Select Committee on Environmental Audit Written Evidence


Memorandum submitted by Biffa Waste Services Ltd

  Biffa Waste Services is the largest waste management company operating in the UK and can justifiably claim to be the most diverse in terms of its spread of interest in industrial/commercial and domestic collection, landfill, liquid waste and specialist hazardous waste management systems. The company has a turnover of around £760 million at a current annualised rate and is also in the top three waste management companies operating in Belgium. We are wholly owned by Severn Trent Plc with over 150 operating centres throughout the UK. We handle 14 million tonnes of material that is treated, landfilled or recycled on behalf of an extensive customer base exceeding 85,000 in the public, commercial and industrial sectors plus collection services to 1.3 million households.

I.  SYNOPSIS

  Our response comprises an underpinning element of support for the work of the Environmental Taxation Team within the Treasury but suggests that they labour under a more general perception problem within the Department in terms of their significance and relevance as part of the wider commitment to economic growth and development of the Economy. As a result—at Departmental level—the Treasury can be criticised for their track record in relation to environmental taxation in respect of the following broad issues:

    (i)  Pace.

    (ii)  Externality Economics.

    (iii)  Focus and Control.

    (iv)  Value for Money.

    (v)  Data and Management Information Systems.

  These areas of potential weakness can be offset were it possible to foster a more proactive framework to environmental strategies. At the moment these appear to be seen as extraneous to mainstream "internality" economic policy development whereas they have the potential to reinforce, actively, mainstream strategies in key areas of government spending. We thus suggest that a more cross cutting approach within the Treasury in terms of . . .

    (a)  Process.

    (b)  Funding for a national resource flow data capture information system.

    (c)  Integration of environmental accounting with supply chain economics.

    (d)  Establishing a common measure for value assessment in environmental terms (such as CO2 abatement).

    (e)  Active involvement in Greening Government initiatives through public sector procurement and policy implementation.

. . . could all produce substantive benefits in terms of value for money, cost effectiveness, and abatement of environmental risk in extant areas of government spend.

II.  SPECIFIC ISSUES

  Environmental taxation as an instrument of policy has moved a long way in the last 15 years but it is still nowhere near the level of significance which should be attached to it given the range of scientific evidence building up with regard to the scale of future abatement costs of current, so called, environmental "externality costs". The latter debate has advanced most in terms of carbon dioxide, global warming, and climate chaos, yet the level of taxation and fiscal instruments as a share of GDP is still tiny, and in recent years has declined. This suggests a lack of concerted commitment to the philosophy of using economic instruments to modify supply chain behaviour on a whole life cycle basis. Specific manifestations of that lack of commitment are:

 (i)   The Pace and Scale of Implementation

  Most obviously, as an example, we would cite the timorous approach to the implementation of the landfill tax. The introduction of the tax—at £7 per tonne—was originally based on an academically focused approach, heavily reliant on cost benefit approaches to avoided costs. With the benefit of hindsight we now understand, more comprehensively, the need to tax landfill at a rate where alternative competitive (and more environmentally benign) technologies can operate competitively. The reality—increasingly underpinned by government funded work within the New Technologies Working Group (NTWG)—suggests that most of these technologies need gate fees of £35 and above to compete effectively. Having absorbed that suggestion—after eight years' operation of the tax—the government are now moving in £3 annual stages to a £35 tax rate—effectively charging an economic "rent" to shift behaviour. Unfortunately this whole process will have occupied almost 13 years, at a time when the pace of technological development has accelerated far more quickly. The compounded effect of this temerity has been to delay crucial investment in the necessary new facilities and infrastructure by making them "unbankable" compared to the landfill alternative. We suspect that this temerity is, in turn, fuelled by an underpinning belief within the Treasury that "The Environment" is somehow extraneous to mainstream business activity—something that is nice to have if we can afford it.

  (ii)  A combination of this temerity and the extended timetable has resulted in a plethora of multiple funding packages ranging from investment breaks, subsidies, research grants, minimisation initiatives, etc, etc, which are very difficult to track down and identify collectively.

  On the whole we suspect that the total level of disbursements roughly matches the amount collected—thus adhering to the Chancellor's original statement that environmental taxation would be fiscally neutral—but nevertheless there are suspicions that the flows of these disbursements have now precisely matched the flow of income streams with the result that there are transfer payments between individual taxation groups and recipients (between private and public sector and in terms of intra sectoral flows). There is thus an impression of numerous initiatives and much activity but one must question the quantitive and qualitative results in terms of outcomes.

  (iii)  In terms of value for money one must thus question the value for money of these outcomes—particularly in terms of the high profile policy implementation debacles such as CFCs (fridges), and the Waste Electricals and Electronics Regulations (WEEE). An estimated £800 million per annum of environmental taxation flows in the waste area have been employed, and dispersed, in ways which have produced less than desirable outcomes in key areas of policy implementation as a result of the lack of funding to create more macro economic approaches to the whole issue of pollution and environmental improvement. In the public sector arena, funding has admirably been made available within the PFI framework without questioning whether this is the most appropriate mechanism for offsetting relative differences between raising funding from public or private sector sources. Relatively little funding has been made available to tackle more fundamental issues in relation to the development of the necessary planning infrastructure at regional level to replace the waste processing capacity currently contained within 200-odd landfills, which will be filled up, and not replaced, between now and 2012.

 (iv)   Data

  We understand that £5 million or less has been made available to the Environment Agency to develop and implement a waste data collection network through the use of advanced information technology data capture systems. We are involved in, and supportive of, this programme but believe that a far more holistic and comprehensive "cradle to grave approach" is required to the whole issue of resource flow management in the economy. In December 2005, the EU announced a major shift in their approach to waste strategy by confirming that waste was a manifestation of upstream production and supply chain systems and that—as such—waste strategy should be seen in the context of whole life cycle production strategies for particular products in individual sectors (food, electricals, automotive, clothing, etc). Funding levels of £20 million or more would be appropriate to develop a UK wide resource flow information database to satisfy this cradle to grave approach.

  Reluctance to commit to such a data capture network is puzzling, given that precisely the same approach is adopted with regard to the flow of financial assets in the monetary economy. The Treasury have an intimate understanding of the flows of all the monetary measures from Mo-Mxx (everything from cash in people's pockets through to the location of financial assets in terms of bank deposits, mortgage lending, fiduciary deposits, short-term lending, long-term lending, international transfer, etc, etc).

  As a consequence the Chancellor is able to determine how best to regulate any overheating or cooling in the economic structures of the UK by the application of judiciously applied accelerators or braking mechanisms, working on an arm's length basis with the Bank of England Monetary Committee. Over the last 30 years, the quality and extent of that management framework has improved by leaps and bounds, and much of that improvement is founded on the availability of online data capture systems measuring the flow of financial assets on a double entry bookkeeping basis across a sophisticated economic system. It is our belief that before environmental taxation and fiscal management can be developed with any degree of quality, we need a similar data capture system for resource flows in the economy as a whole, and it is the Treasury's responsibility to find the funding to kick-start that process for the appropriate department to implement.

  So . . .

III.  OPPORTUNITIES

  In a sense, we are not at the beginning of the end—we are at the end of the beginning (to paraphrase Churchill in relation to El Alamein).

  In fairness to the Treasury, they are receiving information on available options second hand from relevant specialist Departments—primarily DEFRA. Correspondingly, those Departments may or may not be adequately informed with regard to how available economic mechanisms might be applied most appropriately—what is needed is a higher level of round-tabling approaches developed with confidence and commitment. So what are the features of a more proactive combined strategy involving cross-departmental approaches—Non-Governmental Organisations (NGOs), industry, and local government? We would suggest that the following are key features.

 (i)   Cost the Target

  Sufficient is known on a departmental basis with regard to the necessary standards for environmental compliance in terms of air, ground and water. If one were to consider that evidence for delivering substantial improvements in the environmental quality of life in the UK, there is reasonably high quality, informed, and peer reviewed quantification of the economic costs. Broadly, these amount to between £20 billion and £30 billion per annum for the UK economy. That figure comprises approximately £10 billion per annum for the cost of delivering the EU Drinking Water Directive, £8 billion for delivering the new Waste Strategy with substantive reductions in reliance on landfills, and the development of a brand new infrastructure costing approximately £10 billion of capital investment (for recycling, energy, and soil manufacturing facilities), and £12 billion+ for delivering full Integrated Pollution, Prevention and Control (IPPC) standards in the cement, chemicals, automotive, engineering, and electrical generation sectors. Admittedly these are ballpark figures but the informed consensus appears to be that we are talking about an annualised incremental impact on GDP of not less than £20 billion and not more than £30 billion each year.

  The mindset in the Treasury appears to feel that these costs are somehow a threat to our competitiveness, job creation capability, and general economic wellbeing. Viewed from within the environmental services sector, we would suggest that quite the reverse is true—expenditure on these items will produce positive benefits to society in terms of quality of life, health, wellbeing, jobs, security, and international competitiveness. In short, environmental investment forms part of the next industrial revolution and we should be embracing these opportunities, rather than seeking to defend ourselves from them. It would be helpful if the Treasury were to be more explicit in its adoption of the latter approach, rather than the former.

 (ii)   Data

  We have already referred to the parsimonious approach in funding for the Environment Agency with regard to implementing a cradle to grave resource flow data capture information system. We believe that levels of funding in this area should be stepped up for the Agency and that the value for money criteria of this expenditure be closely scrutinised in terms of defined offset benefits such as:

    —  Avoided expenditure on fly-tipping.

    —  Anticipating the impacts of environmental crime.

    —  Ensuring that fiscal and budgetary environmental pricing strategies are more finely attuned.

    —  Assisting the resource efficiency of specific industrial supply chains.

 (iii)   Supply Chain Systems

  Much of the environment disbenefits faced by society today originate—both historically and on an ongoing basis—from entrenched technologies and methods of production in discrete supply chains (food, furniture, clothing, automotive, chemicals, etc, etc). Given the commitment to the development of a national online database in resource flow accounting, it would be possible to integrate revenue expenditure, investment, subsidies, and tax breaks for environmental improvement into those specific supply chains in a far more focused fashion. Many of the environmental disbenefits faced by society—in terms of solid waste, gaseous and aquatic emissions—originate from long established methodologies of production, based on a historic cost infrastructure. The challenge of the environmental economy is to face the need for adaptation, product reformulation, and substantive shifts in the methodologies of component use and composition. The UK is in a leading position to accelerate these supply chain shifts—whilst at the same time ensuring consumer demand is satisfied but by using far more environmentally "sound" production systems. Those systems will be in great demand in coming decades with the prospect of continuing rises in the global population and an increasing proportion of that population which expects to enjoy higher standards of living. Basic production systems are being exported from the UK to these developing economies at a fast pace—the opportunities presented by refining those production systems, together with the associated research and development, IT, and systems integration, represents a very real opportunity for the future economic growth of the UK economy.

  (iv)  The Treasury needs to evaluate the cost/benefit of any environmental policies against an environmental yardstick. It is insufficient to relate this back to crude measures such as tonnages or financial data. As a result, we suggest the Treasury should commission research work to establish what type of common yardsticks might best serve that purpose. We would suggest—given recent statements by the Prime Minister—that most logically these would relate to carbon/CO2 avoidance and abatement. It is likely that the valuation of carbon/CO2 will be increasingly refined through the climate change mechanism in coming years and it would thus be possible to find a linking mechanism between the financial economy and the environmental economy, through the measure of carbon. Such valuations would be underwritten by Tradeable Permit systems, which reflect practical operational market valuations arrived at on competitive trading flows.

 (v)   Value for Money in Extant Environmental Strategies

  By this we mean the avoidance of "negative" expenditure on policy development which might otherwise sour. Looking back, examples include the WEEE Regulations and attempts to abate CFC releases from refrigeration devices. Attempts have been made to determine Regulatory Impact Assessments (RIAs) but if these were carried out ex post, the cost per tonne of removing CFCs would be phenomenal. We suggest that if some of our recommendations above had been carried out, the focus, timing, and precision of taxation and regulatory action would give far better value for money. The most obvious area where the absence of any holistic data collection system will bring immense costs lies in the probability that by 2010 the remaining landfill capacity will be able to charge exorbitant prices until replacement new technologies are brought online, on a scale anywhere near capable of absorbing the current level of material flows (without allowing for growth). Expenditure now in the above recommended areas will bring considerable savings in five to 10 years in terms of accelerating capacity provision in the waste area.

  More proactively, whilst we recognise that the Treasury take a "hands off" role in relation to the quality of spend in Departments with high environmental impact (Health, Home Office, Education, and Transport, etc), there is a case for suggesting that it could facilitate investment in macro economic evaluation of the environmental expenditure of these Departments in areas such as waste management, energy, water use, and raw material purchases. As a cross cutting Department, the Treasury is in a key position to understand the need for more strategic implementation of green procurement systems on a cross-departmental basis and its ability to evaluate the scale of that impact puts it in a prime position to drive innovation in areas such as recycling, green energy procurement/investment, stimulation of reclaimable product reuse, and the reformation of design specifications for specific high volume product purchases in areas of government procurement as diverse as paper, information technology equipment, road vehicles, building specifications, and heating fuel supply systems.

  We hope you find these suggestions useful and, if there are any points on which you require specific clarification, suggest you will not hesitate to get in touch. We are also appending, for information, a copy of a paper prepared by Dr Catherine Mitchell of Warwick University, in relation to the specifics of economic strategy in relation to waste and waste strategy. This is pertinent to some of the earlier points we were making with regard to policy development.

January 2006





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2006
Prepared 21 March 2006