Select Committee on International Development Written Evidence


Memorandum submitted by Christian Aid

INTRODUCTION

    "If we could boost Africa's share of world trade by just 1%, then its income would increase by US$70 billion dollars a year—which is more than three times all the aid the developed world gives, and enough to lift millions out of abject poverty. Driving this forward at the world trade talks in December will not be easy. But we will do everything in our power to secure an outcome that is pro-development and pro-poor."

  Alan Johnson, Secretary of State for Trade and Industry, Monday 26 September 2005

Christian Aid is committed to making international trade work for poor communities. Trade has the potential to help lift millions out of poverty. But it can also undermine livelihoods and make people even poorer.

  Current trade policy reform fails to take into account the economics of poverty in the developing world. Most poor people live in rural areas where the main business is agriculture, and where services, infrastructure and alternative employment are almost non-existent. Rapid liberalisation, which has been the norm in many developing countries over the past 20 years, means a glut of cheaper imports, which push local producers out of business. So, for instance, tomato farmers are reduced to breaking rocks for a living and Jamaican sugar-factory workers are driven to prostitution to survive.

  Christian Aid's work in more than 50 countries has brought us into contact with numerous examples of countries, communities and industries damaged by inappropriate trade liberalisation. Our research estimates that trade liberalisation has cost sub-Saharan Africa US$272 billion over the past 20 years—equivalent to the amount it has received in aid and debt relief over the same period, and more than enough money to pay off its debt and finance vaccinations and education for every child in the region.

  The modern economic success stories—South Korea, Malaysia, China and Mauritius—have based their growth on industries that were protected and nurtured as they grew. This is the way in which every industrialised country has developed.

  Christian Aid therefore argues that developing countries should not be pushed to liberalise their markets but should be able to set their own path to development. We are not calling for blanket protectionism or isolationism and self-sufficiency, but for developing countries to be given the political space to introduce targeted policies that best contribute to poverty eradication, whether they involve liberalisation or protectionism.

  Christian Aid is joined by the 70 organisations and over nine million supporters of the Trade Justice Movement as well as the more than 500 organisations that make up the MAKEPOVERTYHISTORY coalition in opposing pressure on developing countries to liberalise their economies.

1.  THE WTO IN 2005

  1.1  After the G8 in July and two high-profile conferences in the US in September, the next date on the global anti-poverty campaigner's agenda is December, when the World Trade Organisation (WTO) holds its sixth ministerial meeting in Hong Kong. For many campaigners, this is the culmination of a year of intense activity. Despite encouraging news on debt and aid at the G8, many people feel that progress on international trade is the real goal of 2005.

  1.2  However, there is a distinct possibility that trade will be the issue on which there is the least progress in 2005. A pro-poor outcome from the Hong Kong ministerial meeting of the WTO would require rich countries to make long-overdue changes to their own trade policies, while allowing poor countries the policy flexibility they need. At moment, the chances of such reform seem to be receding fast. The EU and US are offering very little but demanding a great deal in return. Developing-country delegates feel frustrated and disempowered, and in Geneva the phrase "no deal is better than a bad deal" is already common currency among poor-country negotiators. There is a strong possibility no deal will be reached, as negotiations falter in Geneva and the mood turns more and more pessimistic. However, a failure at Hong Kong will not be the end of the Doha round; it just means that more progress will have to be made in Geneva next year.

  1.3  Christian Aid believes that the most important thing is to get the right deal—in Hong Kong if possible, or later if not.

2.  AGRICULTURE

  2.1  The majority of the world's poor people depend on agriculture for their living. They have been hardest hit by many years of trade liberalisation. Poor farmers have found themselves unable to sell their goods in local markets, because of competition from cheaper, often subsidised, imports. Research has shown that imports tend to rise faster than exports following trade liberalisation, and that imports of consumer goods, such as food, rise fastest of all. For farmers, this means losing their domestic markets without any increase in their exports to compensate. These farmers have no alternatives available to them—in most developing countries there is no suitable industry to employ large numbers of people leaving agriculture.

  2.2  Some developing-country governments are starting to take a more nuanced approach to agricultural trade policy, protecting farmers at certain times of year, or making imports conditional on a certain level of domestic buying. Christian Aid's report Taking Liberties: Poor People, Free Trade and Trade Justice, contains examples of farmers in Mozambique, Honduras and India who have benefited from protection. However, if WTO negotiations on agriculture lead to an agreement which demands a high level of liberalisation, selective protectionism will no longer be an option for developing countries—and it is poor farmers who will pay the price.

  2.3  The agricultural negotiations are of interest to almost every member of the WTO—but for some very different reasons. For instance, Brazil, India, South Africa and the other big developing countries of the G20, have large and competitive agricultural sectors and want to increase their agricultural exports by reducing trade barriers and the support given to farmers in rich countries. Meanwhile, the EU and US are each trying to resist pressures to reduce the support they give their own farmers. Both have made modest proposals to reduce that support and improve market access for agricultural products, but these proposals fall far short of what other WTO members are asking for.

  2.4  The poorer developing countries of the G33, are most interested in retaining their right to protect their own farmers. Current proposals for achieving this include defining a group of "special products" which developing countries would be allowed to protect, and giving those countries access to a "special safeguard mechanism" that they could use to defend their products from increased imports. Lower tariff reductions for developing countries on all agricultural products are also being proposed.

  2.5  Poor countries that have been enjoying trade preferences (special access to rich countries' markets) stand to lose out if trade barriers come down and other countries get similar access to the same markets. They favour less liberalisation, introduced over a longer period of time in order to protect their preferences for as long as possible.

  2.6  Although there has been much political blood spilt over agricultural liberalisation in the last few weeks, in both Brussels and Geneva, a closer look at the numbers calls into question the huge emphasis on agriculture as the key development issue for the Doha round. Recent academic studies have tried to put a figure on the impact in developing countries of agricultural liberalisation in rich countries. The picture is very mixed.

  2.7  Agricultural reform in rich countries will involve both reducing the subsidies paid to farmers and lowering the high tariffs that keep agricultural products out of rich country markets. Getting rid of agricultural subsidies would, according to Nancy Birdsall, Dani Rodrik and Arvind Subramanian (respectively president of the Centre for Global Development in Washington DC, professor of international political economy at Harvard University and division chief at the research department of the International Monetary Fund), lead to a rise in the price of key commodities, such as sugar, cotton and beef, of between 2-12%.[8] This is a marginal increase, compared with annual price fluctuations for these products of 50-75%.

  2.8  Price rises will, in general, be positive for producers and negative for consumers. Rodrik et al argue that these very small price rises will be of marginal benefit to producers. A price rise for farmers in west Africa producing export crops, which followed the 100% devaluation of the CFA franc in 1994 (and which should have doubled prices for those farmers producing export crops) did not significantly reduce poverty, as much of the price increase was captured by traders.

  2.9  The price rises which may follow the reduction of agricultural subsidies in rich countries are likely to harm countries which import food and particularly poor consumers in those countries. Reviewing various econometric studies on this issue, Joseph Stiglitz and Andrew Charlton conclude that following subsidy reform, "many developing countries will find themselves worse off, and this will be particularly so for urban workers".[9]

  2.10  Other studies have looked at the overall impact of agricultural liberalisation—the impact of improved market access as well as of price rises resulting from reduced subsidies. While most show some benefits, these are small and mainly go to rich countries. Developing countries would get around one-fifth of the overall benefits of agricultural liberalisation, and most of this goes to just three countries: Brazil, India, and Argentina. Many countries in Africa will suffer because of the loss of the trade preferences they currently enjoy.[10].

  2.11  None of this means that agricultural reform should not happen. A system that takes money from taxpayers in the EU and distributes it to large landowners, including some of the richest people in Europe, is not a fair one, and should not be defended. However, the equivocal nature of the effects of agricultural reform in developing countries should lead to two conclusions:

    —  Firstly, it is essential that some of the huge financial savings that will result from agricultural reform in rich countries are channelled into assisting the likely losers in developing countries.

    —  Secondly, poor countries and those, like the UK government, who advocate a development-friendly agenda at the WTO should remain realistic about the likely benefits (and possible costs) of agricultural reform.

  2.12  This is of crucial importance, given that the EU and US are demanding so much from other WTO members in return for the minimal agricultural reforms they are prepared to make. The EU's most recent offer to reform Europe's agricultural regime came with the caveat:

    Europe's major partners need to understand that this offer is conditional on immediate movement in negotiations on trade in industrial goods and services as well as in other areas of the agricultural negotiation.

European Commission, 28 October 2005

  2.13  These trade-offs are potentially disastrous for developing countries. The EU is saying to poor countries that unless they agree to liberalise vital services and lower tariffs on industrial products, they won't get the minimal agricultural reform that they have been promised. The benefits of that agricultural reform far from certain—and indeed there may be costs rather than benefits for some countries, And if, in return, developing countries do liberalise services they will be unable to guarantee their citizens access to the essential infrastructure—such as transport, energy and banking—that make trade possible. And if they give up the right to use industrial tariffs they will jeopardise any chance of industrial development in the future.

3.  NON-AGRICULTURAL MARKET ACCESS (NAMA)

  3.1  A second pillar of the WTO talks is the non-agricultural market access (NAMA) negotiations. Developing countries face two dangers in these talks. Many of their existing industries are under threat if the eventual agreement requires that they reduce their tariffs very steeply and quickly. Countries in Africa and Latin America that have liberalised rapidly have lost tens of thousands of manufacturing jobs and seen developing industries collapse. They will be much less able to develop new industries if they are not able to use tariffs and other protection to support them. In almost every country that has industrialised successfully, protection was a key factor in giving new industries the space to become competitive and productive. For developing countries today, a degree of protection is often key in attracting investors to a new sector (see Taking Liberties, which you can download at www.christianaid.org.uk/indepth/409trade/index.htm for an example of this in the Mozambican sugar sector).

  3.2  In the words of one negotiator, the NAMA talks have been "held hostage to agriculture". Nonetheless, the key fault-lines in the negotiations are clear. The EU and in particular, the US, want to reduce tariffs as far and as fast as possible. The US has even floated the idea of zero tariffs on industrial products in every WTO member. Developing countries are resisting these pressures, arguing that they need to retain the ability to increase industrial tariffs if necessary to support emerging industries.

  3.3  As in agriculture, the discussions have centred around how much tariffs should be reduced by, and what exceptions there should be. The main disagreement is over whether those countries with higher tariffs (generally developing countries) should cut their tariffs the most, or whether it should be richer countries that make the steepest reductions.

  3.4  Current proposals, from the US and the EU, would mean that the highest tariffs would be subject to the steepest reductions. This would require developing countries to reduce their tariffs by more than richer countries. In a particularly damaging development, developing countries are being asked to trade off overall tariff reductions against the number of exemptions they have. In other words, if they succeed in limiting their overall tariff reduction they will be asked to pay by applying that reduction to all products. The US and the EU are being particularly insistent on this point.

  3.5  Least developed countries are mostly exempt from making any reductions, but whatever is agreed will probably start to affect them in future rounds of trade negotiations. Countries which have a low level of "binding" on their tariffs (meaning that they have not agreed maximum tariff levels at the WTO for the products the tariffs apply to), will be asked to bind their tariffs at the average developing-country tariff level. For some, this is likely to mean reducing tariffs on particular products, where there is an existing tariff higher than the developing-country average.

  3.6  Countries that receive trade preferences are also concerned about the effect of general tariff reductions as a result of a WTO agreement, and have proposed that products which receive preferences are liberalised more slowly. Other developing countries do not support this idea, arguing that preferences benefit some developing countries at the expense of others.

  3.7  The EU and, in particular, the US are negotiating very aggressively in the NAMA talks. This is partly because they know they will have to make concessions in agriculture, and are determined to get the best deal possible in other areas to compensate. It is also because they see an opportunity for their exporters to get access to some big developing-country markets.

4.  SERVICES

  4.1  The third main area of WTO talks is services, which are being discussed under the General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS). A number of rich countries, including the UK, hope the talks will help their financial and other industries gain access to new markets.

  4.2  Rich countries have defended the GATS agreement as being especially "developing country friendly" because it works on a voluntary basis—countries make requests of each other to liberalise particular services sectors, and make offers of liberalisation in successive rounds of negotiations. This voluntary framework has been threatened recently by a number of rich countries (the EU, Japan and a few others), who are dissatisfied with the progress to date and have proposed a new structure for the negotiations.

  4.3  They call for "complementary approaches" which would fix the number of services that each country had to liberalise. The WTO has established 163 different categories of services (banking, insurance, water provision, etc) and the European Commission has proposed that developing countries be required to liberalise more than half of these—at least 93 of the 163. Which categories were included in the 93 would in theory be up to individual countries to decide, though the EC has made it clear which sectors it would like to see liberalised.

  4.4  This proposal, previously called "benchmarking", is a response to what the EU and others see as inadequate offers from developing countries to liberalise. In other words, they have not got what they wanted from the existing structure, so are attempting to change it. Changing the rules halfway through negotiations does little to inspire confidence in the motives of rich countries. Quite rightly, developing countries are outraged. It is as if one of the teams in a football match proposed widening the opposition's goal at half-time because they were not scoring the goals they thought they deserved.

  4.5  The EU's demand for more liberalisation from developing countries is somewhat galling, given that developing countries have actually made more offers during negotiations to liberalise their services than rich countries. Brazil has gone as far as to claim that the EU is looking for a "round for free" in services.

  4.6  The proposal for "complementary approaches" has been rejected by a number of developing-country groupings at the WTO, including the African Union, least developed countries, Arab trade ministers and several Latin American countries, including Brazil. Despite this overwhelming rejection, the EU is still strongly pushing this proposal.

5.  SPECIAL AND DIFFERENTIAL TREATMENT

  5.1  A key aspect of the Doha round was meant to be the consideration of developing countries' interests in a separate set of talks on special and differential treatment (SDT). The idea was to review existing agreements and see what changes needed to be made for them to truly support development. Rules were also supposed to be set to guide future agreements, ensuring that basic developmental principles were followed.

  5.2  This area of the talks was supposed to be completed quickly, so that the development credentials of the "development round" could be firmly established. However, they have been dogged by controversy and have made almost no progress in the four years since the Doha ministerial meeting. This slowness has largely been because of the reluctance of rich countries to make any concessions to the poorest, and their determination to hold out and extract the maximum negotiating capital from whatever agreement is made.

  5.3  This is unacceptable in a round where the focus is supposed to be development. WTO members must agree to give developing countries what they were promised in Doha. They must sort out the problems with existing agreements, while putting in place deals which ensure that the special rights of developing countries are respected in any future agreement.

  5.4  One issue that has dogged the talks has been that of "differentiation"—that is, which groups of countries should benefit from particular SDT provisions. Many developed countries—including the UK—have argued that they cannot agree to much of what is being asked for in SDT negotiations because of concerns over who would be eligible. It is often argued that "you can't expect us to treat Brazil in the same way as Ghana".

  5.5  There is an element of truth in this position. However, developing countries are rightly suspicious that talk of differentiation is an attempt to weaken the important political alliances between developing-country WTO members, and to ensure that any SDT offered carries absolutely no cost to richer countries.

  5.6  It is particularly unfortunate that agreements that allow for a more flexible approach—and that may be a suitable model for SDT in the future—are being undermined by those same countries that are most concerned about differentiation. The GATS approach, calling for different commitments from each country, allows for differentiation between individual states. The call for special products in the negotiations on agriculture provides for a set of criteria that can identify trade polices that affect crops, which are of importance to specific groups of poor people, regardless of which developing country they are in.

  5.7  Special products and GATS both allow for a flexible and pragmatic approach to SDT, based on a country's actual economic circumstances. However, the flexibility of the GATS is currently undermined by rich-country proposals on benchmarking which will impose a more rigid system with less differentiation between countries. And the idea of special products has received a lukewarm reception at best from rich countries at the WTO.

  5.8  Rather than allowing SDT talks, and the wider discussion around how developing countries should be treated in the negotiations, to be held hostage to some arbitrary and politically sensitive notion of "differentiation", more attention should be paid to working out how WTO agreements and existing proposals differentiate between countries already, on the basis of economic criteria that are relevant to the particular sector in question. There can be no overarching system for differentiation, but the key criteria must always be how to ensure that poor people—in whichever country they live—will benefit from whatever agreement is on the table.

6.  THE ROLE OF THE UK GOVERNMENT IN 2005

  6.1  The UK government has put development issues firmly on the agenda in 2005. On trade, the government has made many encouraging statements about the need to stop forcing liberalisation on developing countries, and the need to reform agricultural subsidies and high tariff barriers in rich countries.

  6.2  The government has announced changes in two areas of trade policy: the Economic Partnership Agreements between the EU and its former colonies, and the practice of demanding that countries liberalise in return for aid. Neither announcement has resulted in changes in practice yet, but both were welcome as statements of intent. The government has failed to set out its policy position on the WTO with the same clarity, where the negotiating position of the European Commission contradicts their stated position of "no forced liberalisation".

7.  A GOOD DEAL?

  7.1  There has been much talk in Geneva recently that "no deal is better than a bad deal". A good WTO deal for developing countries—whether reached at Hong Kong or many years down the line—is one that will extract big concessions from rich countries, while guaranteeing poor countries the right to use trade policy to further their development goals. Specifically, it would:

    —  end all trade-distorting agricultural subsidies in rich countries;

    —  increase access to rich-country markets for all developing-country products—agricultural and industrial;

    —  guarantee developing countries the right to control agricultural trade in order to protect poor farmers and promote long-term development;

    —  guarantee developing countries the right to control trade in industrial products in order to support emerging industries; and

    —  guarantee developing countries the right to control and regulate trade and investment in services, in order to ensure that poor people have access to the services they need—both public services such as health and water, and essential infrastructure such as banking.

8.  RECOMMENDATIONS

  8.1  The UK should make a clear public statement about its position in relation to the WTO negotiations. It should invest real political capital into changing the stance of the EU. The UK should make the minutes of the 133 committee public, so that member states can be held accountable for their role in formulating the EU's common position.

AGRICULTURE

  8.2  Developing countries should have the right to protect poor farmers. They should be able to fully exempt crops that are vital for ensuring their people have enough food from any liberalisation. And they should be allowed to regulate trade to support agriculture, protect livelihoods, and deliver rural development and long-term growth.

  8.3  An early end date for export subsidies should be announced as soon as possible.

  8.4  Domestic support for agriculture in developed countries should also be reformed, so that it does not distort trade and is only given where it provides clear benefits for rural development and sustainable farming.

NON-AGRICULTURAL MARKET ACCESS

  8.5  Whatever deal is agreed, it must allow developing countries to reduce their tariffs by much less than developed countries, in recognition of the more fragile state of their economies.

  8.6  Developing countries must have the flexibility to exempt certain sectors from tariff reduction altogether, and leave tariff levels for sensitive products unbound.

SERVICES

  8.7  Developing countries must retain the right to regulate all service providers as necessary to promote their development objectives. The role of regulation in ensuring that poor people have access to the services they need must be clarified and confirmed in the GATS.

  8.8  Developing countries should not be required to commit any public services, supplied by the state or the private sector, to binding liberalisation in the GATS. It is essential that developing countries retain the right to provide and regulate public services as necessary to meet their development goals.

  8.9  Current European Commission proposals that countries liberalise at least 93 out of the 163 categories of services go against the EU negotiating mandate and the national sovereignty of developing countries and should be scrapped.

November 2005





8   Nancy Birdsall, Dani Rodrik, and Arvind Subramanian, How to Help Poor Countries, Foreign Affairs Journal, volume 84, number 4, July/August 2005. Back

9   J Stiglitz and A Charlton, "The Development Round of Trade Negotiations in the Aftermath of Cancún", Commonwealth Secretariat, 2004. Back

10   See F Ackerman, "The Shrinking Gains from Trade: A Critical Assessment of Doha Round projections", F Ackerman, Tufts University Global Development and Environment Institute, Working Paper No. 05-01, 2005, for a review of recent econometric studies on this issue. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2006
Prepared 27 April 2006