Select Committee on Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Written Evidence


Memorandum submitted by Joan Noble

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

  The reform of the EU sugar regime is long overdue. The current system is highly complicated, restricts competition, encourages over production, is over protectionist and inflates consumer sugar prices. The rules are now under pressure from the EU's international commitments and a move to a more liberal regime is required. Any change must be agreed as soon as possible to allow the EU's sugar industries time to plan for the future and, where necessary, diversify out of sugar production. Reforms have to be agreed which will reduce support price levels.

  While a system of full liberalisation and abolition of regulation would be welcome in the future, there has to be a phased change to allow the most efficient producers in the EU to adapt to new circumstances. Sugar beet remains an important crop for the British farmer and it must be possible to allow production of sugar in the UK and at the same time continue to provide preferential arrangements to the UK's traditional suppliers of raw cane sugar.

  While much of the proposed change is to be welcomed there are some details which could be improved, particularly to avoid carrying forward imbalances from the current system and provide a greater degree of flexibility despite the rigid quota requirements. A more defined transition to a liberal market orientated system would also be desirable.

GENERAL COMMENTS

  1.  This long awaited reform is essential. The current system which has largely been in place with little reform since 1968 has little relevance in today's political and economic climate. The European Union has moved for other crop products from a system of price to direct farm income support and these proposals to reform the sugar regime (albeit only partially) continue that trend. The current system is no longer sustainable particularly when the EU's international commitments are taken into account.

PRICES

  2.  The support price reduction is essential although this price is still above world market levels at this juncture. This may not always be the case because of the volatility of world market prices. Initially consumers will not benefit from the price cuts because of the application of the restructuring scheme. It is unlikely that consumers will be able to source sugar below the reference price even when world market prices are very low as the reference price will be the trigger point for private storage and other support arrangements which will replace intervention.

  3.  The proposals for the minimum sugar beet price do provide some flexibility in that growers and processors can negotiate up to 10% lower prices although at least 90% of the minimum beet price will be paid on all sugar delivered, even that produced for out of quota sales (for industrial and other use). While the commission plans a less rigid approach to price for farmers, there is still considerable rigidity in the proposed floor to the market.

  4.  The price reporting mechanism is unclear. Could this lead to competitive issues amongst sugar companies following the restructuring envisaged?

  5.  In the proposed amendment to regulation 1782/2003 on direct payment to farmers, to compensate for the price reductions, there is no provision to allow a higher level of compensation to farmers in countries who have in the past been paid higher sugar beet prices than the common level.

CHANGE IN MARKETING YEAR AND DURATION OF THE REGIME

  6.  The change in the start of the marketing year from 1 July to 1 October is a good idea as this merges the marketing year with the balance sheet year and stocks are at their lowest by the end of September. However, some further clarification is required as to how imports will be handled. Will additional amounts be established for the three months?

  7.  The planned duration of the regime until 2014-15 is welcomed for the stability it produces but it must be questionable whether there will need to be further price changes following the conclusion to the Doha development agenda. There is currently uncertainty about the future particularly as regards import tariffs and the phasing out of export refunds.

PRODUCTION QUOTAS

  8.  The continuation of rigid production quotas does not allow for a more liberal market and is out of line with the approach taken for other crop products produced within the EU. While there needs to be some control on production while the restructuring process is underway, there are problems because this continues some of the inequalities inherent in the old regime. The basis of the reform is to help the most efficient producers to continue sugar production while helping the least efficient out of the market with financial incentives.

  9.  There are two possible ways the most efficient producers can increase their market share under the proposals. The first is through buying a reallocation of C sugar production where the farmers and companies who produced the largest quantities of C sugar in the 2004-05 marketing year gain the most. Farmers and companies whose past production of C sugar was seen as (what was originally envisaged) a "safety net" produced less C sugar and will not benefit to the same extent from this reallocation. Perhaps they too should be able to buy additional quota on the same terms as those entitled under the proposals. Some Member States—it could be argued—are being rewarded for deliberate over production in the past.

  10.  The second allows for up to 10% transferability of quota within a member state. This system can only benefit those countries where there has not already been significant restructuring and consolidation of the industry. Some countries where there are efficient producers (like the UK) will be unable to benefit from this reallocation and therefore unable to grow their market share as they are already sole producers in that Member State. In these circumstances there should be the possibility of cross border transfers (subject to some control) to allow greater flexibility of the redistribution of production quota in the longer term.

  11.  The proposed introduction of the principle of a levy on sugar produced outside the quota, which is not carried forward or used in the industrial sector, is a sensible way to control over production. Such a scheme already exists in the dairy sector and the so called "super levy" has largely been effective in controlling over production outside the quota. It is curious, therefore, that the commission proposes this at the same time as proposing to "reward" past over producers with allowing them to increase their quota.

  12.  The simplification of the quota system by merging the A quota with the B quota should be welcomed as a principle. However, this has some hidden difficulties. To meet WTO commitments on exports, the commission has to adjust quotas on an annual basis. This is achieved through the use of coefficients which were established by the council of ministers. The impact of the coefficients was to weight the quota changes so that those producing greater quantities of B sugar (which originally was envisaged as quota for export with the largest B quotas being held by countries producing surpluses) had a larger share of the production quota reductions. Although not spelt out in the proposal, it must be assumed that future quota changes, if required, to meet international commitments would not reflect the historical built in surplus and would have equal impact on all member states whether they were in surplus or deficit.

  13.  On a more positive note, from 2007-08 the announcement of quota adjustments will be made earlier than currently applies. Under the existing rules the adjustments are made in September—long after the beet has been planted—while from 2007-08 it is envisaged that the adjustments should be made by the end of February the previous marketing year.

  14.  The planned increase in isoglucose quota is to be allocated to existing producers, basically as compensation for price cuts. Margins in the isoglucose industry will be severely cut because of the support price reductions.

FUTURE QUOTA CUTS

  15.  A system of voluntary restructuring rather than compulsory quota cuts should be welcomed as this takes into account the economic reality of sugar production. However, if the restructuring does not produce the desired effect then there will be compulsory quota cuts. While details are still to be decided it must be assumed that future quota cuts (both temporary and permanent) would be on a pro rata basis. This would not reflect either areas of particular market deficits or surplus and could result in possible supply difficulties or higher consumer prices in peripheral regions.

  16.  The proposals allow for a permanent quota reduction from 2010 (to be agreed under management committee procedure). It is not clear what would happen if the restructuring measures result in a need for quota increases to meet domestic consumption requirements. Further there is no provision to allow for the ultimate abolition of production quotas to allow a more market orientated scheme to emerge.

EXPORTS

  17.  Exports are expected to be reduced to virtually nil under the new regime. However, under the current WTO commitment (until the conclusion of the Doha development agenda) the EU is able to export just under 1.3 million tonnes (exact tonnage to be confirmed following enlargement from EU15 to EU25). There are markets for EU sugar and this is a dramatic cut from the 2005-06 level of exports (around six million tonnes?). Under the proposed new rules there is no scope to export so called C sugar at world prices (without subsidy) and the only exports will be production within the quota arrangements. If there is less than the 1.3 million tonnes of quota sugar available for export (because of domestic demand or the financial restraints also applicable) then the EU will lose these export markets. The possibility of flexibility should be introduced to allow the export of sugar produced outside quota (not eligible for refunds) if there is too little quota sugar for export. Already many third country customers of sugar are being disappointed because of the WTO disputes panel ruling which has disallowed exports of C sugar and the re-export of ACP sugar.

  18.  It would be sensible to allow flexibility to ensure that the EU (if this is required) is able to export up to the maximum allowed under its international commitments.

INDUSTRIAL SUGAR

  19.  It is proposed to allow certain industrial users of sugar to contract with sugar producers to buy non quota sugar. If this is not available at world market prices, a production refund will be paid on production for domestic consumption only. There are many details to be established on how the scheme will operate, how the price will be set and whether a production refund should be paid on quota and/or non quota sugar. Further clarification is required on the details of the scheme and the products involved. Under the import arrangements (Article 26(3)) it appears that import tariffs can be suspended or reduced to allow world market price white sugar imports for this sector. It is unclear how this system would operate or why this is only for white sugar and does not include raw sugar.

NON ANNEX I USERS

  20.  The EU is committed to the abolition of export refunds in the long term. It is clear that the planned reforms are likely to reduce sugar exports to a trickle as production levels are reduced while levels of imports will still be protected through high (if decreasing) tariffs. Prices therefore within the EU are likely for the most part to continue to be higher than world market prices. While there may be legitimate concerns from consumers over high prices these do not pose commercial risks for domestic consumption as there will be equal competition within EU territory. However, there is a real concern for food and industrial manufacturers within the EU looking to compete on the world market. When there is no longer the possibility of the payment of export refunds to make up the difference between world and EU prices (following the conclusion of the Doha development agenda) EU manufacturers may be subject to unfair competition from third country manufacturers while there is still a rigid system of price support afforded to sugar (and milk) producers. Although raw material prices are only part of the overall manufacturing cost, the impact may be that manufacturers looking to export will relocate outside the EU for that production and/or rely totally on the use of inwards processing relief to allow them to continue to be competitive. Note that it is suggested that the use of inwards processing relief (Article 24) can be "fully or partially prohibited" to ensure the "proper functioning" of the sugar market which provides uncertainty to the food industry.

APPROVED OPERATORS

  21.  There is a new provision in that Member States have to approve sugar, isoglucose and inuline producers. If companies fail to comply with requirements approval status can presumably be removed and the company would lose their right to quota. It seems with the information which can be requested by Member States there could be commercial confidentiality issues to be considered.

MARKET SUPPORT ARRANGEMENTS

  22.  Sugar companies will have to report prices so the commission can introduce measures such as private storage or quota withdrawal (or the reverse when prices rise) to support the market on a temporary basis. The reference price is used for the introduction of private storage ("if the price recorded is below the reference price") but the exact price at which withdrawal is introduced remains undefined ("close to the reference price").

SUGAR REFINERS

  23.  The proposals could cause problems for the EU's sugar refiners. Under the present system there are set quotas for each of the refining Member State. While the overall quantity remains the same, there will no longer be any allocation to the individual Member States. At the same time the proposed abolition of refining aid will put pressure on all, but particularly, the least efficient refineries. This aid was deemed necessary under the current regime because of the difference in margins between sugar beet producers and cane refiners. The difference in margins between the two sectors is increased under these proposals so it seems incongruous to abandon refining aids at this juncture. Refineries are outside the restructuring scheme and cannot benefit from restructuring finance.

  24.  There is some protection afforded to refiners in that for the first three years the import quota will be allocated entirely to them and thereafter, the refineries will have initial rights to the quota for the first three months of each marketing year. However, there should be some clearer definition of "full time refinery". What happens where a refiner is also a beet processor. Can that factory benefit from restructuring finance?

  25.  It also appears that all sugar imports from both ACP and EBA countries will be subject to a guaranteed price taking price negotiation for EBA imports out of the hands of the refiners.

BUDGET

  26.  The current regime is broadly "self financing" apart from the cost of intervention and the re-export of sugar imports. While the restructuring scheme is broadly "self financing", it is not clear if the production charge planned of

12/tonne will be sufficient to meet the costs of the regime, including production and export refunds.

RESTRUCTURING PLAN

  27.  These radical proposals will have a profound impact on sugar production in the European Union. It is clear that several countries will cease sugar production as they will not be profitable when the internal price falls by 39% and some farmers looking to maximise returns will prefer to plant other crops when the sugar beet price is reduced. It is anticipated that production within quota will fall from the current 17.44 million tonnes by about five million tonnes as sugar companies take up the option of restructuring aid.

  28.  Whether the scheme will be too successful and introduce supply problems for EU consumers is yet to be seen though there is a ceiling on the amount of restructuring aid available which should ensure adequate supplies despite the possibly generous amount of per tonnage payment, although local supply difficulties could emerge. It must be anticipated that the major share of the aid will be taken up in the first year of the scheme.

NEED TO ENCOURAGE BIOFUELS

  29.  While a restructuring plan should be welcomed to ease the least efficient out of the market, it is curious that no provision is included to encourage the use of factories ceasing production of sugar to convert into biofuel production. Presumably part of the factory could be salvaged for such use. I wonder if the economics of this possibility have been considered and if there is any "joined up thinking" between DG agri and DG environment on this matter.

  30.  It seems inevitable that oil prices, which already have increased by over 50% in the last year, will continue to be volatile with the current instability in the middle east, concerns over US production following hurricane Katrina, increased demand from China and elsewhere. There is no better time than now to provide incentives to replace fossil fuels with renewable energy sources.

  31.  While not wishing to further complicate the proposals it would be sensible to allow for some form of incentive to encourage the production of biofuels, not necessarily from sugar beet but from any crop product and to encourage the use of those parts of the factories which will be subject to restructuring finance.

  32.  It is proposed that sugar beet grown to be sold to the industrial market (non food uses) should attract the minimum beet price which cannot be negotiated downwards by the 10% allowed for sugar beet grown for normal sugar production.

Joan Noble

September 2005





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2005
Prepared 22 November 2005