Select Committee on Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Written Evidence


Further supplementary memorandum submitted by Tate & Lyle Sugars, Europe

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

  1.  This supplementary evidence is in response to the Committee's disclosure of supplementary evidence from British Sugar on refining issues. TALSE is grateful to the Committee for the access afforded to the British Sugar supplementary evidence. However, TALSE is very disappointed that British Sugar's submission—which seeks to undermine the sugar refining sector—is based on detailed data and calculations which are not published for reasons of "confidentiality". This makes it virtually impossible to provide the full and robust response which the paper requires particularly as it would appear that incorrect figures may have been used, the methodology may be flawed and figures extracted out of context (eg £250 million on capital employed in the UK refining operation for taking sugar from raw to bulk).

  2.  The British Sugar evidence explicitly suggests that TALSE is seeking concessions and special treatment. TALSE is not seeking special treatment. We are only asking that a company that could compete effectively in a totally deregulated market should be treated equitably in a regime that continues to be based on the desire to artificially support the beet sector. This equity extends to margin and supply of sugar for refining. Indeed, in delivering equity, we are simply asking for the Commission to deliver on its previous assurances to the refining sector that "the Community refining sector can maintain its competitiveness under fair conditions".

3.  CONCURRENT/OFF CROP REFINING

  The supplementary evidence provided by British Sugar fails to disclose the cross subsidy available from processing of the beet quota itself. The beet processors' fixed costs are already covered by the artificial support provided by the beet regime. A simple comparison of the respective efficiency of refining imported sugar in a beet factory or a cane refinery can only be done if all variable and fixed costs are brought into the picture. Comparison must take into account the cross subsidy.

4.  MARGIN

  There can be no denying the fact that the cane refiners' margin has been reduced to

44. This is significantly below the operating costs of TALSE and was covered in greater detail in the earlier written and oral evidence.

5.  COMPETING IN A DEREGULATED MARKET

  The comparison between the cost of importing sugar for refining in the country of consumption and the alternative of importing a range of refined products for consumption in that same market contains many elements, some of which would be unique to the operation in question. eg Shipping routes used, the type of ships used, bagging, and handling of refined product at import destination. The detailed figures are not straightforward and would always be the subject of careful scrutiny and evaluation by the professional project team working on the feasibility study or final detailed project. The figures may vary from project to project but the expansion of destination refineries in countries of consumption and the acceptance of this international business model is proven by the number of projects which have recently been developed, enlarged, being built currently or the subject of feasibility subsidies. Fuller details of the expansion of this business model was given in the LMC evidence attached to TALSE's earlier supplementary evidence.

6.  REFINERY COSTS IN OTHER WORLD REFINERIES

  The data provided by British Sugar is not backed up by spreadsheets or even the raw cost data for the refineries used in the comparison. This makes it very difficult to provide informed comment. TALSE can only conclude from the general nature of the figures that perhaps like for like comparisons have not consistently been made. For example TALSE is familiar with the costs of the Jeddah refinery in which it has a 10% shareholding; it was designed by Tate & Lyle and the project management was undertaken by a 50/50 joint venture company, Booker Tate. In the limited time available TALSE asked LMC International, the leading independent provider of economic analysis and advice to the sugar and sweetener sector, to use its own knowledge of Jeddah refining costs and adjust these to take account of the circumstances under which the UK refinery operates ie like for like benchmarking eg EU's statutory import arrangements prevent the use of VHP (Very High Polling) sugar for refining which if available would significantly reduce the cost of capital, labour and energy at Thames; Jeddah has high levels of capacity utilisation because access to raw sugar is unconstrained; it operates in a relatively low wage economy; and it has access to extremely cheap oil. When brought to a like for like basis the Jeddah costs of just below $50 (

42) rise to a UK cost equivalent of somewhere in the region of $120 (

102). It is the latter figure which is important in the context of the EU Sugar Regime and in international cost comparisons. The full report is attached as Appendix I.[35]

7.  COMPETITION BETWEEN BEET PROCESSORS AND CANE REFINERS FOR SUGAR FOR REFINING.

  The base business of the beet processors is to process their beet quotas and cover their fixed costs. The base business of the cane refiner is to refine a quantity of sugar for refining (the refiners do not have an equivalent to a quota) and cover their fixed costs. Thereafter the two businesses should be able to compete with each other for supplies of sugar for refining on a variable cost basis. The above five factors (paragraphs 3 to 7) are dealt with in more detail below.

SECTION I

Supply of sugar for refining

  8.  Refining is a high fixed costs business. The Thames Refinery is currently generally recognised to have a capacity of about 1.3 million tonnes. However, it actually has a capacity of 1.5 million tonnes and could run at this level permanently with only minor technical adjustments and expenditure. The main expenditure would be on packaging equipment, not basic refining equipment. Therefore the refinery is essentially forced to run at 75% of capacity. The British Government and European Commission have always been sensitive to the capacity utilisation issues because of their effect on unit costs and margin requirement. Equally the authorities, since the UK joined the EU and the Sugar Protocol was established, have always been conscious of the inbuilt subsidy provided by the regime to any beet processor, taking sugar for refining in a beet factory, from the restricted supply of imported sugar. In recognition of this a scheme was run for many years by the EU to cancel out the acknowledged subsidy.

  9.  Without the benefit of the cross subsidy it is doubtful that any concurrent/off crop refining would take place at the level of the proposed EU reference price. Also the thrust of the reform proposal is to eliminate a target quantity of beet production, close beet factories and reduce exports to a maximum of 1.3 million tonnes, or eliminate them altogether. Beet factories entering concurrent/off crop refining would counter EU policy by stretching artificially the life of a beet factory by the use of the cross subsidy.

SECTION II

EU supply/demand balance: beet volume versus import volume

  10.  The refiners do not enjoy complete protection from supply cuts; indeed they have never had anything equivalent to a quota in the first place. TALSE has already closed five of its original six refineries at no financial cost to the EU or the consumer. TALSE and its employees have already made very significant sacrifices in financial and human terms during the period when beet has expanded since the regime was first established in 1968. A further reduction in sugar for refining arbitrarily imposed by the EU would simply result in TALSE being an unprofitable business in spite of being an industry able to compete effectively in a deregulated market. Also, TALSE may have to compete for restricted raw sugar supplies against other companies which under a new EU definition may be classed as full time refiners only for the purposes of the regime. On the other hand, British Sugar will not have competition from other companies for its future beet supplies. This will enable it to keep premia to the minimum possible level required to attract farmers to supply beet rather than go into alternative crops. The refiners will have even greater competition than at present for raw supplies.

  11.  Also, British Sugar is not suffering a quota cut as such. It will have a choice of two commercial alternatives if its raw material supply should be insufficient. As a result of its negotiations with beet growers it can either go to the restructuring fund and close a plant or pay an increased price for beet which is sufficiently attractive compared to the price achievable by farmers for alternative crops. Neither of these choices is open to the refiner. Also British Sugar will have the possibility of purchasing extra quota. The options available to beet processors compared to full time refiners are summarised in Appendix II.

  12.  If the supply of imported sugar to the refiners were to be reduced this would, in certain cases, involve the EU being in breach of international import obligations while in other cases result in the reduction in the financial expectations of ACP and LDC suppliers currently benefiting from additional import opportunities given to them by the EU on a concessionary basis.

  13.  In a three year period to 2009 the arrangements differ from those that will apply from after 2009 when duty free and quota free access for LDC sugar comes into effect. It is essential to look at the development of the EU market for refining over the full nine year span of the new regime. The LDCs claim that at the current proposed price only 300,000 tonnes of additional sugar will become available. On the other hand the Commission regularly points to 2.2 million tonnes of additional sugar being available in 20011-12. British Sugar puts the figure at 2 to 4 million tonnes per year. This range of figures underlines the market uncertainties and political posturing. In addition British Sugar has aligned itself with the European Beet Lobby which is lobbying hard for severe restrictions to be placed on these LDC imports. This continuing doubt and controversy over the ultimate level of sugar available for refining runs counter to the declared wish of the Commission to provide the whole EU sugar industry with a long-term financial perspective with known conditions and where sound investment and strategic decisions can be made. It is against this background that the Commission is attempting to provide some sort of supply assurance or stability for refining after 2009.

SECTION III

Refining margin

  14.  British Sugar feels that the institutional margin of

44 should enable TALSE to cover its fixed and variable costs and make an acceptable return on capital. This is simply not the case. In fact, the

44 margin in the proposals is significantly below the operating costs of TALSE whilst the

180 afforded to beet processors would allow an efficient processor to cover fixed and variable costs as well as make an acceptable return on capital employed in the business.

  15.  It is extremely difficult to try to reconcile the many figures quoted by British Sugar in regard to margin. Without full access to the spreadsheets and the Confidential Appendices one can only assume that there could be some sort of miscalculation of the figures used or that the analysis of the net margins can only have been based on an expectation of a significant market premium over the reference price. The latter is not thought to be the case given the assurances which seem to have been given to the sugar using industries in regard to how the market price will relate to the reference price in the reformed regime. In particular Note 2 of Annex I refers to worksheets. If any of those should be some of the Commission's working documents then it must be noted that these themselves are the subject of ongoing questioning by several parties.

SECTION IV

Competing in a fully deregulated market

  16.  The figures here would benefit from a greater transparency. The white/raw differential used has not been reduced to account for a conversion factor of raw sugar to white sugar equivalent. This conversion process was explained in the earlier evidence given to the Committee by TALSE (it is not clear how this has been taken into account in other parts of the exercise where this adjustment is essential in examining and comparing refining margins). The analysis has chosen to assume Brazilian white sugar. However, no account has been taken of the premium that would be payable to secure white sugar of EU quality from Brazil. This is because the LIFFE futures contracts represents sugar of lower quality than that from the EU. The premium over the LIFFE price of sugar of EU quality has typically been $20 (

17) per tonne over the last five years. This would raise the differential to the full time destination refiner by the equivalent amount. The shipping differential is based on the comparison of 50kg bags with bulk raw sugar. However, no EU customer of TALSE accepts delivery of 50kg bags. This form of packing is generally only acceptable in developing country markets such as Africa and the former Soviet Union. EU customers require many sophisticated product, packaging and delivery service permutations. These usually can only be serviced by shipping in containers or having expensive storage and repacking operations at the port of import which have capital and variable costs far in excess of the $10 assumption in the paper.

  17.  As set out in the executive summary these figures have to be looked at on a project by project basis by the professionals involved in the feasibility study. These figures must be specific to the project in hand and subject to sensitivity analysis. It is therefore not out of order for

100 to

110 per tonne to be regarded as the sort of margin level which would be available to a destination refiner in a totally deregulated market—see Appendix III.

SECTION V

World market refinery costs

  18.  There are a number of references to world market refining costs taken from LMC studies throughout the document but once again TALSE has no option but to accept that these are unchallengeable and have been made so by being included in a confidential Annex.

  19.  When attempting refining cost comparisons it is essential to compare like with like. In paragraph 6 TALSE drew attention to work done by LMC to benchmark the Jeddah refinery with the Thames operation. These demonstrate British Sugar's flawed methodology and it is almost certain that analysis of other refineries would give conclusions/comparisons similar to the Jeddah exercise.

  20.  It is also claimed that TALSE could use its spare capacity for toll refining. This is the process of importing world market priced raw sugar, refining it, and re-exporting the white sugar to importing countries. This is in fact done on a very limited scale at the moment if market conditions permit it. However, this can rarely be the case because the process involves the freight charge of importing raws as well as the freight charge for exporting the resulting refined sugar for direct consumption.


35   Not printed. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2005
Prepared 22 November 2005