Select Committee on Foreign Affairs Minutes of Evidence


Written evidence submitted by Dr Linda Y Yueh, University of Oxford, and London School of Economics

  It is my pleasure to make this submission to the Foreign Affairs Committee. The focus of this memorandum is on the wider economic impact of the People's Republic of China, concluding with a discussion of the ensuing policy implications.

I.  THE RISE OF CHINA

The remarkable economic growth of China has propelled it to become the fourth largest economy in the world in the span of just 27 years. With economic growth averaging 9.5%, GDP will be expected to double approximately every eight years. However, GDP per capita in China is estimated to be just under $2,000, which places it within the ranks of the world's developing countries. Although this suggests that China will face numerous challenges as both a developing country as well as an economy undergoing transition from a centrally planned economy, it also indicates that the growth potential of China will be significant as it is starting from a much lower level than comparable economies in terms of aggregate GDP.

  China's economic power as a result of its remarkable growth is increasing its importance in the Asian region and in the global economy. Coupled with its significant political influence, most clearly seen in its position as one of the five permanent members of the UN Security Council, its economic development raises questions concerning the wider impact of China's economic growth.

  The dimensions of China's economic impact can be divided into at least four areas: international trade, international capital flows, effects on global markets for raw materials and commodities, and effects on global economic growth. In terms of international trade, China has become in the span of a decade the world's third largest exporter and importer. China also holds the third largest stock of foreign direct investment (FDI) in the world behind just the US and UK. In recent years, it has often been the leading destination for global FDI, particularly since China joined the World Trade Organisation (WTO) at the end of 2001 when it began to implement greater trade and financial liberalisation. China is a leading consumer of major commodities, after only the United States in its consumption of oil. Finally, although China accounts for less than 5% of world GDP in 2005 as compared with the US whose share is around 28%, its contribution to global incremental growth is substantially above its weight in the global economy. From 1980-2000, when calculated on the basis of purchasing power parity (PPP), China's contribution to world economic growth accounted for around 14%, second only to the US which generated around 20% of global growth. In the past few years, China's contribution to global growth in PPP terms was around 30%. When calculated at market exchange rates, its contribution to global growth was 13% on average from 2000-04 and 14% last year. The attention increasingly paid to China as one of the so-called twin engines of growth in the global economy is a result of these figures. However, it is worth keeping in mind that China remains substantially smaller than the US despite its rapid growth rate.

  These areas of potential impact will be discussed with respect to the Asian region, the global economy, and then specifically with respect to the UK and EU. This paper will conclude with an assessment of policy considerations for the UK. Given the scope of the enquiry, the emphasis will be on placing China in its regional context.

II.  ECONOMIC IMPACT OF CHINA ON THE ASIAN REGION

  Although it began in 1979 with the first waves of market-oriented reforms, China's "open door" policy did not take off until 1992 following then President Deng Xiaoping's famous southern tour where he inspected and admired the success of the early Special Economic Zones, which were essentially export-processing areas for manufactured goods, in Guangdong and Fujian provinces. A common perception of China's rise since then is that it will be accompanied by the decline of its neighbours who had fuelled their growth by exports and particularly manufactured exports. China would be a lower cost producer and thus could threaten the global market share of other Asian economies.

  Over the period 1990-2000, Chinese-manufactured exports grew by 16.9% per annum, compared with 10.3% for the rest of East Asia, and its world market share tripled during that period. China's share of the global export market grew even faster after 2000. By 2005, China accounted for around 6% of global markets in manufactured goods. Moreover, China's transformation from a relatively minor exporter of electronics in 1990 into one of the largest in the region a decade later is remarkable not only on account of its speed but also because electronics has been the chief engine of the East Asian region's export-oriented growth. Even before WTO accession, China's electronic exports grew by 16.9% year-on-year in 2001, while those of the rest of Asia fell by 18.8% for the same year. Accession to the WTO is also expected to improve market access for Chinese textiles and garments abroad as well as open the domestic market to trade. This suggests that China could expand its global market share of textiles and clothing considerably above the estimated 15% that it held before the phase-out of the Multi-Fibre Agreement on 1 January 2005. Estimates place the potential market share of Chinese goods in these two areas in the region of 50% of the global market.

  Moreover, medium and high technology goods have been growing quickly in China, and the below figure gives a picture of the market share of Chinese goods vis-a"-vis its neighbours in 1990 and then a decade later. The economies covered in East and Southeast Asia are the old "Tiger" economies of Hong Kong, Singapore, Taiwan and South Korea, and the new "Tiger" economies of Malaysia, Thailand, Indonesia and the Philippines. Although Japan is a considerable economy in the region, due to its status as a developed country, it is less likely to be affected in the same way as developing Asia. China's economic relationship with Japan will be discussed later in the submission.

  Source:   WTO.

  Despite the general perception outlined above, the data on trade patterns from the 1990s onward suggest that China's rise has not harmed the global market share of its neighbours except for the rather unique exception of Hong Kong. Instead, China's rise has been accompanied by the growth of global market share in manufactured goods of the rest of Asia. In terms of market share of global trade in manufactured products, China has grown from having a mere 1.87%-4.70% between 1990 and 2000. Despite the global import quota system, China gained the most market share in low technology products, such as textiles and clothing. Also impressive has been its gain of export markets in medium and high technology goods as well as resource based goods. The rapid growth in market share of high technology goods, which has been the main engine of growth of the Asian Tigers, in particular is noteworthy. In the span of a decade, China grew from having 0.69% of the world market, a percentage similar to the New Tigers (eg, Thailand with 0.74%), to 4.06% in 2000, a market share that is threatening to the old Tigers. For instance, South Korea has a market share of 4.48% and Taiwan holds 4.87%, while Singapore has 5.88%. Alone among the new Tigers, Malaysia has achieved a similar share of 3.75% in 2000, although it started with a greater share in 1990 of 1.59% of the market. This adds support to the ability of China to engage in the rapid technological upgrading of its manufactures as well as expand in its established labour-intensive products. It currently has a share of global trade that is comparable to that of the established Tigers. The four new Tigers of Malaysia, Thailand, Indonesia and the Philippines began with less than 1% of global trade in 1990 and have grown quickly to account for more than 1% in overall manufactures market share in 2000. However, this falls behind China which started with a slightly larger share mainly in textiles at the start of the 1990s and has reached an impressive 4.70% of global market share in all manufactured exports.

  Analysing manufacture exports as a whole, it appears that China's share of global trade has not come at the expense of the rest of the region. Aside from Hong Kong which is somewhat unique given its new status as part of China, the rest of Asia's overall exports of manufactures grew rapidly during the 1990s. When individual sectors are examined, it becomes more evident that the mature Tigers are experiencing shifts in their export capacities that will cause them to begin to recede in some industries and gain in others. For the newly industrialising Tigers, their strong growth in nearly every sector reflects their comparative advantage as lower cost producers of manufactures in contrast to the mature Tigers which are characterised by rising real wages and related increases in operating costs and real estate, to name a few factors.

  The mature Asian economies exhibit shifting patterns of comparative advantage that would be expected with economic development. The might of China, though, has played a role in the resulting pattern of trade. In contrast, the new Tigers of Malaysia, Indonesia, Thailand and the Philippines have had rapid and impressive export growth over the past decade. For these countries, there appear not to be large effects from China's manufacturing strengths. As the old Tigers are increasingly characterised by rising labour, land and capital and costs which normally accompany economic development, the new Tigers appear more attractive as centres of production with their lower wages and operational costs. The shift from the older to the newly industrialising nations is most apparent in the Philippines and Malaysia. They are producing less or the same amount of resource based manufactures, but more high tech goods. In fact, the global market share of Malaysia's high tech exports was 3.75% in 2000, a share which is not much less than the current shares of the old Tigers. Similarly for Thailand and Indonesia, they have both had rapid growth in all export sectors, ranging from resource based to low/medium/high technology products. Indonesia, in particular, witnessed tremendous growth of exports of high tech goods starting from a base of having only 0.05% of the global market share in 1990 to achieving 0.54% by 2000. The evidence since the 1990s suggests that China's strength in producing low technology goods such as clothing and textiles may have facilitated the shift in comparative advantage of the new Tigers into high and medium technology goods. South Korea has even increased its production of resource based goods, perhaps on account of the slower growth of its low tech exports as well.

  Therefore, the evidence indicates that China's growth of manufactured exports has not inflicted the widely perceived harmful effects on its neighbours. The old Tigers have matured and experienced structural changes in their economies normally associated with development. This scenario is mirrored in the position of the new Tigers. Despite China's impressive gains in all export sectors, the global market shares of its neighbours have mostly grown as well. The evidence of both complementarities and specialisation predicted by trade theory is best seen in the remarkable gains in global market share of the newly industrialising Asian countries. The gains of Indonesia in market shares of low tech goods exceeds that of China over the period 1990-2000, and all four new Tigers experienced substantial surges in manufactured exports in medium and high technology goods. These complementarities derive not only from the usual prescriptions of trade theory, but also from the behaviour of multinational corporations and foreign investment.

  When economies of scale and global production chains are considered, the needs of risk diversification and utilisation of national capacities would predict rising intra-industry trade among the Asian nations. There is indeed evidence of increasing economic integration in the region, including movement to formalise ties between China and ASEAN. With growing intra-regional trade and investment, China and its neighbours should begin to converge in technology and level of skills. It follows that intra-industry trade will increase in importance. In fact, China's own efforts at developing the high tech sector through attracting foreign investment have been successful thus far. Starting from a position of possessing minimal global market share, China's exports of high tech goods now rival the volume of the old Tigers while efforts continue to promote the development of high technology centres such as the Pudong area near Shanghai. Looking ahead, the division of production among Asian nations will likely be increasingly characterised by intra-industry trade.

Intra-industry trade as a percentage of total trade growth averaged over five years
1986-901991-95 1996-2000
East Asia42.5%46.9% 75.0%
South Asia31.2%21.8% 34.5%


  Source:   IMF.

  There is already evidence of this trend. Intra-industry has grown significantly over the past decade, particularly in the second half of the 1990s. Intra-industry trade accounts for three-quarters of total trade growth from 1996-2000 in East Asia, rising rapidly from under 50% in the previous decade. South Asia has seen rises as well in the degree of intra-industry trade. The prominence of multinational corporations plays a significant role in generating such trade as do existing large companies such as those constituting chaebols or conglomerates in South Korea.

  Indeed, multinational corporations are important players in the export sectors of Asia's developing nations. An estimated 50% of China's manufactured exports have been produced by foreign invested firms since the mid 1990s. Granting tax and other concessions aimed at encouraging foreign investment characterises the general growth strategy of industrialising Asian nations. Taiwan, Hong Kong and even new Tigers like Malaysia have focused on attracting foreign investment in their export sectors.

  In short, China's rise has not generated a decline in the rest of Asia. Instead, China should prove to be a strong centre for attracting FDI and multinational production facilities that could have positive spillover effects for its neighbours. The development of cross-border supply chains and the trade deficit that China runs with its Asian neighbours are testament to this trend.

III.  ECONOMIC IMPACT OF CHINA ON THE GLOBAL ECONOMY

  An area where China as well as other developing countries have contributed to the global economy is in terms of producing cheap manufactured goods which have lowered prices worldwide. The low inflation, low interest rate environment in many developed countries, particularly in the UK and Europe which are relatively open economies, is at least partly attributable to the low level of world prices and correspondingly cheaper imports.

  The earlier discussion covered some of the effects of China on international trade. The evidence since WTO accession in 2001 suggests an additional phenomenon. Due to the lifting of import restrictions, imports in China have exceeded the growth of exports in the past few years. Although China had a stronger than expected trade surplus in 2005 of $101.9 billion, there is evidence that imports and their effects on domestic consumption are an increasing important policy focus. After decades of central planning which restricted private consumption, consumption levels are low in China. Consumption accounts for less than 50% of GDP, which is considerably less than the 2/3rd of GDP in developed economies. The change in economic policy focus is geared toward increasing aggregate consumption and reducing the focus on investment. China's growth in imports has already been felt in the market for food where China became a net importer and also in global raw materials and commodities markets.

  China's impact on these global markets (eg, oil, copper, iron ore, aluminium, steel) is considerable, and though some of the demand is driven by exports, the bulk is attributed to China's continuing industrialisation. Due to the period of central planning, China is industrialised to a large extent including in heavy industries. However, the reforms of the past 27 years have been geared at attempting to change the type of industrialisation in China toward more high tech and consumer goods, including real estate and housing. The transformation of an already industrialised economy is a difficult task and depends on interest rates which have only been recently liberalised in China. In terms of global markets, China's growth process starting from a low level of GDP per capita and continuing urbanisation suggests that it will likely continue to affect world markets in raw materials and commodities for some time.

  China has also a saving rate which is 50% of GDP, and its trade surplus accounts for about 8% of GDP. The corresponding accumulation of foreign exchange reserves of more than $800 billion underscores the anxiety surrounding China's role in an unbalanced global economy. Moreover, China's attractiveness to FDI continues, as seen in the rise to 60% of the share of exports from China produced by foreign invested enterprises last year and in the high profile investments in the banking sector in anticipation of the opening of its banking sector at the end of 2006 due to the terms of its WTO accession.

  In addition, the exchange rate regime in China was reformed in July 2005, but it continues to be a source of contention. The move to increase the flexibility of the exchange rate resulted in a depegging of the RMB from the US dollar and instead the Chinese currency became linked to a trade-weighted basket of currencies. Although the precise contents are not known, the US dollar is understood to comprise of less than 50% of the basket. With China's considerable trade surplus with the United States, this issue is likely to continue to plague the global economy. The recent moves in China to reform financial markets to ensure domestic stability before further liberalisation takes place will be closely watched.

  The other major area of China's impact on the global economy is attributed to the "going out" policy of its enterprises. Since the mid 1990s, China has permitted outward FDI. The amount of FDI was small relative to the inflow of FDI, totalling just $2 billion before 2004. Since WTO accession, China has increased the amount of overseas investment in both commercial and also strategic sectors. For instance, TCL's deal with Thomson in 2003 and Lenovo's purchase of IBM's PC business in 2004 are examples of China's "national champion" policy going global. China has also actively promoted investment in oil and natural gas reserves in countries ranging from Nigeria to shares in Canadian-listed PetroKazakhstan as well as a high profile failed bid for US company, UNOCAL. Although China's energy use is predominantly derived from coal, its requirements for energy will double by 2020 and security of supply is considered to be important to safeguard growth. This has caused tensions in the global economy not just due to China's relationship with states such as Sudan, but also the resultant competition with India and Japan. The relationship with Japan is also intertwined with historical political tensions, despite the booming economic relationship where Japan increasingly relies on China as a market for its exports which have fuelled its growth in recent years.

  Finally, although there are numerous issues, this section will conclude with a discussion about China's impact on the global economic cycle. China's disproportionate impact on global incremental growth was mentioned earlier. Another facet is the correlation between China's economic cycles and the global economic cycle. During the reform period, China's economic cycles ranged from peak GDP growth exceeding 14% to lows of 4%. However, these cycles were not driven by market economy forces such as those seen in real business cycles, but by the features of a planned economy that included soft budget constraints and decentralisation. In addition, until 2004, China's largest trading partner was Japan, and its economy was more closely aligned with the Asian region than the west, as was seen in the Asian financial crisis in the late 1990s. China's economy was thus somewhat counter-cyclical to the global slowdown at the start of the 2000s. However, since WTO accession and continued reforms, China's institutional structure has become increasingly marketised and the combination of state and market makes its cycles more complex. As of 2004, the European Union became China's largest trading partner followed by the US and Japan. Growing trade with the EU and US further suggests that economic cycles could become more closely aligned among these economies. Coupled with the growing view that the U.S. and China are the twin engines of growth in the global economy, these changes imply that a slowdown in China could well be aligned with a global slowdown.

IV.  ECONOMIC IMPACT OF CHINA ON THE UK AND EU

  Despite the growing amount of trade, there remain numerous issues which affect the relationship between China and EU. These can be divided into direct competition in manufactured goods, and access to Chinese markets. For instance, there have been high profile conflicts between Chinese and European manufacturers in traded goods such as shoes. This competition raises concerns about manufacturing jobs in some developed economies in Europe. This issue is further complicated by the new accession states and the supply chains which are causing some firms to relocate facilities to Eastern Europe. The impact on jobs will depend on employment structures, the needs of consumer markets, and productivity, among others. There are also ongoing issues concerning intellectual property rights and transparency of laws in China, as well as the pace of its liberalisation of domestic markets. However, given the diverse structure of the European Union, particularly with the new accession states, the scope for trade with China is considerable. Europe's pattern of trade is likely to continue to shift toward the east since China is already the second largest trading partner of the European Union and accounts for 40% of Germany's trade position, which is expanding at 20% per annum.

  In addition to the notable trade relationship between China and the EU, China's trade with the UK is also growing. The UK runs a trade deficit with China in the region of £8 billion. However, it also has a trade surplus with China in the export of services of around £1 billion which is likely to grow as China increases the degree of financial liberalisation in its economy and opens its domestic economy to foreign investment.

  In terms of UK investment in China, there are an estimated 4,000 British firms in China. However, in terms of both overall investment and exports to China, the UK lags behind Germany and also France in some respects. Because of the smaller size of the manufacturing sector in the UK, there perhaps had been less scope for trade than other European countries. With the anticipated opening of China's services sector, including professional services such as law and accountancy, education, banking and financial services, there will be more opportunities for Britain to engage with China. In particular, the internationalisation of Chinese firms means that they will seek advice to operate in foreign markets and stock exchanges. And, China is increasingly keen to improve corporate governance and its regulatory structure, which will draw on international best practice. These are areas in which the UK has considerable expertise.

  Finally, because technological progress and competitiveness are crucial issues in the long-run growth prospects of any economy, the UK should consider China's impact in this area. UK labour productivity has lagged behind the US and some other developed economies for some time. The noted skills deficit in the UK adds further concern to this area. China, by contrast, graduates two million engineers and scientists each year and has begun to invest considerably in research and development (R&D). However, the evidence on productivity growth in China is not necessarily overwhelming as it is a poor, developing country which has grown by mostly extensive growth. Its investment in human capital and R&D, though, suggests that it will eventually begin to improve the productivity element of its competitiveness which would enhance its low cost advantage. There are also concerns about the extent of domestic innovation despite the rapid expansion of high tech goods production in China. It is thought that foreign technology is largely responsible for the rapid upgrading of China's high tech goods, and not domestic innovation. Although China is now the leading exporter of ICT goods globally, having surpassed the US, some sectors of high tech exports are dominated by foreign invested enterprises which produce around 80% of all such goods. In any event, the impact on the UK, and indeed other countries, should be to stimulate investment in human capital and innovation, as international trade and globalisation can enhance the drive for competitiveness.

V.  CONCLUSION AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS

  Just as China's growth did not pre-empt the growth of its Asian neighbours, there is scope for gains from trade for the UK, EU and the rest of the world from China's rise so long as each country focuses on its productivity and contemplates how best to engage international trade to take advantage of the specialisation and exchange which generates gains from trade. Although this is a difficult proposition particularly for developing countries, it is possible and certainly worth focusing on as globalisation progresses.

  A recent Deloitte/YouGov poll found that 79% of 2,704 people identified China as the largest threat to the UK. The non-economic impact of China is also considerable and outside the scope of this submission, but would certainly play a role in these perceptions. The poll perhaps also suggests that there is much to be learned still about China, particularly in the economic arena where the concepts are not always clear and the evidence can be difficult to interpret. Given that China is the world's most populous nation and its fastest growing economy, the question should not be if, but how, to engage this country. On account of the UK's openness, tradition of internationalism, and comparative advantage particularly in the fast growing area of services, I hope that this submission has suggested that China poses challenges but also considerable opportunities.

References

International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook, September 2002.

Lindsey Hilsum, "Re-enter the Dragon: China's new mission in Africa," Review of African Political Economy, July 2005.

Paul Krugman, "Competitiveness: A Dangerous Obsession," Foreign Affairs, 28-44, March/April 1994.

Linda Yueh, "China and Intra-regional Trade: Threat or Opportunity?" Asia and Australasia Regional Overview, Economist Intelligence Unit, October 2003.

Linda Yueh, "China's Competitiveness, Intra-industry and Intra-regional Trade in Asia," in Globalisation and Economic Growth in China, Yang Yao and Linda Yueh, editors, World Scientific Co. Pte. Ltd., forthcoming.

Dr Linda Yueh

Pembroke College, University of Oxford, and

London School of Economics

8 February 2006





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2006
Prepared 13 August 2006