Select Committee on International Development Written Evidence


Memorandum submitted by Alan Gibson, The Springfield Centre

  Alan Gibson is a partner in the Springfield Centre for Business in Development, a UK-based consultancy, training and research organisation. Working with a number of international development agencies, Springfield's focus is private sector development. At the heart of all their work is the market development approach—or making markets work for the poor. They have been involved in the design and review of a number of market development interventions (some supported by DFID) in Africa and Asia, have written extensively on the subject and offer training programmes on this theme for development agency staff.

1.  INTRODUCTION

  1.1  While the Committee's remit in relation to this inquiry is broad the focus of this brief submission is more limited. The starting point here is that growth is essential for poverty reduction and that, in turn, private sector development is critical for growth.[105] The question to which this submission addresses itself is, given this, what should be the role of agencies such as DFID in promoting private sector development that is both effective and inclusive? In other words, what should DFID do?

  1.2  The submission first recognises the widespread failings of many development experiences and then, learning from this, focuses on the market development approach[106] as a means of bringing greater coherence and efficacy to development agency (and government) endeavours. It presents the essence of this approach, highlights current, positive examples of the approach in action and outlines its advantages. Finally, the broad implications for DFID are highlighted.

2.  RECOGNISE THE BIG PICTURE: ACKNOWLEDGE GENERAL WEAKNESSES . . .

  2.1  Development, as an activity and "sector", is characteristically prone to its own emperor's new clothes syndrome. Good intentions are mistaken with achievements. Causes are confused with symptoms. The possibility of doing damage is not acknowledged. Debate can slide to a default option of comfortable superficiality and easy myths—the "more-is-always-better" school of aid-giving, the "answer-is-money" response to the big challenges and so on. Incentives, as has been mentioned by other contributors to this inquiry, often encourage not candid examination of performance but presentation of the best possible interpretation of reality.

3.  | AND THE SPECIFIC FAILINGS IN PRIVATE SECTOR DEVELOPMENT

  3.1  These general traits apply to private sector development but here there are more specific failings—and recognising and learning from these is a prerequisite to acting more effectively in the future. Broadly, these can be categorised into two blocks:

    —  Remote reform: the essence of this approach has been to reform the overall environment of policies and regulations so that the costs of business are reduced and the allocative power of the price mechanism restored so that the supply-side of the economy, unencumbered, will respond. The experience here is mixed. Often, despite apparently following the correct script, countries' private sectors have not developed well and growth has remained sluggish (eg Ghana). The reasons for this are various but, crucially, processes of institutional reform have not reflected local realities and the other constraints to development—information, networks, knowledge—have not been addressed.[107]

    —  Impulsive intervention: in contrast, this swathe of development activities has sought to "get things done" directly. The ethos here is, if the market isn't delivering, we should replace it and provide finance, advice, contacts and materials ourselves. After many years of experience, major reviews[108] of these all point to disappointing outreach, sustainability and impact, and markets that are distorted and weakened. Why has this happened? Most obviously, agencies are not businesses—they don't have the culture, orientation and skills to deliver. More fundamentally, they haven't asked the right question. The interveners' instinct has been to ask: "What problems do businesses have and how can I solve these?" and not to ask the more relevant systemic questions—"What problems do businesses have, why isn't the market environment providing solutions to these and how can I address these". Development interventions have been about addressing business problems (symptoms) and not those of the wider market system around business (causes).

  3.2  What both of these experiences share is a failure to engage with the underlying systemic constraints that prevent market systems from working effectively. Market development has emerged from these experiences.

4.  MARKET DEVELOPMENT: THE APPROACH AND THE PRACTICE

  4.1  The essence of a making markets work approach to private sector development is:

    —  Understand market systems: identify the key reasons for the underdevelopment of the market system. Why isn't the market working, especially from the perspective of the poor—as consumers, employees or producers?

    —  Develop a vision of the future: build a transparent view of the future in relation to who undertakes and pays from key market functions.

    —  Intervene to build the market system: on the basis of key principles of good practice and using a variety of potential tools, take actions to address key constraints and develop the market system.

  4.2 There is now a growing body of experience of how, using this approach, sustainable and effective private sector development can be stimulated. Three examples illustrate the potential of the approach (all of which have been DFID-supported to some degree):

    (a)

        Financial services in South Africa

    The problem: low reach of financial services, especially among low-income groups excludes them from the mainstream economy.

    The solution: developing enhanced information services for financial providers, supporting innovation in services and contributing to improved regulatory processes.

    The result: contributed to major increase (several million people) in coverage and usage of financial services and a growing momentum of positive change.

    (b)          Radio services for SMEs in Uganda

    The problem: poor quality of SME-related programming in commercial radio services restricts information flow in the economy and limits accountability.

    The solution: work with small number of radio stations directly to improve programme innovation and quality, support "crowding in" of others and strengthen wider market functions (regulation, journalism quality etc).

    The result: up to 20 radio stations, serving around 8m listeners, competing on the basis of programming and services aimed at an SME audience.

    (c)          Information services for farmers in Bangladesh

    The problem: productivity among small-scale vegetable farmers is low. One key reason for this is lack of information on cultivation practices and application of inputs.

    The solution: in the context of dysfunctional state agriculture extension services, introduce new training for input retailers in the supply chain to enhance their role as information providers to and problem solvers for farmers.

    The result: after successful introduction, major input companies plan to expand training to reach up to 14,000 retailers, potentially covering one-quarter of the country's vegetable farmers.

5.  THE ADVANTAGES OF THE MARKET DEVELOPMENT APPROACH

  5.1  Although very different, all cases have achieved success that is sustainable (market players have a strong incentive to continue), significant and discernible (millions of people have been affected) and additional (it's unlikely that these benefits would have been achieved without intervention—or certainly not with the same scale and speed). These also highlight a number of advantages and characteristics of the approach:

    —  A uniting framework: although different markets, each uses the same framework to guide their actions. The messy nature of so much diverse private sector promotion activity can be brought into a coherent framework for implementation and a potential common platform for inter-agency collaboration established.

    —  Clarity of agencies' role: in each case, development agencies have acted as temporary facilitators of market systems (rather than—as conventional approaches would emphasise—direct players within them)

    —  Operational flexibility within a strategic framework: each case has used a variety of inputs—cost-sharing grants, technical assistance, new ideas. However, while there is clearly no mechanical formula here and flexibility is required, these are all within a coherent strategic context.

    —  Transparency of organisation's role in markets: the role of different players—government, membership associations, the private sector—is set out clearly.

6.  WHAT DOES THIS MEAN FOR DFID?

  6.1  DFID, like all development agencies, is not one tight-knit entity but rather a series of smaller communities—and sometimes at odds with each other. Notwithstanding this inherent diversity, there are general trends in evidence. In the context of these, what are the implications of market development thinking and practice for DFID policies and organisation?

(a)      Marking the limits of budget support—recognise the need for other interventions

  6.2  While there are strong arguments in favour of focusing aid efforts on budget support (not least promoting cohesion and reducing coordination costs), there are also serious concerns. When many of the fundamental constraints to private sector development are related to information, incentives and knowledge it is not clear how budget support can address these. There is an unfortunate sense of deja" vu here; tweak the big levers of government policy and regulation and supply-side response will happen. But an environment that is truly enabling is more than simply having the right regulations in place (even if that's a big part of it). The kind of tangible, systemic changes mentioned above simply would not happen were budget support the only instrument that DFID could call upon. Budget support may well allow DFID to shift large amounts of money in a relatively easy manner but—by itself—has limited efficacy in relation to private sector development outcomes.

  6.3  The first implication therefore must be that DFID needs to restore greater balance to its work and complement its budget support focus with other interventions related to market development. A growing body of experience is emerging on the different mechanisms and approaches available to design and implement these. It would be ironic if, just as we're learning more about how to intervene effectively, DFID's support began to wane. Indeed, budget support collaboration with governments is likely to be enhanced by a market development framework and when it is informed by market development interventions.

(b)      Put making markets work thinking at the centre of private sector development

  6.4  There are (still incipient) signs within DFID that market development is emerging as a unifying theme for different disciplines (enterprise development, livelihoods, agriculture etc). Development is an endeavour characterised by different technical specialisms—boxes stuffed with different methods, perspectives and jargon, often jealously guarded. Market development potentially offers one means of bringing greater cohesion to these disparate boxes.

(c)      Re-establish DFID's technical capacity in private sector development

  6.5  The DFID brand in the world of development agencies has, historically, stood for technical insight and innovation. Making markets work for the poor is an example of DFID leading international practice. Yet, as more emphasis appears to be placed on shifting funds and DFID simply as a conduit for these, its technical edge is declining—much to the surprise of other agencies. The implication is clear: there are ways in which thoughtful and intelligent interventions can promote effective and inclusive private sector development. If DFID wishes to engage meaningfully with private sector development issues it needs to have people of the right calibre in place.

(d)      Give private sector development a champion

  6.6  Amidst the plethora of structural changes that have taken place within DFID in recent years, private sector development appears to have missed out. Yet (and this inquiry is evidence of this) there is no doubt that pro-poor growth (and the range of wider benefits stemming from it) will depend critically on the extent to which private sector development is achieved. Given this, the absence of a strong commitment from DFID to private sector development—manifested perhaps in an in-house champion—is a striking omission.

March 2006







105   Clearly, there are many issues pertaining to the nature of growth and poverty reduction but while these are important they have been the subject of other submissions and discussions and are not considered here. Back

106   The terms market development approach and making markets work for the poor are used interchangeably. Back

107   The ascendance of institutional economics in development thinking is a response to these past failings. Back

108   For example, the Committee of Donor Agencies for Small Enterprise Development in the 1990s. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2006
Prepared 23 July 2006