Select Committee on Environmental Audit Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witness (Questions 173-179)

JOHN HEALEY MP

9 FEBRUARY 2006

  Q173 Joan Walley: Welcome. Can I say at the outset, Minister, thank you very much for coming back to this Committee. We understand we have about an hour to an hour and a half with you. We have got a lot of ground to cover, so we would like to go straight into the questions, if that is okay. I would start off by saying that when the Environment Agency gave evidence to us about the Treasury's approach to environmental taxes and incentives, they felt that the Treasury had been unnecessarily tentative and that you could be more ambitious. Do you recognise that criticism or do you feel that it is unfair criticism?

John Healey: No, I do not accept the criticism. To respond to your welcome, I am very pleased to be here again, and it is good to see you in the Chair, Ms Walley.

  Q174 Joan Walley: It is only temporary.

  John Healey: Even though it is temporary. Would you pass on my congratulations to Mr Ainsworth for his promotion? I have been coming before this Committee for several years and a number of members from both sides have gone on to front bench duties and responsibilities afterwards. It is good to see that the parties are taking the Environmental Audit Committee seriously as well. I do not accept the criticism, briefly, for these reasons. If you look back to 1997, when we first came into government, we set out a principled statement of intent on the environment and the use of economic instruments led by the Treasury but obviously on behalf of Government at that point. At different stages, we have reinforced that principled framework—in the Pre-Budget Report in 2002 and then again in the Pre-Budget Report this inquiry is basing its work on in December. Within that framework we have introduced a number of very serious fiscal and economic instruments, often at points when we have faced considerable opposition not just from opposition parties but from groups outside. If you think back to the introduction of the climate change levy which we started the process for examining and introducing in 1999, at that stage, with the exception of the Scandinavian countries, there were only two other countries in Europe with any sort of carbon or energy-related tax. Now, of course, with the Energy Products Directive, it has become the standard. When you look also at the introduction that we did with the Voluntary UK Emissions Trading Scheme, it was the first economy-wide emissions trading scheme. It was the forerunner and very much the basis on which the EU Emissions Trading Scheme was devised. Again, if you look at the recognition that has always been there in our environmental policy, particularly on the biggest challenges like climate change, this is not a UK problem. It cannot ever be simply a UK problem because our emissions are around 2% of the world's emissions. Therefore our ability to lead and contribute to the international consensus for action and measures to deal with climate change has been essential. You have seen that not just in the instruments and measures that we have been prepared to introduce, as I have just said, but also, in the recent 12 months, with the priority that we gave to climate change within the period of Presidency that the UK held for the G8 and for the European Union, and you will see this again tomorrow and Saturday when the Chancellor is in Moscow at the G8 meeting—the follow up to Gleneagles—where he will be discussing and leading the arguments for the World Bank to go further with the energy investment framework that was recently announced to try and help the poorest and developing countries develop alternative and cleaner energy sources.

  Q175 Joan Walley: Thank you. It is very helpful to have that as a contextual framework for the inquiry that we are taking. I think the issues that you have raised about consensus or communication and understanding by the public are issues that we will come on to later. What we really want to press you a little bit further on is that the 1997 statement from the Treasury really did promise so much in terms of shifting from "goods" to "bads", and the issue is: how do we measure the success of that? We have to have regard, surely, to the fact that the proportion of tax revenue generated through environmental taxes is now, for the fourth year running, lower that it was in 1997. How can you show that you have kept faith with that huge ambition in 1997 and that we are still making progress on the shift from "goods" to "bads"?

  John Healey: You can see it, first of all, in some of the specific measures. I mentioned the climate change levy, very specifically an instrument that, apart from its environmental objects, did just that. It shifted the taxation, because it was accompanied, you will remember, by a 0.3% cut in employers' national insurance payments, from "goods", if you like, the cost to employers employing people, to "bads", in other words, the profligate or excessive use of energy in business processes. First of all, you see that, and I could make the same argument with the aggregates levy, I could make the same argument with the landfill tax. Secondly, and this is important to understand, if the sole measure of the seriousness with which the Government takes environmental taxes is the total tax take of that group of taxes that happens to be categorised as environmental transport taxes, then I think you are missing two very important points. The first is this. Some of those tax regimes are devised specifically to discourage the activities which are taxed. In other words, if they are working, you see a reduction in the activity that is being taxed because the reduction has a beneficial environmental impact. The evidence of the operation of the aggregates levy is precisely that. The period of economic growth and expansion of the construction industry, the amount of virgin aggregate quarried in this country, has fallen since the introduction of the aggregates levy. The amount of recycled aggregate produced has increased. The second thing to bear in mind on the question of looking at crude figures is this. Within some of these taxes we are able to use the design of them in a way to achieve environmental objectives that just is not shown if you look at the headline numbers. Take fuel duty.

  Q176 Joan Walley: We will come on to fuel duty.

  John Healey: May I just say, the discount in duty to support the development of bio-fuels, which is 20 pence per litre, is precisely to achieve an environmental end, but if you are just looking at the total take, including the tax take from fuel duty, you will not see that registered.

  Q177 Colin Challen: I want to ask a follow up question. I think you are right in terms of the reduction in tax take in terms of its effectiveness domestically, but has the Treasury done any work to see whether or not some of the people who are affected by these taxes might simply be displacing their activities elsewhere in the world? I could mention one example which has recently come to my attention of the potential for people to use Renewable Obligation Certificates for a power model, for example, which could have serious impacts elsewhere, but here, of course, we can say it is a bio-fuel and therefore it is a "good" and reward it, even though it might cause the destruction of ecologically sensitive rain forest and so on?

  John Healey: I think you are right to point to that sort of life-cycle perspective in trying to assess the environmental impact and benefit plus the cost of some of these measures. I have mentioned the rather simple and initial policy instrument of the duty discount to support the development of the UK bio-fuels market. The Pre-Budget Report confirmed the Government's intention to introduce what I think you are referring to here, which is a road fuel, road transport fuels obligation, probably from April 2008. Part of the work that the Department for Transport, which obviously leads in this area, is conducting at the moment is, importantly, our ability to assess not just the nature of the fuel that is produced, to make sure it meets the specifications of bio-fuels and we get the mandatory 5% level by 2010-11, but also the environmental impact: because what we do not want to see is imported bio-fuels derived from other countries and derived from environmental production practices which are hugely damaging—it could be deforestation, it could be a number of other detrimental activities—and we do not want to be producing a policy instrument, albeit one that is likely to deliver about a million tons of carbon savings per year, which has those effects which are perhaps a litter further out of sight.

  Q178 Mr Hurd: Minister, I understand your point completely about the initiative taken by the Government at the beginning of the programme. The point is that there is considerable frustration about the amount of activity untaken since 2001-02 against a background in which the biggest environmental priority of all, which is the reduction in CO2 emissions, is quite clearly being failed. Do you understand that point, the frustration in terms of activity since 2001-02?

  John Healey: I am not sure if you are arguing for the introduction of policy instruments of the significance and weight of the climate change levy every year, but I do not accept it entirely. If you look at some of the initiatives that were set out in the Pre-Budget Report, they were designed to reinforce some of the measures we have got in place. They were designed also to try and take us into some of the new areas, like further support for carbon capture and storage. We have just discussed the road fuels obligation, which is potentially a very significant economic measure which has recently been announced by the Secretary of State for Transport, developed by the Chancellor, and, I think, will produce a really important environmental gain for us.

  Q179 David Howarth: Can we probe a little further into the points that you made a moment ago about the relationship between behavioural change and revenue and the evidence base that you were using to judge behavioural change. On the first point, Paul Ekins came before us yesterday to re-emphasise the point that the Committee has made in the past that it is a false dichotomy to set up behavioural change against revenue raising, but, if the elasticities are right, you can have both. You have mentioned the aggregates levy, but what about the climate change levy, what about fuel duty? Surely there is no contradiction between raising revenue and changing behaviour, because both can happen at the same time. Have you changed your view on that, or are you still of the view you were last year that behavioural change can only happen if you abandon revenue raising as an aim?

  John Healey: No. I do not know if you have misread the transcript of last year's session, but that cannot be the point. You are pointing to two of the factors that inevitably are part of the judgments that the Chancellor takes when making decisions either about new policy instruments or particularly about decisions on rates; and they are balances between perhaps the behavioural change and signals that we want to encourage, because of the environmental gains, with some of the concerns that there may be about distributional impacts or the economic impacts and, indeed, revenue raising, but those are precisely some of the dimensions to any judgment that does not make some of these things straightforward.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2006
Prepared 21 March 2006