Attachment
PARTIAL REGULATORY IMPACT ASSESSMENT RESTRUCTURING
PROBATION TO REDUCE RE-OFFENDING COST ASSUMPTIONS TECHNICAL NOTE
COSTS AND
BENEFITS
Option 1: Do Nothing
1. Access to alternative providers would
be possible only at the discretion of individual probation boards
which would need to take the decision to contract out services.
Currently some £45 million of probation business is contracted
out. This includes training contracts, provision of some interventions
and the operation of some approved premises. These figures were
extract from the activity costing returns produced by probation
board for the financial year 2005-06.There is no power for the
Secretary of State to compel boards to subcontract or market test
core services. A relatively rapid increase in the rate of contracting
out could see boards increase this, say by up to 50% over five
years. Without direct intervention it was felt that this was a
realistic maximum expansion of contracting out. To deliver more
than £23 million of contracting out would require significant
areas of activity either currently or planned to be undertaken
my core probation staff to be contracted out and it considered
unlikely that Probation Boards would be willing to embark on major
revision of recently agreed staffing strucutures.
2. Assuming efficiency savings within the
range of 3% to 8.5% the estimated annual savings of contracting
out a further £23 million of probation business would be
in the range of £0.5 to £1.7 million per annum. The
basis for modelling assumption within this range is the experience
gained from contracting out within the Prison Service. The upper
estimate of 8.5% annual efficiency was achieved in a number of
large establishments, where there was greater scope for efficiencies.
The 3% was the minimum level of efficiency improvement delivered
through contracting out Prison Service activity (the Prisoner
Escort Custody Service). A high proportion of Prison Service costs
are fixed infrastructure costs with over £450 million of
resource cost being required for the maintenance and capital charges
on the estate alone. The probation service has proportionately
higher levels of staff related costs and the scope for medium
term efficiencies is therefore at least comparable and probably
far higher that in the Prison Service where the nature of the
estate imposes severe constraints on restructuring.
3. The minimum cost of contracting out this
level of business is estimated at £20k per board, a total
of £840k. This figure was estimated to the full costs of
one member of staff for four months writing tender specifications,
reviewing bids and letting contracts. The minimum cost of managing
these contracts is estimated at 0.9% of contract value. This is
based on the average contract management costs on the major contracts
(including Prisoner Escort and Custody Service and the various
electronic monitoring contracts) already let within the NOMS area
and includes the staff costs and associated overheads of the directly
employed contract management staff, Discounted over 25 years at
3.5% to allow for costs inflation, this option would have a positive
net present value (ie net savings) of £22 million at 2005-06
prices. The costs and benefits are summarised in Table 1 below.
The DCF rates are the standard Treasury rates for analysis. The
undiscounted cash figures are attached at Appendix 1.
Table 1
OPTION 1 DISCOUNTED CASH FLOW (DCF) ANALYSIS
|
Costs £M | 2005-06
| 2006-07 | 2007-08
| 2008-09 | 2009-10
| 2010-11 | 2011-12
| 2012-13 | 2013-14
|
|
Tendering Costs |
| 0.10 | 0.19
| 0.49 |
| |
| |
|
Contract Management Costs |
| | 0.02
| 0.06 | 0.18
| 0.17 | 0.16
| 0.16 | 0.15
|
Released resources @8.5% |
| | 0.21
| 0.61 | 1.66
| 1.60 | 1.54
| 1.49 | 1.44
|
NET DCF resources released |
| -0.1 | 0.0
| 0.1 | 1.5
| 1.4 | 1.4
| 1.3 | 1.3
|
|
|
Costs £M | 2014-15
| 2015-16 | 2016-17
| 2017-18 | 2018-19
| 2019-20 | 2020-21
| 2021-22 | 2022-23
|
|
Tendering Costs |
| |
| |
| |
| |
|
Contract Management Costs | 0.15
| 0.14 | 0.14
| 0.13 | 0.13
| 0.12 | 0.12
| 0.11 | 0.11
|
Released resources @8.5% | 1.39
| 1.34 | 1.29
| 1.25 | 1.20
| 1.16 | 1.12
| 1.08 | 1.04
|
NET DCF resources released | 1.2
| 1.2 | 1.2
| 1.1 | 1.1
| 1.0 | 1.0
| 1.0 | 0.9
|
|
|
Costs £M | 2023-24
| 2024-25 | 2025-26
| 2026-27 | 2027-28
| 2028-29 | 2029-30
| TOTAL |
|
Tendering Costs |
| |
| |
| |
| 0.77 |
Contract Management Costs | 0.11
| 0.10 | 0.10
| 0.10 | 0.09
| 0.09 | 0.09
| 2.73 |
Released resources @8.5% | 1.01
| 0.97 | 0.94
| 0.91 | 0.87
| 0.84 | 0.81
| 25.79 |
NET DCF resources released | 0.9
| 0.9 | 0.8
| 0.8 | 0.8
| 0.8 | 0.7
| 22.3 |
|
Notes
1. Assumes £23 million of newly contracted business,
of which 12% is contracted in year 1, 24% in year 2, 64% in year
3 and the balance in year 4.
2. Contract management costs of 0.9% of contract value.
3. Assumes savings occurs in the year following tendering.
Option 2: Transfer the statutory responsibility for provision
of probation services from boards to the Secretary of State.
4. Benefits are expected to arise as follows:
to help NOMS achieve its aim of reducing reoffending,
by getting more out of existing resources and freeing up resources
to reinvest, by enabling ROMs as commissioners to insist (in service
specifications) on common approaches and seamless delivery across
prisons and probation institutional boundaries, and by allowing
providers with new and better ways of doing things, including
synergies with their existing operations, to provide services.
5. Some of these benefits can be evidenced from the example
of competition for the operation of prisons over the past decade.
Some benefits can be costed, others cannot.
REDUCTION IN
REOFFENDING
6. Together with the introduction of offender management
within NOMS, the creation of a purchaser provider model and the
introduction of increased competitive forces in to the market
for the provision of correctional service is a core enabling measure
designed to deliver an additional reduction in crime through a
further 5% reduction in reoffending, which is estimated to deliver
wider social and economic benefits amounting to £625 million
over the period 2005-062008-09. This figure was taken from
the Home Office's internal Research and Development Services estimate
of the benefits of crime reduction and was used as the basis for
the SR 2004 spending review negotiations with the Treasury.
PERFORMANCE ENHANCEMENTS
7. In addition to the tangible and costed benefits from
contestability, there is widespread acceptance that introduction
of competition for custodial services has had a positive impact
on the decency agenda which aims to treat offenders with decency
in a caring and secure environment. This helps develop positive
relationships with prisoners and increase the probability that
they will be more likely to go on to live useful and law-abiding
lives that will benefit them as individuals and society as a whole.
8. There is also evidence that competition has helped
provide the impetus for improved performance in prisons across
a wide spectrum of measures. Prisons are rated on a 1 to 4 performance
scale on the basis of a weighted scorecard of measures: level
4 is awarded to excellent establishments that are delivering exceptionally
high performance and level 1 indicates a poor performer. Currently
18% of contracted prisons are rated at performance level 4, compared
to 15% of public sector prisons.[1]
DELIVERING FINANCIAL
EFFICIENCY IN
A COMPETITIVE
MARKET: EVIDENCE
FROM CUSTODIAL
SECTOR
9. The custodial Sector Provides the Following Examples
of Delivering Financial Efficiencies in a Competitive Market:
a number of prisons have been market tested. As
a consequence of this the annual cost of providing those prisons
has reduced from £82 million to £75 million, a saving
of 8.5%;
the outsourcing of the Prisoner Escort Service
has delivered savings of £3.8 million per annum, equivalent
to 3% of the cost of providing the service;
a small number of prisons have been privately
built and are privately managed. The estimated savings are £15.9
million equivalent to about 6% on a base of about £250 million;
performance testing of prisons has generated savings
of £2.8 million, equivalent to 3% on those prisons where
performance testing has been carried out; and
this evidence from the Prison Service suggests
that further market testing of services within the National Probation
Service could deliver savings within the range of 3% to 8.5%.
10. Estimates of the net present value of the benefits
fall within the range of £220 million-£571 million over
25 years years as set out in Tables 2 and 3 below:
Table 2
OPTION 2 STANDARD ESTIMATE (USING DISCOUNTED CASH FLOWS)
|
Costs £M | 2005-06
| 2006-07 | 2007-08
| 2008-09 | 2009-10
| 2010-11 | 2011-12
| 2012-13 | 2013-14
|
|
Central Market Testing costs |
| 0.4 | 1.1
| 1.6 | 1.4
| 1.3 | 1.2
| 1.1 | 1.0
|
In House Bid costs |
| 0.3 | 0.9
| 1.4 | 1.3
| 1.1 | 1.0
| 0.9 | 0.9
|
In House Contract Compliance Costs |
| | 0.0
| 0.2 | 0.4
| 0.6 | 0.8
| 0.9 | 1.1
|
Contract Management Costs |
| | 0.3
| 1.3 | 2.8
| 4.2 | 5.5
| 6.6 | 7.7
|
Released Resources |
| | 21.0
| 26.8 | 32.0
| 32.7 | 34.1
| 35.3 | 36.5
|
NET DCF resources released |
| 0.7 | 18.6
| 22.4 | 26.1
| 25.5 | 25.7
| 25.8 | 25.8
|
|
|
Costs £M | 2014-15
| 2015-16 | 2016-17
| 2017-18 | 2018-19
| 2019-20 | 2020-21
| 2021-22 | 2022-23
|
|
Central Market Testing costs | 0.9
| 0.5 |
| |
| |
| |
|
In House Bid costs | 0.8
| 0.4 |
| |
| |
| |
|
In House Contract Compliance Costs | 1.2
| 1.4 | 1.4
| 1.4 | 1.3
| 1.3 | 1.2
| 1.2 | 1.1
|
Contract Management Costs | 8.8
| 9.7 | 10.1
| 9.7 | 9.4
| 9.1 | 8.7
| 8.4 | 8.1
|
Released Resources | 37.5
| 38.3 | 39.6
| 40.7 | 40.1
| 38.7 | 37.4
| 36.1 | 34.8
|
NET DCF resources released | 25.8
| 26.4 | 28.1
| 29.6 | 29.4
| 28.4 | 27.4
| 26.4 | 25.5
|
|
|
Costs £M | 2023-24
| 2024-25 | 2025-26
| 2026-27 | 2027-28
| 2028-29 | 2029-30
| TOTAL |
|
Central Market Testing costs |
| |
| |
| |
| 10.4 |
In House Bid costs |
| |
| |
| |
| 9.1 |
In House Contract Compliance Costs | 1.1
| 1.1 | 1.0
| 1.0 | 1.0
| 0.9 | 0.9
| 22.5 |
Contract Management Costs | 7.9
| 7.6 | 7.3
| 7.1 | 6.8
| 6.6 | 6.3
| 160.0 |
Released Resources | 33.6
| 32.4 | 31.3
| 30.2 | 29.1
| 28.1 | 27.1
| 773.2 |
NET DCF resources released | 24.6
| 23.7 | 22.9
| 22.1 | 21.3
| 20.6 | 19.9
| 571.2 |
|
Table 3
OPTION 2 LOW ESTIMATE (USING DISCOUNTED CASH FLOWS)
|
Costs £M | 2005-06
| 2006-07 | 2007-08
| 2008-09 | 2009-10
| 2010-11 | 2011-12
| 2012-13 | 2013-14
|
|
Central Market Testing costs |
| 0.5 | 1.3
| 2.0 | 1.8
| 1.6 | 1.5
| 1.3 | 1.2
|
In House Bid costs |
| 0.3 | 0.9
| 1.4 | 1.3
| 1.1 | 1.0
| 0.9 | 0.9
|
In House Contract Compliance Costs |
| | 0.0
| 0.2 | 0.4
| 0.6 | 0.8
| 0.9 | 1.1
|
Contract Management Costs |
| | 0.4
| 1.7 | 3.7
| 5.5 | 7.3
| 8.9 | 10.3
|
Released Resources |
| | 21.0
| 20.4 | 20.3
| 20.8 | 21.5
| 22.1 | 22.7
|
NET DCF resources released |
| 0.8 | 18.2
| 15.1 | 13.1
| 11.9 | 10.9
| 10.0 | 9.2
|
|
|
Costs £M | 2014-15
| 2015-16 | 2016-17
| 2017-18 | 2018-19
| 2019-20 | 2020-21
| 2021-22 | 2022-23
|
|
Central Market Testing costs | 1.1
| 0.6 |
| |
| |
| |
|
In House Bid costs | 0.8
| 0.4 |
| |
| |
| |
|
In House Contract Compliance Costs | 1.2
| 1.4 | 1.4
| 1.4 | 1.3
| 1.3 | 1.2
| 1.2 | 1.1
|
Contract Management Costs | 11.7
| 12.9 | 13.4
| 13.0 | 12.5
| 12.1 | 11.7
| 11.3 | 10.9
|
Released Resources | 23.2
| 23.6 | 24.0
| 24.1 | 23.6
| 22.8 | 22.0
| 21.2 | 20.5
|
NET DCF resources released | 8.4
| 8.3 | 9.2
| 9.8 | 9.8
| 9.4 | 9.1
| 8.8 | 8.5
|
|
|
Costs £M | 2023-24
| 2024-25 | 2025-26
| 2026-27 | 2027-28
| 2028-29 | 2029-30
| TOTAL |
|
Central Market Testing costs |
| |
| |
| |
| 13.0 |
In House Bid costs |
| |
| |
| |
| 9.1 |
In House Contract Compliance Costs | 1.1
| 1.1 | 1.0
| 1.0 | 1.0
| 0.9 | 0.9
| 22.5 |
Contract Management Costs | 10.5
| 10.1 | 9.8
| 9.4 | 9.1
| 8.8 | 8.5
| 213.3 |
Released Resources | 19.7
| 19.1 | 18.4
| 17.7 | 17.1
| 16.5 | 15.9
| 478.2 |
NET DCF resources released | 8.2
| 7.9 | 7.6
| 7.3 | 7.1
| 6.8 | 6.6
| 220.3 |
|
11. The assumptions that have been made in modelling
the costs and benefits are explained in the following paragraphs.
RELEASED RESOURCES
12. In the standard estimate it is assumed that work
that has been subject to a formal market test process will generate
efficiencies equivalent to 3% of the value of the work tested
within the first year after testing, rising to 6% in the second
year and to a maximum of 8.5% after three years. In the low estimate
the figures are 3%, 4% and 5% respectively. The rational for the
rising profile is that structural constraints within the organisation,
particular staffing levels, make it difficult to drive out short
term efficiencies without incurring disproportionate costs in
restructuring.
13. It is further assumed that the introduction of a
formal market testing programme will have a significant "ripple"
effect across the full supplier base as providers seek to improve
performance and become better placed to thrive in a competitive
marketplace ahead of further market tests. These benefits are
modelled at 3% in the first year of the programme, rising to 4%
in the second year and to a maximum of 5% by the third year. In
the low estimate the figure is a 3% effect.
14. A key assumption is that the process of market testing
will deliver efficiencies from suppliers, irrespective of whether
the process results in a change of supplier. As part of the testing
process, it is envisaged that existing providers will be expected
to produce bids that offer better value for money that the existing
provision.
15. Although expressed as financial savings for modelling
purposes, the expectation is that the benefits will be delivered
through a combination of undertaking additional work with offenders
within the same level of financial resources. It is further assumed
that the process will create additional capacity to generate innovative
solutions to address re-offending which will be at least as, and
probably more, effective in addressing the rehabilitation needs
of offenders and thus deliver a greater impact on reducing re-offending
and hence crime.
SPEED OF
ROLLOUT
16. The pace of the market testing programme has not
been finalised but the modelling here assumes that total probation
expenditure will be tested over a 10 year period. There is a practical
constraint in the volume of business that can be contested at
any one time. This is estimated at around 12% of the value of
probation business in any one year. This is the equivalent of
the work of five entire probations areas. This has led to the
illustrative pace of the market testing programme which is set
out in Table 4 below:
Table 4
|
Year | 1
| 2 | 3
| 4 | 5
| 6 | 7
| 8 | 9
| 10 |
|
Value of Business market tested | 2%
| 1% | 21%
| 33% | 45%
| 57% | 69%
| 81% | 93%
| 100% |
|
CENTRAL COSTS
OF MARKET
TESTING REGIMES
Evidence from the custodial sector
17. The evidence from the custodial sector is as follows:
Design, Construct and Manage (DCM) Prisons:
The prisons at Peterborough and Bronzefield have recently
opened and are DCM Prisons, designed, constructed and managed
by the private sector. The estimated cost of running the competition
for these prisons is estimated at £2 million, equivalent
to £1 million a prison. It is now estimated that further
DCM Prisons might cost £1.1 million to procure. These costs
are made up as follows (and could be reduced in the event of there
being more DCM prisons):
£120KFinancial advisors
£220KCompliance Engineers
Market Testing Prisons where an individual
prison is marked tested and put out to competition with the private
sector. This is estimated to cost about £700K per prison
as follows:
£70KFinancial advisors
£300KCompliance Engineers (condition
surveys)
Performance Testing Prisons where a prison is
required considerably to improve its performance or be subject
to market testing/competition. It is estimated that performance
testing a prison costs £350K. This is £100K for the
staff in the Competitions Unit within NOMS and £250K for
the in-house bid team within the Prison Service.
Inferences for Probation Market/Performance Testing
18. The average prison has a budget of about £12
million. This figure is on a par with the average budget for individual
probation areas (excluding London). It is estimated that market
testing a whole probation area might cost broadly the equivalent
to the cost of market testing a prison. Until the market testing
approach is agreed, this is the simplest approach to estimating
probation market testing costs. If that assumption is valid then
the cost would be in the region of £700K. However, it is
questionable whether it would be necessary to spend £300K
on building condition surveys. All probation buildings have regularly
been subjected to condition surveys so this expenditure might
not be required, reducing the cost to £400K. It is assumed
that a learning curve effect would reduce this to £230K by
the end of the testing cycle. Using this benchmark the maximum
costs of market testing all 42 probation areas is therefore of
the order of £12.5 million. In the low estimate at Table
3 market testing costs are modelled at an initial £500K,
again reducing through the learning curve effect to £290K
by the end of the cycle.
IN HOUSE
BID COSTS
19. There are costs for the supplier in preparing bids.
It is estimated that performance testing a prison costs £350K.
This is £100K for the staff in the Competitions Unit within
NOMS and £250K for the in-house bid team within the Prison
Service. It is assumed that a learning curve effect would reduce
this to £200K by the end of the testing cycle. Using this
as a benchmark, the cost of in-house bid preparation for contracts
to the value of expenditure currently committed to the 42 probation
areas would total £9.1 million.
IN HOUSE
CONTRACT COMPLIANCE
COSTS
20. In addition to the existing reporting requirements,
it is estimated that the additional costs associated with the
move to a contractual relationship are likely to be of the order
of £50K per annum per probation area. These are primarily
legal costs associated with contract compliance and would be additional
to existing financial and performance reporting requirements.
CONTRACT MANAGEMENT
COSTS
21. The average annual costs of future probation contract
management is estimated at 0.9% of contract value. This assumption
is based on evidence of the contracted management costs of the
current contracted out prisons, the electronic monitoring contracts
and the PECS contracts. These contracts are larger than those
anticipated for probation and consequently contract management
represents a smaller percentage than assumed above for probation
services contracts. The option was modelled with contract management
costs of 1.2% and still returned a substantial positive net present
value of £220 million (Table 3).
SUMMARY COSTS
AND BENEFITS
Table 4
|
Option | Total Benefit Per Annum: Economic, Environmental, Social
| Total Cost Per Annum: -Economic, Environmental, Social -Policy and Administrative
|
| £M
| £M |
|
1 | 1.7 |
0.2 |
2 | 64.0 |
17.0 |
|
(These figures are full costs at 2005-06 prices)
1
Source: Prison Service Performance Ratings August 2005. Back
|