Select Committee on International Development Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 140 - 159)

TUESDAY 6 DECEMBER 2005

MR ROGER LIDDLE


  Q140  Hugh Bayley: One of the areas where the EU appears to be the most vulnerable in its offer is in relation to "sensitive products", where I think you are proposing that 8% of tariff lines could be so designated. The World Bank told us in Washington DC a couple of weeks ago that if only 2% of products were so designated, 90% of everything that the rich world wanted to protect would be protected. Really there must be some change there. Will there be a numerical limit on the number of products that the EU Member States, or any states, could designate as especially sensitive? Will there be a requirement for some tariff cuts, if not the steep tariff cuts, for such especially sensitive products?

  Mr Liddle: I recognise on the face of it the naming of 8% of agricultural tariff lines of sensitive products looks as though the EU is basically offering something with one hand and trying to take it away with the other. I think Peter believes that the Commission has to better explain what it has in mind when it talks about sensitive products and, of course, the whole package is for negotiation at the end of the day. The point that you raise that is crucial is that I think a lot of people think when we say 8% sensitive products, that means that we will maintain the present levels of protection that we have on those 8% sensitive products. That is not the case. We are not going to maintain the present levels of protection. For each of these tariff lines we would negotiate a Tariff Rate Quota, a TRQ. That means that there would be a tariff applied to these sensitive products. It would be a lower tariff than presently applied but a higher tariff than it would be under the general formula. A quota would be fixed for how much could come in at that special tariff. This is all to be negotiated, line by line, once you have got general agreement on the tariff structures. I would emphasise that these are matters for negotiation, so there is quite a lot of give and take in future in this area that would be likely.

  Chairman: That is a good introduction to John Battle's question.

  Q141  John Battle: I think in the context of the general conversation and lowering expectations, if you are going to get to it line by line it is going to take some time even if you get an agreed tariff structure. This is going to take a long time. One of our witnesses suggested that Hong Kong was a rushed event because the preparation had not really taken place, in effect there had not been enough focus and consensus building around key proposals and, therefore, we could not expect too much to come out of the Round. At Cancún the Commission was criticised for playing a game of last minute brinkmanship right up to the edge of the final days in the WTO negotiations. I wonder whether in the present context there is a calming down and a longer look now not to expect too much in Hong Kong but to set some frameworks that will be running, or do you expect some rabbits to be drawn out of hats in Hong Kong? As an adjunct to that, how does the Commission avoid the Americans blaming Europe if things do not work out productively?

  Mr Liddle: That is a very interesting set of questions. The EU has been at the front foot of these negotiations, in my view, throughout. After all, it was the EU in July 2004 when Pascal Lamy was still there that made the offer conditionally to phase out export subsidies. That was an important move which got no reciprocation whatsoever for a long time from the other rich countries of the world. As I say, there was a pause because of the change of Commission and the change of US trade representative. From the start, Peter always recognised that we had to make progress on agriculture. This was a very difficult subject for Europe because we know all the different political pressures within Europe on the Common Agricultural Policy but we had to make progress on agriculture. We agreed the conversion of ad valorem tariffs in May, we reached a compromise tariff structure in China in July, and we were waiting all the time for the United States to make a comparable move to ours that had been made in July 2004. We had to wait quite a long time for that, partly because the whole focus of the administration was on getting the controversial CAFTA[5] bilateral trade deal through Congress rather than on the Doha Round. Then the Americans did turn to Doha and they made an offer on agriculture which surprised a lot of people by the boldness of its details, it was certainly a public relations triumph. We deliberately decided not to blow that offer out of the water. We could have done because it contained elements that were very unspecified, for example, although they are saying they are going to cut overall domestic support for agriculture they are not saying how, and there is no commitment to remove the price related supports for agriculture which are a key feature of the American agriculture farm system, in particular something called Counter Cyclical Payments. There is no commitment to do that. It is very, very difficult to see how in practice you could contain your agriculture subsidies within a limit if at the same time you do not support the regimes which effectively imply open-ended public spending commitments, which is the case with the Counter Cyclical Payments. We could have made an awful lot of that but we did not because we wanted to get the negotiations going. We made a counter-offer on agriculture. You know all about how difficult it was to get the EU25 into a position where that was agreed, but we managed to do that. We managed to rally support for that in the Council of Ministers, and that was good. What we were hoping was when we had made our countervailing agriculture offer on tariffs then the Americans on the one side and the Brazilians on the other would get into a serious negotiation with us, but instead what happened was they said, "Oh, this is just completely unacceptable. We are not prepared to talk about this at all" and it created exactly the wrong reaction in Europe, as far as Peter was concerned, to the one that we needed because the consensus in the Commission and the Council of Ministers was, "If they are going to behave like that and say Europe is not offering anything significant when we actually think Europe has offered something really significant, we are not going to do anything more until these other people realise we have got to get into a serious negotiation here". It hardened the position in Europe and the reaction in the rest of the world. I think that Europe's position on this agriculture offer is pretty strong. The maximum tariff cut of 60% is much bolder than anything we have done before. It is also the case—this is a point that the competitive agricultural producers, both the rich countries like America and Australia but also the Brazilians, will not accept—if you cut agricultural tariffs too radically, too fast, then some of the biggest losers will be the very poorest countries who get access to our markets through preference schemes because you will be cutting back the preference that they have. They just will not accept the validity of this argument but I think it is one that we have got to make very, very strongly at Hong Kong.


  Q142  Richard Burden: Could we just go back to the description you were giving a little earlier on in answer to Hugh about the two stage process of an agreement and a framework but then moving on to more detailed line by line negotiations, whether it be on special and differential treatment on one side of the equation or sensitive products on the other. Just thinking in terms of the collective psychology of Hong Kong and the process, that could sound very easily to developing countries like you are asking them to write a bit of a blank cheque in practical terms. There is a promise there, but what is behind the promise? Would you recognise that would be a likely fear and, if so, how could you allay that fear? What could you build in to show that was not just asking them to write a blank cheque?

  Mr Liddle: I think that is a very real concern and certainly the Indian Trade Minister, Kamal Nath, does say, "I cannot agree any figures on tariffs until I know how my sensitive products are going to be dealt with". That is an understandable point of view. I think the only way you can proceed on this is on the principle that nothing is agreed until everything is agreed. I think you have got to agree the main outlines of your tariff structures and their cuts first and then address how you deal with all the exceptions and the timescales and the sensitivities and all the rest. I do not see how you could deal with the sensitivities first without having at least some provisional view of what the actual percentage cuts for the generality would be. Logically, I think you have to do the percentages first and then the exceptions. I do think that is an issue and perhaps what we need to do more is try and establish the trust that we are not going to promise lots of sensitivities and then in the detailed line by line negotiation after the tariff cuts have been agreed refuse to deliver on that promise. I think we have got to try hard to establish that trust.

  Q143  Mr Singh: Roger, before I ask my intended question, I would just like to reflect on this grand bargain a little bit where the rich want access for goods and the advanced developing countries will get greater agricultural access to rich markets. In a case like India, which presumably is an advanced developing country now, my understanding is they are not a net exporter of food apart from rice, so what incentive is there for them in this grand bargain?

  Mr Liddle: Again, that is a very good question. India is not an agricultural exporter, you are quite right and, indeed, the Indian Trade Minister is very, very concerned about agricultural tariff cuts that would lead to more food imports into India and very, very concerned about what effect this might have on the stability of the Indian countryside. Although we describe India as an advanced developing country we must always, always remember that there are more poor people in India than in the whole of Africa. We are not stupid about that. Peter is very sympathetic to these arguments of Kamal Nath, with whom he has an excellent relationship, about destabilising the Indian countryside and in practice, of course, that would mean destabilising the political stability and democracy in India, so the stakes are very, very high here. I think we have to recognise that concern. What is in it for India? I think there are two things in it for India. First, further liberalisation of industrial tariffs and services would aid the process of internal reform in India which has led to the tremendous improvement in Indian economic performance that we have seen in the last 10 or 15 years which the present Prime Minister initiated in his earlier days. Secondly, I do think that in the area of services there is quite a strong Indian commercial interest and that has been made pretty clear by Kamal Nath to us in the negotiations. Of course, it is a classic example of where there is a mutual benefit to trade because of the different types of services that Europe and India can offer, as it were, in exchange, and we would be mutually better off as a result of opening our markets on both sides. In the Indian case on services, one of the real sensitivities as far as the Council of Ministers here is concerned is on so-called Mode IV which is basically an immigration issue, as I am sure you know. If you are an Indian company doing a contract in Europe, it is about the rights to bring your workers here. Let us say you are an IT company and you want to bring your IT workers over for a limited period in order to fulfil the contract, that seems to me a perfectly reasonable proposition but it causes all kinds of political sensitivities in some quarters.

  Q144  Mr Singh: Thank you for that. My intended question is about the Green Box. I would be grateful for some clarification as to what the Green Box actually is. What is in the Green Box? What criteria was used to put what is in the Green Box in the Green Box? Will that criteria be changed, or certainly reviewed, at Hong Kong and, if there are any changes, what are they likely to be?

  Mr Liddle: It was a hard learning process when I took on this job working for Peter, I can tell you. Of all the many public policy issues I have dealt with in my 25 years of life as an adviser in politics, I have found trade the most bewildering of all. Let me try and explain this as clearly as I am able to. A lot of people when they look at the Common Agricultural Policy, certainly a lot of British people, say, "Gosh, this is a terrible waste of time, waste of money, what we want to do is scrap agricultural subsidies". That is the sort of instinctive reaction a lot of people have. What the EU is committed to doing is not scrapping agricultural subsidies, it is committed to scrapping trade distorting agricultural subsides, and that is a much more qualified concept. What it enables us to do in Europe is continue to subsidise farmers in order to produce a sustainable countryside so that they can be stewards of the land, but not in a way that offers artificial incentives to production and leads to unfair trading practices, the dumping of subsidised goods on world markets or very high tariff walls in order to protect the fact that we have encouraged over-production in Europe. In the Uruguay commitment, trade distorting subsidies were called the Amber Box and the Green Box was where you had to make your reforms in order to remove the trade distorting element in the subsidies. The 2003 reform did make an awful lot of progress on that. I remember reading various speeches that Margaret Beckett made about it and I think that she did a tremendous job as British DEFRA Secretary of State in the negotiations on that package because what basically happened was for a very, very high proportion of the support that was given to EU farmers the link to production was ended, so farm subsidies are moving over to a system whereby you get the subsidy for your stewardship of the land, not for how much you produce. This is a huge change. I do not know much about farming but I was talking to some people in farming in my home county in Cumberland, and they were saying the impact of this change is that as they get the money already, as it were, they now find that the cost of rearing the animals or growing the seeds or whatever, the cost of the inputs, exceeds what they are going to get on the market for this, which is forcing them to cut back production. The impact of shifting the subsidy regime from one that is related to production to the Single Farm Payment system is to cut back production. Obviously it varies: if you are a very efficient farmer, you have got good land and are very efficient, you will continue to be able to produce and sell at a profitable price, but some people will not be. It is that impact on production which creates the possibility of Europe accepting more imports from the rest of the world because we will be able to do that. The non-trade distorting subsidies are what we call the Green Box. It is absolutely vital for Europe to have this Green Box accepted. We agree that the disciplines within it have to be transparent, they have to be clarified, they have to be tight and it has not got to be a disguised production subsidy, but this is the trend of policy that Europe is presently engaged in. If I may say so, I think too often in Britain you hear the argument calling for scrapping the CAP when, in fact, what we should be talking about is a sustainable agriculture and making sure that subsidies go to that purpose and not to distort trade.

  Chairman: I will happily echo that given that 90% of the land in Scotland is Less Favoured, so a total scrapping would be disastrous. I think it is important to understand that mix.

  Q145  Ann McKechin: I would like to move on to the NAMA side of negotiations, which I know have stalled pretty badly coming up to Hong Kong. I think there is some concern about the EU's suggested formula to deal with this, which is known as the Swiss Formula, which would appear to insist that developing countries are going to have to lower their higher bound tariffs to a greater extent than we are asking them to do for our own. The ACP countries have come up with a Swiss Formula-plus which would seem to provide a greater degree of what is known as "policy space" which the UK Government in turn is saying is something which developing countries should have. Why is the EU so insistent on its current formula?

  Mr Liddle: I hope you will not ask me to explain the Swiss Formula because my maths is not good enough to be able to do so, I have to confess. The argument you are making is made very forcefully by a lot of NGOs, most forcefully, I think, by War on Want in the papers of evidence you have had that I have looked at. We do not agree with it, let us be clear about that. Let me try and explain why. Let us talk about the advanced developing countries rather than the least developing countries. In terms of the advanced developing countries, what we are seeking is genuine increased market access for our industries. That means a lower tariff than those countries presently apply. One of the confusions in all of this is that there is a difference between the tariffs countries apply and their so-called bound tariff. I had not any idea about this at all until I came here a year ago, it was one of the things that one learned, that there is this difference between bound tariffs and applied tariffs. In Brazil's case, for example, the average bound tariff for Brazil is 29.94%—I wrote down these numbers because I think it is a good way of illustrating the point—their applied tariff, however, is only 11.63%. That is on average. There are a lot of variations and some of the tariffs on things like automobiles are quite a lot higher. What Brazil has proposed is basically a formula which says, "We will bring down all our tariffs to the level of our bound tariff, or we will have a formula that compresses all our tariffs down to the level of our bound tariff, around that 30% mark". Brazil has something like 9,000 industrial tariff lines. 2,700 of these are at the bound level over 30%. What the Brazilians are saying is that they would apply a formula which would in effect result in real market access of about 800 of these 9,000 tariff lines, in other words less than 10% of their total industrial goods. That is because all they are doing is cutting the bound rate, not the applied rate. What we are saying is we have got to get a cut in the applied rates, however we accept that the cuts on average the developed world would apply in applied rates would be higher than the cuts we would ask the developing world to apply. Peter has talked in general terms of us making twice as large tariff cuts as developing countries in terms of our applied rates on average. That is the kind of outcome that we are working towards where developing countries, even the advanced ones, in practice are not making as big a tariff cuts as we are but they are making real tariff cuts. Then there is the Least Developed Countries and, as I say, for them we have always been clear that it would be up to them to decide and they can, as it were, have a round for free. I am sorry if that is not as clear as it should be perhaps but it is a very complicated subject.

  Q146  Ann McKechin: That is very helpful. Can I ask one supplementary? I understand that the Swiss Formula is to try to reduce the advanced developing countries' bound tariffs to a median level, the problem is that China actually has relatively low tariffs.

  Mr Liddle: Yes.

  Q147  Ann McKechin: India, which as we were just discussing has more poor people than the whole of Africa, has very high tariffs.

  Mr Liddle: Correct.

  Q148  Ann McKechin: If you try a median level which includes China, it immediately distorts what the median would be. With the greatest respect, I think the position of the Indian economy in terms of manufacturing is much less advanced than that of China. It seems you are applying an across the board one-size-fits-all formula for an advanced developing nation but they are not in the same position in terms of progress in the industrial formula.

  Mr Liddle: They would not be required to end up in the same position, it is a percentage cut from where they are now. As I understand it, the main point that the NGOs make is this point about policy space. In other words, it is not so much that they are worried about the principle of cutting the tariff, what they worry about is if you have brought your bound tariff down you cannot decide at a later stage that you want to increase your tariffs in order to protect your industries, because the kind of War on Want people believe in an infant industry view of industrial development that you have to protect your industry very heavily in the early stages of development. Of course, this view of industrial development is highly contested. I do not know what I think about it, to be quite honest. I think the example of the Asian tiger economies, who are the most successful of countries that lifted themselves out of poverty in the post-war period, probably is that there is some truth in the infant industry argument, that you need protection at the early stages of development. On the other hand, some countries that have tried to build successful industries behind tariff walls have just ended up with very inefficient industries that are never going to be internationally competitive and the impact of the tariff is simply to force their domestic consumers to buy goods at higher prices than they would obtain on the world market if the world market was opened up. I think that was the case with quite a lot of India's industrialisation that was attempted in the Nehru era. As I say, I think it is a highly contested thing as to what view you take of this.

  Q149  Ann McKechin: Would it not be the case that we should have an independent assessment before we start making decisions about it?

  Mr Liddle: Yes, maybe. That is worth thinking about.

  Chairman: The problem, in passing, is that we still justify protecting some of our own industries whilst lecturing developing countries as to the need for them to reduce theirs. I just pass that as a comment.

  Q150  John Barrett: You mentioned in your opening remarks how vitally important services were. You will also be aware of the slow pace of progress in the GATS process of "request and offer". The Commission has been attempting to speed up these negotiations and could be accused of changing the rules with its benchmarking suggestion. I wonder if you could say something about that. Also, could you touch on what you have heard in your discussions with the NGOs and civil society about the whole aspect of services?

  Mr Liddle: The services negotiations were going nowhere and, therefore, the Commission felt that it had to come up with some new ideas. I think there were essentially three new ideas that the Commission came up with which for us at a political level, when we saw these papers, we regarded as perfectly reasonable. One is that you break down services—people talk very generally about services—into sub-sectors. I think there are 163 sub-sectors. You set a numeric target. For the rich developed countries the target we have suggested is you bring forward proposals for liberalisation in 139 of these 163 sectors. For developing countries, excluding the poorest, you bring forward proposals for liberalisation in 93 of the 163 sub-sectors. That allows quite a lot of policy space for people to say, "Oh, I do not want my education or my health sector to be involved in this in any way", or whatever. The second point is the EU has proposed what it calls "qualitative parameters". Let us say, on the rights of service investment that means you should have a measure that says if you are an outside provider are you able to take a majority stake in a company operating in a country or not or do the rules force you to a maximum 49% stake, say. That seems to be pretty important; is an outside service provider able to have a majority stake or not? The third point is that we have proposed in services in the jargon what they call pluralateral negotiations and, as I understand it, that is if you have a group of countries that want to talk about telecoms they can opt in to talking about telecoms and having a special deal on telecoms. It is an opting in proposal, no-one is forced to join in, but if they do it is a deal that applies to the countries that have opted in. My own view, and Peter's own view, is that we are very, very sympathetic to most of the NGO lobby on development, but I must say we find these arguments that the NGOs put forward on services very difficult to comprehend and are not very much in sympathy with them, first of all because we regard services as crucial to development, secondly because of the point that I mentioned that it is not one-way traffic, countries like India are becoming very effective service providers so do not let us look at it as though we are imposing something on them, which is just not true, and, thirdly, I do not have this view of the great majority of European service providers as greedy capitalists out to take advantage of developing countries, which is the kind of image that comes across in quite a lot of these papers that one reads. In fact, rather I think a lot of European companies that we are aware of have very high standards, including high standards of probity and anti-corruption, which in the developing world, in the right circumstances, we think could help the cause of good governance. I must say, I find a lot of these arguments quite difficult to engage with because our instincts are just very different about this, and I have just been honest with you about that.

  Q151  Joan Ruddock: I just want to make the point, Roger, not to defend the NGOs, but perhaps their frustration in that respect is because, as you said at some point, nothing is decided until everything is decided. I think the concern is that what is perceived as the aggression of the EU on services is linked to the fact that if we have to hold out to get a lot on services then we are not going to get to the agricultural needs of the poorest countries, and it is that perhaps as a package that gives rise to concern. Not that one could not justify doing something on services quite separately, but it is the linkage that is the problem.

  Mr Liddle: I understand that. For instance, if you look at what has happened in sugar you can understand ACP anger about it.

  Joan Ruddock: You can

  Mr Liddle: I absolutely understand that, but I do not believe this argument about services, if you are just looking at it on its own merits, rings true with me.

  Q152  Mr Davies: Roger, as the Chairman has already mentioned, we had breakfast this morning with several ACP ambassadors, one from the South Pacific and two from the Caribbean. Can I put to you first of all two of the things that they said to us and a third thing which they did not say to us but which I infer from the position they have taken up. One was that they saw a considerable lack of coherence within the EU between DG Development, DG Agriculture and DG Trade, and that made their lives very difficult and they thought this was bad from the EU's point of view and contrasted unfavourably with the position in Washington. I want to put that to you. The second point they made was they felt pretty badly let down, let down very hard, over bananas and sugar by an organisation, the EU, with whom they had had a very close and symbiotic relationship over the last 30 years. They felt there was no consultation as there should have been and all the rhetoric in Lomé and in Cotonou about co-operation, partnership and equality and so forth was for the birds because they have not been consulted and taken along in this, they have been the victim of unilateral decisions. They said—I thought this was a very telling point if it is correct—that although they had suggested to the Commission that a Joint Impact Assessment be made so it is possible for the Commission and for them to look at what the actual impact will be on their producers and their economies of the measures that you are now imposing on bananas and sugar particularly, you had turned that down and found various excuses and said this will not be done on a bilateral basis, which would be rather a good thing because the whole negotiation has been based on the assumption that we are talking about a regional bloc, the EU, with another regional bloc. They felt pretty badly let down. I would be grateful for your comments on that and what could be done about it. It is a matter of political concern to us, going broader than just trade and the Doha Round, that these countries with whom we have had such a close relationship for a long time should feel that they have been treated that way. Of course, in any negotiation there will be a certain amount of rhetoric about how badly someone has been treated and how the other side ought to address these grievances, but I thought there was a kernel of authenticity to their complaints which I must put to you. The third point is one which I infer, they did not say this. I inferred from our discussions this morning that the EU is forcing them to make these sacrifices and change the regime because the EU needs to make some progress on the Doha Round and they are just the victims who will have to pay the price for that but, irrationally, they would now pay the price even if there is no deal in Hong Kong or later on the Doha Round—they would still have lost their existing preferential regimes on bananas and sugar, and in that case for no purpose at all because it will not be in the interests of the wider trade deal with improvement in world GDP from which they might gain indirectly and over the long term plausibly some benefits. They did not put that point to me but I inferred that from the situation as I understand it.

  Mr Liddle: On your first point about lack of coherence, I think that has certainly been the case in the past. All I would say is strenuous efforts are being made to improve performance in the future. The example of where we are trying very hard is you had your separate inquiry into Economic Partnership Agreements and there it is absolutely crucial that the different arms of the Commission work together. This is something that Peter is very focused on and where he is trying to make an impact. On your second point about the sense of grievance, I am very struck by the sense of grievance as well. In our defence, you have got to remember that in Europe's defence we are facing WTO action in these areas, that we are multilateralists, we believe in sticking to the rules, that the banana and sugar regimes have been subject to challenge through WTO procedures and we have to reform them as a result. The countries that stand to gain from these reforms would equally feel aggrieved if we were not acting to fulfil our legal obligations. That is true. I think the problems that arise for some of the Caribbean countries, Mauritius and other places, are awful. As a Brit, these things go back to the Commonwealth sugar and Commonwealth banana agreements that were done in the Attlee Government where Arthur Creech Jones was colonial secretary. There is a hell of a lot of history involved in this. We are unpicking quite a lot of what were conceived as noble attempts to help parts of what was then the Empire prosper.

  Q153  Mr Davies: Why no joint impact assessment?

  Mr Liddle: I do not know about that, to be quite honest. You have asked me a question and I just do not know what the situation is on that. I think the problem with these countries is that they have not accepted the reality that because of the WTO these arrangements would some day have to come to an end. The focus should have been much more on adjustment assistance and trying to get alternative economic bases for their economies rather than on trying to hang on to what they already have. I do not think we have done that perfectly either, there is a lot of scope for improvement, but, as I said earlier, it is all bound up in the debate about the EU budget and, if the EU budget is going to be very constrained, how much the Member States themselves are prepared to help as well.

  Q154  Mr Davies: Can I ask you to take away the point about the joint impact assessment.

  Mr Liddle: I have registered it very much so.

  Q155  Mr Davies: If you could let us have a note it would be very helpful because I am sure this will come up and we need to know what the position is.

  Mr Liddle: We will do that.[6]

  Chairman: That is very fair because they were quite strong about it.

  Mr Liddle: I will straight away go back.

  Q156  Joan Ruddock: Roger is saying about the obligation that the EU is under in terms of the WTO and I just wondered about the scope that there is to give a much longer period of adjustment. Do we really have to make it as brutal as it seems to be?

  Mr Liddle: All I can say is that this has been going on for a long time. I think the Commission has tried to do its best within the very, very considerable constraints that it faces because of the fact that we are dealing with WTO judgments that we have to meet. I am sorry, but that is the situation.

  Chairman: Do you want to pursue your question about Rules of Origin?

  Q157  Joan Ruddock: Yes, if there is time. One of the things you said in speaking about Aid for Trade was many countries do not have capacity. I think we would have liked to talk a bit about how to increase that capacity. One of the things that are of concern is the EU's Rules of Origin. I wonder what progress, if any, is being made on that.

  Mr Liddle: There are proposals to simplify our Rules of Origin which are working their way through the system now. I think that is in hand. That is the responsibility of Commissioner Kovas, not of Commissioner Mandelson. Progress on that is being made.

  Q158  Chairman: Thank you very much, colleagues, you have all been extremely disciplined, which I appreciate. Thank you, Roger. You said at the beginning that the expectations of Hong Kong are lower to the point of probably not very much progress but you hope the Doha Round will still come to positive conclusions. I think you have been very frank in answering our questions across a range of subjects. Can I ask you a practical question because three Members of the Committee are going to be in Hong Kong. I know Peter Mandelson will be there but are you going to be there?

  Mr Liddle: Yes.

  Q159  Chairman: I am hoping that we will have some access to the briefings that the Commission is providing. Not the closed ones, I know you have open ones as well.

  Mr Liddle: Again, Rebecca Collyer will pursue that as soon as we go back upstairs. Which of you are going?

  Chairman: Myself, John Bercow, who is not with us, and Ann McKechin. Because clearly Hong Kong is now a process rather than an end, I think we are tentatively setting up for Peter to come and give us some evidence in London in the New Year. This dialogue will continue, I just hope these 25 Member States can deliver and, indeed, several different DGs because another part of the problem seems to be fitting all of these pieces together. Thank you very much.





5   Central American Free Trade Agreement. Back

6   Ev 70 Back


 
previous page contents

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2006
Prepared 27 April 2006