Select Committee on International Development Third Report


4  COMPLETING THE DEVELOPMENT AGENDA

What is at stake?

69. Progress with the Doha Round has slowed down since December. Ian Pearson told us he was planning to hold talks with the Brazilian and Indian commerce ministers to help move the Round forward.[68] A meeting between President Lula de Silva of Brazil and the British Prime Minister on 9 March produced a joint statement which said that, 'current offers on the table fall well short of the deal we want.'[69] A subsequent meeting of the G6 — US, EU, Brazil, India, Japan and Australia - produced no new outcomes and led some delegates to suggest that Members were unlikely to be able to meet the end of April deadline for agreeing numbers for tariff and subsidy cuts in agriculture and non-agricultural market access (NAMA), and that their chances of doing so were decreasing by the day.[70]

70. There may well be value in joint statements with developing countries such as Brazil — demonstrating that the Government shares the concerns of developing countries. However, unless the EU position changes, and this requires changes in member states positions, the April deadline will be missed. The Government should therefore prioritise high level meetings with its EU member state partners.

71. The Doha Round was labelled a development round because there was a consensus that multilateral trade rules were unbalanced in favour of developed countries. The intention, according to Pascal Lamy, Director General of the WTO, was to address these imbalances, particularly in agriculture and in industrial products of interest to developing countries.[71] Much has been made by the Government of the potential benefits for developing countries of a successful round.[72]

72. New research has begun to express reservations about the precise benefits of the Round for the developing countries, especially if only minimal changes are made to existing rules. Initial World Bank assessments about the value of trade liberalisation were revised during 2005 to reveal that the gains would not be as great as had originally been predicted. In 2003 the Bank had predicted gains of US$539 billion to developing countries; in 2005 the gains for developing countries were now estimated at US$90 billion. Much of this downgrading of the estimate was due to the use of a different base year, 2001 instead of 1997, and from incorporating trade agreements reached up to 2005 whose effects can not be counted as resulting from the Round. Research from the Centre for Global Development using a different data set, produces even lower estimated gains for developing countries and has also thrown into question the precise benefits of what is on the table for developing countries.[73]

73. However, what both studies show is that 'gains as a share of national income are higher in developing countries'[74] and that roughly 60 per cent of the potential gains from free trade come from liberalising agriculture, because that is where the major distortions are. Developing countries' share of gains from liberalisation are estimated at between 30-50 per cent depending on whether countries such as Hong Kong, Korea, Singapore and Taiwan are included.

74. An important caveat is that these gains assume full liberalisation. Gains from a Doha scenario — limited and qualified liberalisation — both reduce the benefits and skew them toward the developed countries. The developing countries which gain the most in a Doha scenario are competitive Latin American exporters. A few lower income developing countries will lose because of preference erosion and higher food prices. Some of these will be able to compensate by moving factors of production but a few will gain too little to compensate for the loss of preferences.

75. Current offers on the table for improved market access fall far short of what is required for developing countries to benefit. Agricultural liberalisation has to be better structured so as to increase the benefits for developing countries. One aspect of the EU offer is the potentially devastating consequences for the Round if too many products are designated as sensitive by the EU. Pascal Lamy indicated to the Committee that the areas which the EU was likely to designate as sensitive would be so deemed precisely because they were products which other non-EU countries also produced, for example sugar. While these sectors would not be immune from tariff reductions, the basis for the reduction — for example, as a percentage of existing imports, or of domestic consumption, or of the existing tariff rate quota, — and the quota of imports allowed in, are as important as the overall number of products. Peter Mandelson has indicated to us that there may be some room for a reduction in the number of sensitive products within the limits of CAP reform, provided new commitments are forthcoming from other players. We would welcome an offer to reduce the number of products which the EU designates as sensitive, otherwise market access for developing countries will be severely limited and Doha will not be a development round. In making this offer conditional upon the actions of other states, the EU is going against the spirit of the Round. This improved offer should not, under any circumstances in this Round, be conditional on actions by developing countries.

76. In industrial sectors, estimates of gains are similarly heavily qualified and depend entirely on what formula is used to reduce industrial tariffs. Most of the debate is, rightly in our view, focused on allowing developing countries sufficient policy space to tailor a country specific industrial policy. Joseph Stiglitz in his recent book, Fair Trade for All, argues that the Round has concentrated on the wrong things if the intention is to promote development.[75] In his view, a true development agenda should go beyond agriculture and encourage industrial development, especially in the poorest countries so that they are not consigned to producing primary commodities for export. We agree with Stiglitz's recommendation that the WTO needs to promote a culture of robust, impartial and publicly available economic analysis of the effect of different initiatives on different countries, and groups within countries, if it is to effectively identify pro-development proposals and promote them to the top of the agenda. Mechanisms must be found to facilitate industrial diversification. We urge the Government to ensure that the formula for tariff reductions in NAMA does not discriminate against this.

77. In the book, Poverty and the WTO, World Bank authors conclude somewhat pessimistically: 'the impact of global trade reform on global poverty, as measured by the model in this chapter, is modest.'[76] This is partly because in many developing countries changes in prices at the world market level do not always translate to the household level. These internal blockages are significant but they cannot be addressed by the WTO.

78. How then can the developed countries best ensure that developing countries reap the benefits of liberalisation? It should be noted that the existence of losses for some developing countries in some areas should not be taken as evidence that reform is not needed, but rather that more gradual liberalisation by developing countries might help and/or that assistance is necessary to help developing countries benefit from the reforms.

79. The idea of a more gradual approach to liberalisation for developing countries is part of special and differential treatment (SDT). The report by the previous Committee in the last Parliament, Trade and Development at the WTO: Issues for Cancún, proposed general principles to inform discussions about SDT.[77] Since then, research by the ODI and the Swedish Ministry of Foreign Affairs has indicated that it remains important to make SDT more effective and to do so by agreeing a revised framework agreement in the WTO.[78] While Pascal Lamy's idea of a 'round for free' for the LDCs is a recognition of the need to treat the poorest differently, questions about who else should be eligible for SDT have made further discussion difficult. This question is made more complicated by the fact that some non-LDC countries in Africa, the Caribbean and the Pacific will lose as the value of their preferences are eroded by multilateral liberalisation.

80. There has been limited discussion of SDT in the negotiations, despite a commitment to ensure that SDT would be part of all areas of negotiation.[79] To some extent this is to be expected, since SDT is usually agreement specific and without numerical formulas it is impossible to calculate what SDT might be in any given case. Nevertheless, recognition of SDT is important, and the UK Government should work to ensure that once numerical formulas are agreed for agriculture and NAMA, effective SDT is possible according to the needs of developing countries. Particular attention should be paid to the needs of smaller, low income developing countries, especially those which will lose because of preference erosion.

81. Some adjustment assistance will be necessary in order to help developing countries benefit from trade liberalisation. One aspect of the Commission's development package was enhancing aid for trade. Aid for trade describes several categories of assistance, only some of which are relevant to the WTO. According to Oxfam, its objectives include: 'enhancing worker skills, modernizing customs systems, building roads and ports, and improving agricultural productivity and export diversification. Aid for trade should also help developing countries to meet the adjustment costs of implementing trade agreements, together with preference losses and more expensive food imports.'[80] This latter interpretation is the most important one in the current WTO context — compensating developing countries for losses incurred as a result of a new agreement. A wider pro-development agenda would also include appropriate assistance for labour and social security policies to enable developing countries to properly tackle the social and developmental costs of rapid change in their domestic economies, as well as trade facilitation.

82. Member states of the EU have promised to spend almost €3 billion a year by 2010[81] and the UK Government has £100 million per year by 2010. However, this money is part of the Government's Gleneagles pledge to increase aid. It is not new money. If the Government, or the EU, enters into agreements which harm developing countries, for example by eroding preferences, it should seek to compensate developing countries for those losses. [82]The reason for giving money — compensation — is distinct from the reason development assistance in general is given. The EU contribution is welcome. The WTO, should as a matter of priority, turn its attention to how the aid for trade mechanism will work and provide a clear mandate by the end of the year as agreed in the Doha time line. This should be done with input from potential beneficiaries in developing countries. There is also the need to clarify the relationship between aid for trade assistance and general development assistance. Aid for trade should be additional to and not simply a diversion of aid monies already pledged. We do not believe that the Government should consider aid for trade as part of its general aid budget.

Making multilateralism work for developing countries

83. One positive outcome of Hong Kong was that all members agreed to keep negotiating, and not to walk away as they had in Cancún. This is a success for the principle of multilateralism. The multilateral system is particularly important for small developing countries who can protect their interests better in a rules-based rather than a power-based system. As Pascal Lamy told us, 'if you are a developing country, if you are poor, if you are weak, if you are small, getting a bit of the EU market or the US market or of the potential Chinese market is so important for you that you will concede things you would not concede around a multilateral table.[83]

84. In addition, there are an increasing number of bilateral and regional trade negotiations which are not always in the best interests of developing countries, or of the multilateral system. We were told, 'it is not obvious that the two things are compatible and complementary, preferential trade agreements may be undermining agreements reached in the WTO and there is a question of whether the WTO is going to try and exert some sort of multilateral discipline on the formation of these agreements.'[84] We consider the multilateral system to be important for developing countries and are pleased that the Doha Round did not collapse in Hong Kong. The Government should work to ensure that the EU does not in any way prejudice a successful and timely conclusion to the Doha Round.

85. Cancún saw the emergence of developing country coalitions, capable and willing to exert pressure on the developed countries. The collapse of the Cancún Ministerial is attributed to coalitions of developing countries being unwilling to accept the deal which was on the table. Hong Kong saw the continuation of this practice. Of particular note was the formation, at the request of Brazil, of the G110, combining the influential G20 and the group of poorer developing countries the G90. Whereas the interests of the two groups are far from identical, the groups came together because they felt the EU and the US were trying to 'divide and rule' the developing countries. Certainly, as we have said, the EU mandate does attempt to do so. It is not clear whether, or for how long, such a coalition will last. However, the formation of the G110 should not be seen as just a trade union, as was suggested by Pascal Lamy, rather as a response to an attempt by the developed countries to exert pressure on developing countries to agree to things which they did not feel were in their interest. The Commission should step back and ensure that it is not abusing its position in the WTO.

86. One aspect of the process which gives us concern is the practice of mini-ministerials, or meetings of select members of the WTO. The London mini-ministerial was attended by only two developing countries, Brazil and India. There were no representatives from Africa. We accept that the use of smaller ministerial meetings make for easier decision-making but consider this an unrepresentative approach in an organisation which has facilitated greater participation and ownership by developing countries than its predecessor the GATT. It is not good from the point of view of either transparency or accountability. The Government should not condone such a practice, especially if a development agenda is still the goal of the Doha Round.

87. In summary, whilst it is good news that the Doha Round, and the principle of multilateralism, did not collapse at Hong Kong, much remains to be done in order to bring the Round to a successful conclusion. The minimum criteria for a successful agreement would be one which does not differentially hurt developing countries or provide disproportionate benefits for developed countries. At present we have concerns that sufficient progress is not being made.

88. Peter Mandelson says that any further margin of manoeuvre in agriculture could only be considered if other key players make offers in manufacturing trade and services.[85] The Commission position must change, and there is good reason for the Commission to act pre-emptively on this since, in the WTO, nothing is agreed until everything is agreed. Such action would demonstrate leadership and political commitment to a development round. The developing countries have much to gain from an ambitious outcome. The EU must not become the cause of failure.

89. The outcome of the development agenda is not a forgone conclusion. Much work remains to be done now, and subsequently after the formulas for tariff reductions are finally agreed. Despite overall commitment to multilateralism, it is still not clear that members will make ambitious new offers. A development round will not be the result of a gradualist approach. While the LDCs have secured a (limited) deal in market access, the remainder of developing countries have not. There is no more time to lose. As a key player within the EU, the UK has a major role to play. This role must be to encourage the EU member states to put the interests of developing countries first in this case. This will be the true test of a development round.


68   Q 166 [Ian Pearson MP] Back

69   Joint Statement by President Lula and Tony Blair on trade, 9 March 2006. Available at: www.number10.gov.uk Back

70   ICTSD, Bridges Weekly Trade Digest, 16 March 2005. Available at: www.ictsd.org Back

71   Q 202 [Mr Lamy] Back

72   Hilary Benn MP "In order to make poverty history, we must make trade work for the poorest' Financial Times 23 November 2005.  Back

73   For a detailed discussion of the different models and the basis on which their assumptions are made in respect of agriculture see, Kimberly Elliott, 'Looking for the Devil in the Doha Agricultural Negotiations, CGD brief, December 2005. World Bank studies are found in, K. Anderson and W. Martin (eds.) Agricultural Trade Reform and the Doha Development Agenda, (Basingstoke and Washington, 2005), and T. Hertel and L. A. Winters (eds) Poverty and the WTO, (Basingstoke and Washington, 2006). See also, W. Cline, Trade Policy and Global Poverty, (Washington, 2004). For analysis of the limits of these complex modelling exercises see, F. Ackerman, "The shrinking gains for trade: a critical assessment of Doha round projections" GDAE Working paper no 05-01, Tufts University, (2005). Back

74   Kimberly Elliot, "Looking for the Devil" ibid p 2.  Back

75   J. Stiglitz and A. Charlton, Fair Trade for all? (Oxford, 2006). Back

76   T. Hertel and L.A. Winters, Poverty and the WTO, p 499. Back

77   International Development Committee, Trade and Development at the WTO: Issues for Cancún, HC 400-I, para 145. Back

78   S. Page and P. Kleen, Special and Differential Treatment of Developing Countries in the WTO, (Sweden, 2005) Back

79   Ev 60-61, paras 5 and 8 [DFID and DTI] Back

80   Oxfam, Scaling up Aid for Trade: how to support poor countries to trade their way out of poverty, Briefing note, November 2005. Back

81   Ev 100 [Rt Hon Peter Mandelson, EU Commissioner for External Trade] Back

82   In Brussels we met with ACP Ambassadors who expressed concerns about their loss of preference as a result of reform of the EU sugar regime. The compensation which they have been promised will not meet their adjustment costs.  Back

83   Q 215 [Mr Lamy] Back

84   Q 70 [Prof Wade] Back

85   Ev 101 [Rt Hon Peter Mandelson] Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2006
Prepared 27 April 2006