Select Committee on Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 400-419)

MR ANDREW PERRINS AND MR MARTIN JOHNSON

10 MAY 2006

  Q400  Chairman: Let me just stop you. You used the word "key". How do we rank in the various stratagems the use of biofuels?

  Mr Johnson: There are different measures that Government has used, both in the Energy White Paper in 2003 and then in the review of the Climate Change Programme this year. You can look at measures like the lifetime cost of carbon abatement per tonne of carbon and I think that would be the key measure that you would use. If you take in that measure things like domestic or business energy efficiency would score very highly. They would have a positive net present value. Things like onshore wind would score better than offshore wind, for example, and then you would have a ranking perhaps within transport where biofuels would be relatively competitive compared with, for example, the latest assessment of hybrid technologies or the use of hydrogen in internal combustion engines.

  Q401  Chairman: Is that ranking that you have described in relation to a trade-off of carbon savings for every pound of the public purse that is used to stimulate the development of the particular area that you have described?

  Mr Johnson: It is not so much the public purse; it is the resource cost to the economy so it is, if you like, regardless of whether it is from the general taxpayer or through consumer payment or whatever the funding route is. It is a measure of the resource cost and that is the analytical basis on which this is looked at.

  Q402  Chairman: For example, when Sheffield Hallam did their work on looking at the relationship between what you got for each pound of public money spent on energy savings, loft insulation was streets ahead. You have talked about different returns. Is there a piece of paper on which somebody ranks all of these returns so that we can see where in the pecking order bioenergy comes? The reason I ask that question is that if you look at the second annex of the Biomass Task Force report there are two pages of itty-bitty little schemes stimulating this, that and the other thing. There are no outputs against it, in other words, what is the rate of return for this, what are we trying to achieve, how much carbon are we saving from the use of biomass in that context? Therefore, in terms of policy I am left wondering whether this is seen by the Treasury as a bit of a nuisance but something you have to do because it is all bitty and very difficult, whether it is an environmental necessity because you have to have a broad portfolio of routes in to reducing greenhouse gas emissions or whether you think there is a strategic benefit because it does affect energy security. I am still not clear where in that ranking the use of bioenergy comes. Can you shed a little more light on it?

  Mr Johnson: The commitment to biofuels from the Treasury is very real. We brought in the duty incentive for biodiesel in 2002 and for bioethanol in 2005, and I think Treasury ministers, along with those in the Department for Transport, Defra and DTI, have been very much at the centre of the policy development process and the Renewable Transport Fuel Obligation announcements, both in the PBR[1] and then at the time of the recent Budget, have been symbolic of the Treasury's engagement with biofuels. That is the first thing: the Treasury commitment on biofuels is genuine. In 2008-09 the cost of the 20p duty differential is expected to be about £300 million based on a market share of 2.5% biofuels. Just on that point, I think the commitment is real. In terms of the ranking point, you made the point about loft insulation. My understanding is that what you said is right: it is one of the very best things that you can do, but there are only so many lofts that you can insulate and you do need a broad range of policies, some of which deliver now, some of which deliver now but also—and this is the case for biofuels I think—should deliver more savings in future more cheaply, and that is where there is a strategic—

  Q403 Chairman: You can see why I am asking the question, because one of the things we have to derive from the report is to talk about whether in fact we think the amount of support to pump-prime and stimulate this innovative and interesting area of energy is sufficient but it is very difficult for us to do that in an informed way unless we have something that enables us to rank it in terms of what we get for the expenditure. If there is any information you can give us to help us put into context what you have just said it would be helpful. You mentioned the 20p duty derogation. Why did you decide 20p was the right number?

  Mr Johnson: The 20p has been there since 2002. I think the assessment that ministers made was that 20p was the right level which would balance on the one hand giving enough incentive so that you will begin to move the market, because if you do not do that then it is not worth having, but on the other hand balancing what is felt to be an acceptable cost to the Exchequer in exchange for the carbon savings.

  Q404  Chairman: With respect, Mr Johnson, you have not actually answered my question. You said that ministers had decided. Ministers do not decide anything unless somebody gives them some information to make a decision upon, and somebody in your area of the world must have sat down and done a calculation because, for example, at the pump the price differential of biodiesel versus ordinary diesel is perhaps a pence or two a litre, hardly any difference between the two, notwithstanding the fact that there is a duty derogation of 20p. Some people suggested at the outset that it should be 27p or 30p; that was rejected, but I have never understood why 20p was deemed to be the right number.

  Mr Johnson: Without wanting not to answer the question, I must say I was not in post at that time but my best guess would be that an assessment was done on the additional resource cost of biofuels and that 20p was viewed to be an approximation of the additional cost of production and therefore a fair duty discount to offer.

  Q405  Chairman: That is an ex post rationalisation of it and it is not a bad stab but it might be the case that some could have argued that you needed to be a little more generous at the pump to encourage people prior to the arrival of the Renewable Transport Fuels Obligation to use this material against a background where, of the sectors where greenhouse gas emissions were rising, the domestic sector and the transport sector are the two which have been going up. If you cannot answer it now because you were not in post I fully accept that, but I think the Committee would find it very helpful to have a little more detailed information as to why 20 was deemed to be the right number and why, in terms of encouraging the uptake of this ahead of the RTFO, nothing more than 20p was given. Against that background you were very generous on LPG and as a result got an infrastructure in place and then gradually backed off the amount of discount, but you have not done that with biofuels and I think the Committee would be very interested to know about that.

  Mr Johnson: I am happy to provide a note on that, and also, in terms of the ranking of policies, there is material that has been published but again I am happy to provide a note on that one which draws together the best material that we have on that.[2]

  Q406 Chairman: You have taken a pretty hard line view on unprocessed biofuels. You have given no discount to encourage uptake of that at all. Why?

  Mr Johnson: The requirement to get the 20p discount relates to the legislation in the Hydrocarbon Oils Duty Act. That legislation sets out a definition of "biodiesel" and it has four parameters. One is that the fuel must be of diesel quality; secondly, it must have an ester content of 96.5% or more; there is a sulphur limit, and also it must come from biomass sources. We announced at the Budget that we would review the definition as it stands but, to try and answer your question directly, the concern is on the one hand to reward fuels that offer an environmental benefit because we want to encourage those for the climate change benefits that they give you, but on the other responding to concerns that there might be, both from car manufacturers worried about engines, and indeed motorists, and then other biofuel producers who may have concerns about quality and a level playing field. You will be aware that there have been MPs, companies and others who have questioned the current interpretation that Revenue and Customs have made of the legislation in certain parts of the country. Plymouth Biofuels are one company in that position, with whom I had a meeting this morning as part of this review, but we said at Budget that we will look at this and we expect to do that over the summer.

  Q407  Chairman: What is the Treasury stance with reference to flexible-fuel vehicles? Ford and Saab have got these vehicles available. Ford are making them more generally available in the United Kingdom. Here we are moving to bioethanol as opposed to biodiesel and there is a novelty in the technology that is available: there are not warranty issues, the car is £200 more expensive than a normal one. Hardly an inducement to buy cars like that is given through the duty discount in terms of the road fund licence It is a bit half-hearted in response to a bit of really good technology. From the Treasury standpoint why are you not giving it a bit more of a push?

  Mr Johnson: In countries like Brazil principally and Sweden increasingly within Europe this is a technology where the manufacturers and the infrastructure have responded. We know that in Brazil, for example, the great majority of new vehicles sold are flexi-fuel vehicles. Companies like Ford and Saab are now beginning to bring models onto the market. You have got the Somerset project going on. In terms of the Treasury's response, the Renewable Transport Fuel Obligation is the central government response to biofuels generally and the way that mechanism will work is that it will offer incentives for E85 as much as 5% blends, in that the way the certificate trading system works should provide some incentives for E85. To some extent it is up to the market how that biofuel, that 5% by volume, is distributed. I know we have had representations just recently to look again at the company car tax framework and to look at other incentives. Of course we will look at that, but one thing I would say is, okay, Sweden is ahead of the game, but this is a relatively new area within the rest of Europe. It is something which departments are beginning to look at seriously now and it is something that we intend to look more closely at over the coming months. The RTFO is the key mechanism which will support biofuels generally.

  Q408  Chairman: But, for example, when the Government moved strongly to remove lead from petrol there was a very clear price signal given in the discount between the two forms of fuel. Here we have a virtually indistinguishable discount and nothing much else in the pot, and yet motor manufacturers have got some proven technology available in the market place. The point that is being made to us is that if you are going to get people to move to more environmentally friendly technologies you have to give them a little bit of inducement because it is new and novel. I suppose it is about sharing the risk. Let me ask this question. At Gleneagles it was said that ministers were going to be moved around in flexi-fuel vehicles. If it was good enough for ministers then what are you doing with the government car fleet? Has the Treasury said, "We have got to move to flexible-fuel vehicles in the government car fleet"? Has the Treasury got any?

  Mr Johnson: I believe the Chancellor now has a hybrid vehicle.

  Q409  Chairman: But not a flexible-fuel vehicle?

  Mr Johnson: No, that is correct, but any more than that I could not tell you. That would be a procurement policy issue rather than one that would come to me. Ministers have certainly purchased greener cars, perhaps not flexi-fuel vehicles though.

  Q410  Chairman: So we are a little bit behind the weekend at Gleneagles in terms of the Government. Let me just move to the conclusion of this section of the questioning. We have a buy-out price for the RTFO. I am interested to know what economic modelling the Treasury has done to see how much potential investment money at your 15p a litre discount is going to be generated as a result of this. In theory, if all the fuel companies were able to source properly there should not be any money from the buy-out, but how many do you know are relying on investment capital from the buy-out? Why did you settle at 15p? Why was that number chosen?

  Mr Johnson: Maybe I can just take a step back and say a little bit about the package of announcements and how the different incentives will work together. What we announced at Budget was first the target levels for RTFO were 2.5% biofuels in 2008-09, 3.75% in 2009-10 and 5% in 2010-11. We announced that the duty incentive would be maintained at 20p in 2008-09, and that is the first year of RTFO. Then we also announced that the buy-out price would be 15p in 2008-09. That means that in the first year of RTFO you will have 20p duty incentive and you will also have an additional incentive of 15p per litre buy-out. What that means is that where companies fail to meet their obligation they will have to pay a 15p per litre penalty. That means that not only do you have a 20p reward but you also have an additional 15p disincentive, and if you take the combination of these two things that is a significant step forward from simply having a 20p incentive, which is where we are now. We also announced that that combination, that 35p, would be maintained in 2009-10 before reducing to 30p in 2010-11 but without specifying how the package would be split. To answer your question about who is relying on buy-out payments, the answer to that is that nobody should be relying on buy-out payments. The mechanism is not designed such that people should rely on payments. It is more that if people choose to buy out rather than meet the obligation they will have an additional penalty, if you like, which is that their rivals who have met the obligation will receive that penalty money—

  Q411  Chairman: That does not actually answer the question I have asked though. You are doing a very good job of driving away from the question so let me bring you back. The question I asked was, why 15p? Why did you decide that was the right number? Let me add to that. In terms of the length of time that the capital assets involved in the production of biofuels would be operating do you consider that the timetable of the fiscal regime you have outlined is sufficiently long to give certainty to investors?

  Mr Johnson: The way the 15p was derived was to do with a study which Climate Change Capital did for the Department for Transport last year. They recommended that a combination of support within the range of 25-30p was required to shift towards biofuels to make it economic. That was their view based on the additional resource cost of what companies needed. Ministers took the view that rather than just have a combination of 25-30p duty and buy-out they would go beyond that and offer a combination of 35p duty and buy-out in the first two years, so the 15p was added to the 20p that was there and got you to 35p, and that was more than the study that Climate Change Capital recommended. That was how the 15p was derived. It was based on the assessment that Climate Change Capital did and that Graham Meeks, who was with them at the time and I know has given evidence to the Committee, refreshed that analysis in his new role in January/February, and he came back to us and that evidence suggested that a package of roundabout 30p was sufficient. Ministers decided they would give this mechanism an additional kick-start and go a little bit further than the 30p with a 35p combination, and that was how the decision was arrived at.

  Q412  Lynne Jones: What about the length of time that it is going to take?

  Mr Johnson: Sorry; that was the other part of the question. You also asked about the long term nature of this package. I think it is important to say that in terms of duty the duty incentives are for three years. The view was taken by ministers, based on what they had heard from the industry and what they had heard from investors, that three years was insufficient to deliver in an industry where capital assets are basically repaid over up to 10 years. That is the key benefit of RTFO. That is why RTFO is a very significant step forward. You are talking about a long term mechanism. I think the DfT feasibility report talks about 15 years. This is a mechanism which gives the certainty to industry that they said they needed as well as the financial rewards that should reflect the additional cost of biofuels.

  Q413  Chairman: Can I just ask whether the calculation that you do on these matters is updated to take into account what must be additional revenue coming back to biofuels producers by virtue of the rise in the hydrocarbon fuel price?

  Mr Johnson: The short answer is yes, it is.

  Q414  Chairman: It is an interesting question that comes out of this. When the 20p duty derogation was set, I think some two or three years ago, prices of hydrocarbon fuels were probably in the mid-70p's. Now they are nudging a pound. What calculations have you done to show the extra revenue that is going in? I go back to my point that the pump differential appears to be hardly any different and yet the margin above where these differential prices were set has widened perhaps to 10p or 15p a litre. Have you done any modelling to look at the increased cash flow? Am I right in thinking there should be increased cash flow?

  Mr Johnson: At first glance you would think that would be the case. Where the complexity comes in is that increasingly we have seen the biodiesel market price start to track the crude oil price. What you have is that as the oil price rises the biodiesel price tends to follow it, so where you would expect to see a margin open up it does not necessarily happen. There is volatility in the biodiesel/biofuel market as there is in the oil market. In terms of the question on modelling, yes, it is updated. We do work with Defra, we do work with the RIA[3] and we do take account of this, but because of this tracking and the linkage that you can see between these prices these margins do not always operate in that way.

  Q415 Chairman: But the raw material price for making the fuel has not followed the oil price, has it?

  Mr Johnson: Not necessarily. I am not an expert on this.

  Q416  Chairman: Mr Perrins, can you help us on that?

  Mr Perrins: One factor that has changed on raw material prices would be the very high increase in the world sugar price we have seen over the last year which is a significant factor in determining the bioethanol price.

  Q417  Chairman: But not biodiesel.

  Mr Perrins: Indeed.

  Q418  Chairman: That is the bit I am interested in because in terms of UK manufacturing capacity there is visibility on that. There is zero visibility on bioethanol.

  Mr Perrins: The demand for biodiesel as well as bioethanol has also significantly risen on the UK market, the European market and the world market over this time frame. We are seeing, for example, very strong demand for raw materials around Europe, which would be rape seed, for example, or sunflower seed in Mediterranean countries, to go into biodiesel production which is moving ahead very rapidly in certain parts of Europe such as Germany and Spain. That demand increase is clearly impacting on the raw material prices and as a consequence the price of biodiesel itself.

  Q419  Mr Drew: Speaking as someone who was persuaded to buy an LPG vehicle, we went through a similar problem in that the differential never grew because LPG seemed also to increase despite the fact that it is a so-called waste product. What is never taken account of is that you get a much lower level of performance from an LPG vehicle which means that you use twice as much of it. It is a nice notion that you really are encouraging the user by giving them a price differential but when you have got an existing vehicle and you just put biodiesel into the fuel I wonder whether it makes any difference to the performance which then counteracts the benefit you might get in terms of a lower price.

  Mr Johnson: I think with biofuels at 5% blend, which I think is what you are going to see—


1   Pre-Budget Report Back

2   Ev 183, A. Back

3   Regulatory Impact Assessment Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2006
Prepared 18 September 2006