Select Committee on Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Written Evidence


Further supplementary memorandum submitted by British Sugar Plc

BRITISH SUGAR RESPONSE TO TATE & LYLE'S SUPPLEMENTARY EVIDENCE TO THE COMMITTEE

INTRODUCTION

  In their supplementary evidence, Tate & Lyle (T&L) make four main claims:

  1.  That the reform proposals reduce their margin by more than beet processors', so they should be given a refining subsidy to correct this "imbalance".

  2.  Refiners can compete in a totally deregulated market whereas beet processors cannot; so they should receive special treatment.

  3.  Beet processors have been allocated quotas—refiners should therefore get guaranteed cane raws supplies.

  4.  Refiners offer the principal gateway to the EU for ACP and LDC developing countries, by acting as the "agent" for their cash transfer from the EU.

  We have structured our responses under these same headings.

FINANCIAL EFFECTS OF REFORM PROPOSALS ON REFINERS AND BEET PROCESSORS

    —  T&L's basic claim is that their gross margin has been cut by 77% compared to only 44% for beet processors (p 10 of their submission). This comparison is fundamentally flawed for two reasons.

    —  First, the comparison has not been done on a fully costed basis, as it completely excludes all the operating costs and assets for each sector. This introduces a major distortion, as the product transformation, including operating costs and assets used in the beet sector, are typically 2-3 times those in refining. The reason for this is that all the primary cane processing is carried out in the country of origin: the refinery merely "cleans up" the raw sugar already produced (as explained on pages 8 and 9 of T&L's submission), whereas beet processors have to carry out the entire operation from crop processing to white sugar refining and storage in a single continuous process. To avoid this distortion it is essential to do the comparison on a fully costed basis using actual figures.

    —  The second flaw in the comparison is that the prices assumed for 2004-05 and 2009-10 are not the same: a relatively high market price has been used in 2004-05, but the lowest possible support (or "Reference") price has been used in 2009-10. The effect of this inconsistency has been to magnify the apparent differences, and distort the figures even more.

    —  Removing these two distortions completely alters the results. Annex 1 of the report[27] enclosed with our earlier submission, summarises the effects of reform on net margins and return on assets for both sectors.

    —  The report demonstrates that for a wide range of operating costs the financial effects of the reform proposals (measured as % net margin reduction and return on assets) are similar for European refiners and beet processors.

    —  It also demonstrates that higher cost refiners are more favourably treated by the proposals than higher cost processors.

    —  The operating cost figures presented in Annex 1 of the British Sugar report27 have been taken from studies carried out by sugar economists LMC International. LMC's report on the UK refiner is attached with this response.[28] It concludes that their overall refining costs are $74/tonne (about

    60/tonne). If LMC's assessment is accurate, then the UK refiner will have a net margin reduction of 43%, and will generate a return on assets of 28% under normal market conditions—considerably better than even the lowest cost beet processors in the EU.

    —  Doing the comparison on a fully costed basis demonstrates that the financial effects of the reform proposal on European refiners and beet processors are broadly similar—there is therefore no justification for special treatment for refiners in the form of a refining subsidy.

    —  On the contrary, the margins calculated for beet processors in the above report27 assume beet supplies can be secured at

    25/tonne of beet. In reality this is highly questionable, even in efficient growing areas like the UK. Any beet price top up necessary to secure adequate beet supplies would reduce processors' margins even more than shown.

    —  On page 3 of their submission T&L also comment that they have been excluded from participating in the Restructuring Scheme. This anomaly could be corrected in several ways, for example by arranging a separate refiners' restructuring fund.

COMPETING IN A TOTALLY DEREGULATED MARKET

    —  T&L have repeatedly claimed they could survive in a totally deregulated market. This assertion has been used to promote the notion that their operations are somehow more economically "pure" and justifiable in the context of a European market which is partially regulated.

    —  The figures behind this claim are set out on page 6 of their evidence. In this, they have assumed figures for extra freight (ie shipping) costs of $55/tonne and for extra unloading/storage of $20/tonne. No sources have been attached to support these figures.

    —  We have secured quotations as follows (full details are available if required) which suggest these figures are inflated:
Extra Freight Cost[29]       $20/tonne
Extra Unloading Costs[30]       $10/tonne


    This indicates that the total refining margin available in a deregulated market is not $120/tonne as stated on page 6 of their evidence, but $85/tonne:
$/Tonne
Extra Sugar Cost45
Extra Freight Costs20
Extra Unloading/Logistics Costs10
85


    —  This total available refining margin must cover both the refiner's costs and a reasonable return for the business. The lowest acceptable level of return on total net assets to enable any business to cover its cost of capital is roughly 10% (this is half that suggested by T&L in the Select Committee hearings). For European refiners, this would be equivalent to about $35/tonne.[31]

    —  This implies, by subtraction, that to be able to compete in a fully deregulated market then a refiner's operating costs must be no higher than $50/tonne (

    42/tonne).

    —  If T&L are indeed this efficient, they would receive much higher returns from the reform proposals than any European beet processor (see accompanying report27).

    —  Their returns from the reform proposals would also be higher than in a totally deregulated market.

    —  In addition, if T&L can genuinely compete in a totally deregulated market as they claim, then they would be able to "toll refine[32]" world market raw sugar, by taking advantage of the differential in price between raw and white sugar on the world market. There are no regulatory restrictions preventing this happening, so their refinery would always be able to top up their normal ACP/LDC supplies, and need never have to operate under-capacity (page 9 of their submission suggests their Thames refinery is only operating at 85% capacity).

    —  Finally, pages 18 and 19 of their submission lists 12 refineries worldwide which have been built or expanded in the last decade, suggesting that competing in a totally deregulated market is straightforward for stand-alone refineries, and relatively commonplace. However, this is not the case. Of the 12 refineries quoted, 11 are protected by import tariffs and are therefore not operating in a deregulated market at all.

GUARANTEED CANE SUPPLIES FOR REFINERS

    —  T&L assert (on page 2 of their submission) that refiners should be granted guaranteed "base supplies" to cover their fixed costs, similar to the beet sector's production quotas.

    —  One of the European Commission's main reform principles is to bring the EU market into supply/demand balance. It proposes to do this by eliminating 5 million tonnes (30%) of Europe's beet quota production. Refiners are completely protected from these permanent quota cuts. If refiners want "quotas" similar to the beet sector, then they must be prepared to shoulder their part of the burden, and accept that their supplies should be reduced in line with everyone else's. This could easily be done without jeopardising the ACP commitment, by sharing raws supplies with beet processors.

    —  This claim also implies that beet quotas offer a guaranteed volume and supply for beet processors. This is not the case. On the contrary, the European Commission has deliberately set the beet price so low (

    25/tonne) that many beet industries will shrink or collapse: hence the cut in beet quota production of 5 million tonnes. Even in efficient countries like the UK, beet supplies are not assured—as concluded in DEFRA's impact assessment. European beet quotas are therefore a ceiling, not a guarantee.

    —  In addition to being totally protected from permanent quota cuts, refiners have also been offered two further concessions on supplies: complete exclusivity for the first three years of the reform, and preferential access for 2008 to 2015.

    —  These concessions offer refiners considerably more security of supply than beet processors—there is certainly no case for increasing this imbalance by offering refiners even greater supply guarantees.

EUROPEAN GATEWAY FOR ACP

    —  T&L have often suggested that stand-alone refiners are a necessary gateway into Europe for ACP (and LDC) developing countries. They comment on it again in their supplementary evidence (page 1).

    —  However, the attached letters from two principal ACP suppliers, Swaziland and Fiji, to DEFRA tell a very different story.

    —  Points made in their letters include:

    —  Restricting cane raws supplies to full-time refiners, as proposed in Article 29(2) of the Commission's proposals, is against the interests of ACP countries, and contravenes the terms of the ACP Protocol.

    —  Freedom to supply cane raws to a variety of buyers, including beet processors, would improve the terms, conditions and prices available for ACP countries, so giving greater value to their EU market access.

    —  ACP strongly oppose any form of supply exclusivity for refiners in the new reform period 2006-15.

    —  Port handling facilities at T&L's Thames Refinery are sub-optimal, for example because vessels sizes are restricted, which increases ACP countries' costs.

    —  ACP returns have recently been adversely affected by operational and commercial constraints imposed by refiners on their contracts by refiners.

    —  In reality, "co-refining" cane raws in beet factories is a highly efficient process, which is common practice outside the EU.

CONCLUSIONS

  The Commission's sugar reform proposals are radical and hard-hitting. They have been specifically designed to restructure the whole of the European sugar sector, to eliminate the surpluses and to drive efficiency.

  As such, they will have severe effects on everyone. The European beet industry, for example, is expected to have to close over 50 factories with between 80,000[33] and 150,000[34] jobs lost.

  In this "brave new world" there can be no guarantees. Even for the UK beet industry, regarded by the Commission as one of Europe's most efficient, beet supplies are not assured and the forfeit of UK quota into the Restructuring Scheme cannot be ruled out.

  Like the rest of the European industry, refiners are worried about the effects on them of the coming reforms. This is understandable—we all are. But refiners have already been offered valuable concession in the proposals. Apart from their possible inclusion in the Restructuring Scheme, any further concessions are wholly unjustified and would move the beet/cane balance even more in their favour. The reforms will have tough consequences for everyone, including refiners. This is true, but does not justify exclusive handouts to prop up one sector which are denied everyone else.

British Sugar

November 2005













27   "Financial effects of sugar reform proposals on European refiners and beet processors", 2005. British Sugar evidence to EFRA Select Committee, 2005. (Please see Annex 1 on Ev 76). Back

28   Report on UK refiner, LMC International, 2004. Back

29   How Robinson Shipping Ltd. Back

30   GP Shipping, Port Agency Services; JPL Stevedoring Contractors. Back

31   "Competing in a fully deregulated world market", 2005. British Sugar evidence to EFRA Select Committee, 2005. Back

32   Toll refining is a process where world market raw sugar is temporarily imported, refined and the refined white sugar re-exported outside the EU. No tariff is paid on these imports. Back

33   Evidence given by Lars Hoelgaard of the European Commission to the House of Lords Inquiry on sugar reform, October 2005. Back

34   European Economic and Social Committee, October 2005. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2005
Prepared 22 November 2005