic laws that are likely to be very useful in controlling the import of illegal timber, particularly from countries that do not sign a partnership agreement. So the second stage then is to look at what the options are for additional legislation at the EU and Member State level that might be helpful to control the import of illegal timber, and again I would agree with the NGOs that this kind of legislation would be extremely useful as a reinforcement to the licensing scheme. There are a series of options that we will be looking at—we have not finished the study yet—and one is modelled on legislation in the United States that makes the import of illegal fish and wildlife produced illegally overseas illegal in the US. I think it should be possible to adopt something like that at EU and EU Member State level.

  Q213  Mr Ainsworth: Does the WTO come into the equation at some point?

  Mr Brack: It depends what the legislation says. The US legislation, the Lacey Act, is not a border measure, it is not a requirement that is imposed at the border—if it was then there would be a WTO case. What it simply says is that if you are found in possession of fish and wildlife produced illegally overseas or if you sell it or market it or transport it or export it, then that is an illegal act and you can be subject to prosecution in the US courts, and even if you did not know that the material was illegal you can have it confiscated from you. So it is important to say that that is not a border measure, it is a change to criminal legislation; and the German draft legislation which made the marketing and possession of timber produced illegally in virgin forests illegal in Germany—it is not implemented yet, it is still draft legislation—is an attempt to do something like that at the EU level. I think that kind of measure adopted at the EU Member State level would be a very important reinforcement for the licensing scheme. It is not a panacea because it is still quite difficult to get evidence of the fact that the timber has been produced illegally; you need to have good cooperation with the producing country and you need to have evidence of the crime there, and that is not easy by any means. But it is another kind of reinforcement, a shoring-up of the licensing scheme.

  Q214  Mr Ainsworth: But you also need political will within Europe.

  Mr Brack: You need the political will. I think it is very helpful that Germany published its draft legislation because it rather moved the debate on. I think the view amongst the EU Member State Governments and the Commission has been, "We want to see the licensing scheme come into effect first and that is the top priority," and I think they are right on that. And, "When we have that in place we will look at other options as well." I think they could have been faster in looking at the other options but they are due to look at the other options.

  Q215  Colin Challen: Turning to the role of investment finance, particularly as it supports the destruction of forests and encourages unsustainable timber production, what sort of investment are we looking at, in both public and private senses, and what kind of figures might we be talking about?

  Ms Saunders: I was told yesterday that you would ask for figures and unfortunately it is the one thing that I cannot really give you. As to the kinds of investments, there is a really broad scope and it goes from everything on the public side where there are export credits, development assistance, development banks, and on the private side equity investments, bond trading, project finance and corporate finance. They are all involved in different ways and in different sectors that are damaging or high risk at least. There is not a lot of international investment in actual forest management or logging because they are not particularly capital-intensive sectors, but there is investment in, for example, the pulp and paper sector. The extractives quite often are in forested areas so although they are not ostensibly forestry investments they still have an impact. The infrastructure and investment in road building and those kinds of things, and timber processing such as ply, are all quite critical sectors that do get international investment.

  Q216  Colin Challen: I understand that in China the pulp and paper mill sector is already over capacity measured against its legal sources of supply. Are we still seeing a lot of investment going into that sector?

  Ms Saunders: If you talk to analysts now it is still being punted as an exciting sector in which to be investing.

  Q217  Colin Challen: Where are those analysts based?

  Ms Saunders: Europe and North America.

  Q218  Colin Challen: British banks?

  Ms Saunders: I have spoken to one analyst in the UK and two in Dutch banks and they have been talking about it quite positively. I have also seen recommendations from Asian arms of European banks, Asian subsidiaries of European banks. Credit Suisse was the one I read recently.

  Q219  Colin Challen: Have any of these analysts become more aware of things like corporate social responsibility, those CSR issues that many companies now seem more engaged with?

  Ms Saunders: On paper, yes, but it is very difficult to see the impact of that in investment decisions. Banks are not particularly transparent about the decisions they make and they are certainly not transparent about the investments they decide against. I have been reading recently that there have been a few big oil palm flotations in Malaysia and in the general business Press the only risk that is mentioned is the potential fluctuation in commodity prices. No one is talking about the potential for that land to have been cleared illegally; I have not seen anything like that in the mainstream. Obviously you get it in SRI, socially responsible investment type publications, or if you talk to those kinds of banks, but I have not seen anything mainstream suggesting it.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2006
Prepared 24 January 2006