Memorandum submitted by the World Development
Movement
WATER, SANITATION AND PRIVATE SECTOR DEVELOPMENT
SUMMARY OF
SUBMISSION
Overarching principles
The World Development Movement (WDM)
is not anti-private sector. There are many legitimate roles for
the private sector in an economy although whether and how such
private sector activity benefits society is dependent on how governments
regulate. There are also roles that the private sector should
not be expected to fulfil.
It is critical that governments understand
and promote an appropriate role for the private sector in development.
International development policy should not be based on the assumption
that the private sector is always more efficient and effective
than the public sector or that private sector investment can substitute
for government funding.
The water and sanitation sector provides
an important case study of the limit to which the private sector
can be expected to provide a key public service (or "infrastructure
service" as the World Bank calls it) and contribute to achieving
several of the key Millennium Development Goals. WDM's contribution
to the IDC inquiry focuses on this sector.
The theory behind water privatisation
There is a global water crisis which
needs tackling, especially in terms of connecting new communities
to the water network.
There are many expectations and assumptions
about what the private sector can contribute towards tackling
this global water crisis.
How water is different from other sectors
Water is a natural monopoly so arguments
about competition and markets, which may apply to private sector
development in other sectors, are not relevant.
The private water sector is not necessarily
more efficient than the public sector.
The water and sanitation sector is
very capital intensive and billions of dollars of investment in
the sector is required.
Access to water is a human right.
The reality of water privatisation
Private companies have not delivered
the better capital on better terms that has been expected.
In parts of the world where tackling
the lack of access to water is an imperative, few people have
been connected due to private investment.
Private companies have also not reduced
government risk and the burden of borrowing.
Instead, privatisations have been
dependent upon public or donor funding when making new connections.
Investment activity has not been
concentrated in the area of most need but rather where companies
feel they can maximise their profits.
Private companies have resorted to
unacceptable tactics to maintain profits.
The role of donors
Conditions set by donors have pressured
developing countries to privatise water.
Donors have also contributed aid
funds to public relations work aimed at promoting privatisation.
As a result of misplaced expectations
on the private sector, donors and governments have substantially
reduced the amount of money they devote to water and sanitation.
Where next for the water sector
Water utilities which keep water
in public hands have had success in boosting the number of connections.
The private sector does have a role
in the water and sanitation sector but this must be restricted
to activities which do not require their control or management
of utilities.
INTRODUCTION
1. The World Development Movement (WDM)
campaigns to tackle the root causes of poverty. With our partners
around the world, we win positive change for the world's poorest
people. We believe that charity is not enough. We lobby governments
and companies to change polices that keep people poor. WDM is
a democratic membership organisation of individuals and local
groups.
2. This submission concerns the issue of
the private sector's role within the water and sanitation sector.
It is based, at least in part, on the findings of a study shortly
to be published by WDM and Public Services International.[168]
3. This study will look at the claims made
by, and on behalf of, the private sector, in terms of the contribution
it could make towards tackling the global water crisis. It will
look at the structural reasons why these claims were never likely
to be realised, as well as the evidence that demonstrates this
to be the case. In particular, there will be a number of case
studies to demonstrate the failure of the private sector to deliver
investment as was promised. It will also assess the knock-on implications
of this failure, especially for donors.
THE THEORY
BEHIND WATER
PRIVATISATION
4. Over one billion people need to gain
access to clean water supply and over two billion need to gain
access to adequate sanitation. Over 80% of those needing connections
are in the regions of Sub-Saharan Africa, South Asia, and East
Asia and Pacific. Meanwhile, the Millennium Development Goal (MDG)
requires, by 2015, a reduction by half of the proportion of people
without sustainable access to clean water and adequate sanitation.[169]
Achieving other MDGs, such as reducing disease and cutting child
mortality rates, will also require improvements to water and sanitation.
5. There are many misplaced hopes and expectations
surrounding the ability of the private sector to make a contribution
towards the MDGs in water. If a public utility is failingand
there are many, especially in developing countries, which arethere
is often an assumption that inevitably the private sector will
be able to do a better job. It is assumed that the private sector
will be able to bring in a higher level of finance than is otherwise
possible. It is expected that cash-strapped governments will be
able to off-load risk and the burden of borrowing and investing
themselves if they bring in the private sector. There is also
the assumption that the private sector will extract better value
from a given sum than the public sector by spending more wisely
and streamlining procedures and structures.
6. The assumptions outlined above are similar
to the justifications for the private sector's involvement in
other sectors: efficiency, injections of cash and relieving the
public sector burden. As Clare Short, former UK Secretary of State
for International Development, told the House of Commons in 2002:
"Privatisation is the only way to get the investment that
[poor] countries need in things like banking, tourism, telecommunications
and services such as water under good regulatory arrangements."[170]
But water is different from almost any other sector, for a number
of important reasons.
HOW WATER
IS DIFFERENT
FROM OTHER
SECTORS
7. Firstly, water is a natural monopoly
meaning that competitionand any resulting efficienciesis
impossible. As the European Commission's Directorate General (DG)
for Competition which, amongst other things, has been working
on how to organise the water sector within the European Union,
stated, "the liberalisation of water is unlikely to result
in the same benefits as other network industries because a large
proportion of the cost of supply of residential customers is incurred
by the distribution network (which would remain a monopoly) and
there is little scope for supply from distant sources."[171]
It is hard to see how a privatised water system would lead to
a market where competition could lead to benefits for poor people.
8. Secondly, the evidence does not indicate
that it is possible to make assumptions about the relative efficiency
of the public and private sector. In the water sector specifically,
research suggests that the private sector is no more efficient
or effective than the public sector. As one research article on
water provision in Asia concludes, "The results show that
efficiency is not significantly different in private companies
than in public ones."[172]
Another report concluded that the studies it analysed "reveal
that there is no compelling evidence to date of private utilities
outperforming public utilities or that privatising water utilities
leads to unambiguous improvements in performance".[173]
9. In a study of the Thames Water concession
in Jakarta, Thames PAM Jaya, it has been noted that "The
overall achievement of the private company must be considered
very low. This may imply that the status of water supply system
in Jakarta is very much the same as it was before the involvement
of the private sector ... Officials admit that [the previous]
public operation should have been able to attain the targets even
better than the private company's performance".[174]
10. Thirdly, the water and sanitation sectors
are incredibly capital intensive and investment on a massive scale
is required. There have been a wide variety of estimates of the
extent of investment needed to tackle the global water crisis:
these range from US$51 billion to US$102 billion for water supply,
and from US$24 billion to US$42 billion for sanitation.[175]
11. It is difficult to see how the requirement
to inject such sums can be reconciled with a private company's
profit motive. Companies need to generate profits which they then
transfer to shareholders, and they are on the record as stating
how this duty can conflict with the need to invest. For example,
after negotiations for a water concession in Zimbabwe broke down
in 1999, an executive from UK water company Biwater explained
that, "from a social point of view these kind of projects
are viable, but unfortunately, from a private sector point of
view, they are not".[176]
12. Finally, access to clean water is widely
recognised to be a human right and as such only deliverable by
public authorities and governments. Indeed there are a number
of campaigns being run around the world to get this demand entrenched
within the United Nations system, which would enable people to
hold their governments to account on this issue.[177]
At the root of each of these campaigns is a belief that water
is a fundamentally important resource that should not be treated
as if it were solely an economic commodity.
THE REALITY
OF WATER
PRIVATISATION
13. The reality of water privatisation,
and especially the amount of investment it has levered in to connect
new customers in developing countries, has been disappointing
to say the least. Overall, there is little evidence that private
companies have brought in extra capital on better terms to boost
the number of connections.
14. Some types of privatisation contracts
contain no private investment requirements at all. Management
contracts never involve the private sector investing in the water
system while lease/affermage contracts involve private investment
in renewing the existing system but not in extending the system.
Only concession contracts have requirements on private companies
to bring investment in to extend the system.[178]
15. But the record of concession contracts
has been very poor. Only five concessions for water services have
been implemented in sub-Saharan Africa. Three of these covered
water and electricity in Cape Verde, Gabon and Mali. The only
two concessions for water and sanitation services alone are both
in South Africa and both have cut their investment plansby
60% at Dolphin Coast, and by a complete halt to all investments
in Nelspruit since 2001 (see later). Meanwhile, Mali has terminated
the concession and renationalised the electricity and water services,
and Cape Verde is threatening to do the same, in both cases on
the grounds of failure to make the necessary investments. In Gabon,
as of 2005, the new investment programme of the privately-controlled
utility is being financed by an international public sector bank,
and the savings of the residents of Gabon.[179]
16. In the entire South Asia region, including
India, Pakistan, Bangladesh and Sri Lanka, there has not been
a single concession or lease contract for the private sector operation
of water or sanitation services. In a region with 1,400 million
people (23% of the world's population) no investments have been
made by private operators of water services in extending the water
distribution systems.[180]
17. Once a privatisation contract is in
place, a company might seek to re-negotiate itself out of some
of its commitments. Eight months after starting operations in
Buenos Aires in 1993, Aguas Argentinas a subsidiary of Suez, requested
an "extraordinary review" of tariffs, due to unexpected
operational losses. Despite tariff increases, 45% of projected
investments were not implemented in the first three years of the
concession. The concession agreement was subsequently renegotiated
so that little remained of the initial covenant. In September
2005 Aguas Argentinas' private shareholders decided to terminate
the 30-year contract.[181]
18. The only form of finance uniquely available
to the private sector is equity finance from private shareholders.
All the other funding sources such as finance from donors, development
banks, commercial bank loans, bonds and operating surpluses are,
in principle, equally available to public and private sector operators.[182]
19. Meanwhile, it costs the private sector
more than the public sector to borrow the same amount. Companies
have to pay higher interest rates than the public sector when
they borrow from the markets, because their credit ratings are
worse than governmentsand even low income developing country
governments can access finance at favourable terms from development
banks.[183]
20. Private companies have not helped reduce
government borrowing and risk by taking on the burden of making
investments to connect new communities to the water network. Privatisations
that do deliver investment to connect new communities depend upon
public finance, donor finance or government guarantees.
21. In Senegal, the privatisation (lease)
contract is frequently quoted as a success story, with a substantial
increase in the number of connections35% from 1996 to 2001.
However, these new connections were not financed by or through
the private company, but largely through the public water authority.
The leap in new connections came after 1999, when a new injection
of public financeincluding a World Bank loanwas
provided through the public water authority.[184]
22. As the Head of SAUR, one of the major
French water multinationals, said in 2002, "Substantial grants
and soft loans are unavoidable to meet required investment levels
[This entails] the considerable dependence of the growth of the
water sector in the developing world on soft funding and subsidies.
If it does not happen the international water companies will be
forced to stay at home."[185]
23. All of this evidence illustrates that
it is an illusion to think that private companies either have
in the past, or will in the future, be able to finance the massive
investment required to connect new communities to water networks.
24. This emphasis on the private sector
has had negative impacts on poor people without water around the
world. Putting private companies in the driving seat in recent
years has allowed them to set the agenda in terms of prioritising
the continents, regions and cities where investment in the water
sector should go. Because of their need to make a profit, companies
and donor-funded investment have not concentrated on the areas
of greatest need: cities where the poorest live and rural areas.[186]
25. For example, Latin America includes
a number of middle income countries, and contains a relatively
small proportion of the population who need to be connected in
order to achieve the MDGs (9%). The region has nevertheless been
the target of most of the investment by the water multinationals,
clearly because of its relative profitability. Many of these concessions
are now terminated or in crisis, either as a result of popular
opposition, or as a result of economic crisis (as in Argentina)
or both.[187]
26. Meanwhile, the zero new connections
in South Asia from private investment is the most dramatic illustration
of how corporate decisions on where to operate are based on commercial
judgments which may bear no relation to the relative needs of
populations.[188]
27. Companies themselves have admitted this
trend too. For example, in a water policy meeting in Uganda in
2001, staff from the French multinational Vivendi (now called
Veolia) stated that the need to make reasonable profit means they
only invest in the larger, richer cities.[189]
28. In order to meet their profit needs,
private companies operating privatisation contracts have resorted
to tactics in developing countries which are no longer acceptable
in the UK such as pre-pay water meters, massive price rises and
disconnections for failure to pay. In South Africa, UK water company
Biwater's Nelspruit concession depended heavily on generating
a surplus through increased water charges, based on (non pre-pay)
metering of households and full cost recovery. Many households
could not afford the new tariffs, and payment levels were considerably
lower than the company expected. Strict enforcement was attempted:
"After warnings, water was cut off, but restored if payment
(or part payment) was made. Persistent non-payment led to the
removal of pipe work" and disconnections for non-payment
continued even during the cholera epidemic of 2000.[190]
THE ROLE
OF DONORS
IN PUSHING
WATER PRIVATISATION
29. Donors such as the World Bank and International
Monetary Fund have been instrumental in pushing the concept of
water privatisation in developing countries. To receive cheap
loans and debt relief, demands are made that poor countries reduce
their public sector expenditure, while loans and aid to the water
sector specify that they will only be given if a privatisation
occurs.
30. In March 2005, the UK Government's Department
for International Development (DFID) published a new policy on
conditionality which stated that economic policy conditions would
no longer be attached to its aid programme.[191]
WDM and others welcomed this new policy; it was something that
we had been calling for, for years. However, in and of itself,
this policy has not put a complete stop to the UK government pushing
water privatisation in developing countries.
31. 12% of UK aid is channelled through
the World Bank which continues to attach economic policy conditions,
such as water privatisation, to its lending. In addition, the
UK aid budget continues to pay for policy advice and technical
assistance on water privatisations in developing countries, even
where that policy had emerged after the World Bank or IMF had
attached it as a condition for support.
32. This is the case in Sierra Leone where
in June 2005, DFID started to recruit consultants to work with
the Sierra Leonean National Commission for Privatisation to privatise
24 state-owned enterprises (including Freetown's water provider).
While the civil war was still being fought in that country in
1999, the IMF was first recommending privatisation: "In the
area of public enterprises... a program for future reforms, including
privatization, in the sector will be elaborated in collaboration
with the World Bank".[192]
33. The UK government (and the World Bank)
also have a history of funding public relations initiatives to
pacify sceptical populations in developing countries, who are
often unwilling to see their water services privatised. The consultancy
firm Adam Smith International (ASI) received £270,000 of
UK aid money in 1999 to produce a PR campaign in Tanzania involving
the use of a national comedian in a series of TV adverts as well
as a pop videoall promoting the country's privatisation
programme.[193]
The pop video had the following lyrics: "Young plants need
rain, businesses need investment. Our old industries are like
dry crops and privatisation brings the rain. When the harvest
comes, there is plenty for everyone."
34. More generally, ASI notes that it has
the ability to "help muster the critical political support
necessary to carry policies through to their successful conclusion".[194]
It has built up a reputation as the consultant that "sells"
privatisation to an unwilling population. In Ghana, DfID funded
a "public awareness raising programme" about the benefits
of privatisation.[195]
In India ASI was given aid money to produce a film about the benefits
of privatisation.[196]
35. The expectation of private sector investment
has not only failed to deliver what was claimed. Coupled with
IMF demands for reductions in state spending and borrowing, and
policies of development banks and donors to insist on attracting
private finance, it also has had the effect of reducing public
sector investment in infrastructure, including water. This has
happened because many countries have chosen to cut investment
to meet the targets for lower spending and borrowing, in the expectation
that the private sector would replace it.[197]
36. The international financial institutions
and donors have also cut their own expenditure, with similar expectations
that the private sector would take over. The total invested by
all the development banks and donors in infrastructure (including
water) fell by one third between 1996 and 2002.[198]
A World Bank paper concludes: "Ultimately, many of the adjustments
in public financing and overseas development assistance largely
reflect the fact that the expectations of private sector participation
in the financing of infrastructure needs were overoptimistic."[199]
37. The World Bank, according to its infrastructure
review paper in 2003 cut its infrastructure investment (in all
sectors including water) lending by 50% between 1993 and 2002,
from about US$9.5 billion to US$4.8 billion.[200]
The report notes that the reasons for this include: "a lack
of clarity on the roles of the private and public sector in infrastructure
service provision and under-investment in country-level infrastructure
diagnostic work". It noted that, contrary to the World Bank's
expectations, the private sector's investment (in all infrastructure,
not only water) also declined by over 50% between 1997 and 2002,
and concluded that "the recent decreases in private sector
interest in infrastructure show that reliance on the private sector
alone will not be sufficient to guarantee a scaling-up of infrastructure
service provision".[201]
38. The same effect can be seen in the donor
policies of the EU, which in 2002 set up a new EU Water Initiative,
and proposed a new EU water fund, to support the MDGs. By the
end of 2005, a WaterAid/Tearfund review concluded that "Not
a single extra person has received safe water or sanitation through
the Initiative. Separate but linked efforts to increase funding
for water and sanitation through the EU Water Facility (EUWF)
have similarly failed". The review also identified as one
key reason why these initiatives had failed was because of an
"ideological bias to private finance", seeing the main
function of aid as `leveraging' private finance.[202]
39. The focus on private sector development
has contributed to a reduction in the level of aid and development
finance from donors for the water and sanitation sector which
is far greater than the actual investments made by the private
sector. It is not possible to produce a single figure for this,
but it is possible to say that the net contribution of 15 years
of privatisation has been to significantly reduce the finance
available to developing countries for investment in water.
WHERE NEXT
FOR THE
WATER SECTOR?
40. Where does all this evidence about the
failure of water privatisations to make significant progress towards
the MDG leave us? Surely the question that needs to be asked is
not "how to get the private sector into the water sector"
but instead "what is the best way to improve water services".
41. There are a number of successful models
of water utilities in developing countries which are in public
hands but which are successfully connecting new communities to
the water network. Perhaps one of the most well-known examples
is that of Porto Alegre in Brazil. In 1961, the city council created
a water and sanitation provider that, while remaining wholly owned
by the municipality, had a separate legal personality, operational
autonomy and financial independence.[203]
It is subject to the municipality's `participatory budgeting'
processwhere citizens play an active role in taking decisions
on how local finances are usedand also subject to public
scrutiny through a "deliberative council".[204]
42. Even though Porto Alegre nearly doubled
in size from some 700,000 inhabitants in 1961 to 1,360,000 in
2001, the water provider has managed to extend service coverage
and improve quality. By 2001, it provided water supply to 99.5%
of the population, an increase from the 95% supplied in 1990.
Similarly, by 2001, sewerage services had been extended to 84%
of households, up from 70% in 1990.[205]
Now Porto Alegre has an infant death rate of 14 per thousand in
comparison with a national average of 65. And by 1999 the city's
`human development index' was 0.79, comparable with a typical
0.80 for cities in the industrialised world.[206]
43. Porto Alegre is a fine example of a
successful public provider which responds to the needs of the
people and which has been able to extend the number of connections.
Interestingly, it also illustrates the role that the private sector
can usefully play in water and sanitation provision. Porto Alegre's
water operation uses subcontracting, including employing Suez
subsidiaries on specific construction jobs when they have won
competitive tenders.[207]
44. Indeed, there is a long tradition of
public utilities subcontracting to the private sector in many
countries and the private sector can be tapped for building up
the management, financial and operational capacity of public services,
especially in urban areas. Procurement contracts in other countries
have included computer services, engineering works and repair,
maintenance and rehabilitation of a network. However, in such
cases, the control remains outside of the private sector's handsand
the arguments against privatisation do not apply.[208]
CONCLUSIONS
45. To conclude, as this submission has
demonstrated, there is a role for the private sector in the delivery
of water and sanitation services. However, it is a limited one
and it should not involve private sector control or management
of water services. Indeed, there has been a wholesale failure
of water privatisations to extend water and sanitation networks
to those who currently lack access in the areas where the need
is greatest.
46. Moreover, the expectation that the private
sector could deliver has led donors and governments to substantially
reduce their overall funding for the sector. There is a massive
funding gap in the sector which donors and governments must urgently
address if we are to meet the MDG on water, with its knock on
impacts on achieving other MDGs. Critically, there is a need to
dispel the myth that the private sector will deliver the MDG for
us and there must be a complete halt to economic policy conditions
which demand water privatisations. The UK government should stop
supporting water privatisations that stem from such conditions,
stop funding pro-privatisation PR campaigns, and work with international
donors to make up the funding gap which results from years of
misplaced faith in the private sector.
47. As former British Environment Minister
Michael Meacher has noted: "Private sector finance will certainly
be important, but it will generally not be used for basic services
private sector investment is at present insignificant at providing
basic water and sanitation services to the very people who most
need it."[209]
February 2006
168 This report will be published in March 2006 and
will sent to the Committee. Back
169
Vandemoortele, J (2003). Are the MDGs feasible?. New York.
United Nations Development Programme. July 2003. http://www.undp.org/mdg/Are%20the%20MDGs%20feasible.doc Back
170
Rt Hon. Clare Short MP (2002). Debate on International Trade.
House of Commons Hansard. 19/06/02: Column 297. Back
171
Gee, A. (2004). Competition and the Water Sector. EC Competition
Policy Newsletter No.2. Brussels. Summer 2004. http://europa.eu.int/comm/competition/publications/cpn/cpn2004_2.pdf Back
172
Estache, A. and Rossi, M. (2002). How different is the efficiency
of public and private water companies in Asia? The World Bank
Economic Review Vol. 16 No. 1. Oxford University Press. Oxford.
June 2002. Back
173
Renzetti, S. & Dupont, D. (2004). Ownership and Performance
of Water Utilities. Sheffield. Greenleaf Publishing http://www.greenleaf-publishing.com/ Back
174
Shofiani, NE (2003). Reconstruction of Indonesia's Drinking Water
Utilities-Assessment and stakeholders' perspective of private
sector participation in the capital province of Jakarta. TRITA-LWR
Master Thesis LWR-EX-03-30. Back
175
Hall, D and Lobina, E (2006). Pipe dreams: The failure of the
private sector to invest in water services in developing countries.
WDM, PSIRU and Public Services International. London. Forthcoming
March 2006. Back
176
Zimbabwe Independent 10/12/99. Taken from Hall, D, Bayliss, K,
Lobina, E (2002). Water Privatisation in Africa. Public
Services International Research Unit. London. June 2002. Back
177
The Right to Water Campaign, Council of Canadians, http://www.blueplanetproject.net/cms_publications/RTW%20handbill.pdf Back
178
Hall, D and Lobina, E (2006). Pipe dreams: The failure of the
private sector to invest in water services in developing countries.
WDM, PSIRU and Public Services International. London. Forthcoming
March 2006. Back
179
Hall, D and Lobina, E (2006). Pipe dreams: The failure
of the private sector to invest in water services in developing
countries. WDM, PSIRU and Public Services International. London.
Forthcoming March 2006. Back
180
Hall, D and Lobina, E (2006). Pipe dreams: The failure of the
private sector to invest in water services in developing countries.
WDM, PSIRU and Public Services International. London. Forthcoming
March 2006. Back
181
Hall, D and Lobina, E. (2006) Pipe dreams: The failure of the
private sector to invest in water services in developing countries.
WDM, PSIRU and Public Services International. London. Forthcoming
March 2006. Back
182
Hall, D and Lobina, E (2006). Pipe dreams: The failure of the
private sector to invest in water services in developing countries.
WDM, PSIRU and Public Services International. London. Forthcoming
March 2006. Back
183
Klein, M (1996). Risk, taxpayers, and the role of government
in project finance. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No.1688.
New York, World Bank. Note: the author recognises that government
borrowing is cheaper but argues that, in an ideal world, it should
not be because taxpayers should be compensated for the risk they
are being forced to take. As far as WDM is aware, the reality
remains that government borrowing is cheaper. Back
184
Tremolet, S (2002). Rural Water Service. Public Policy
for the Private Sector. Note Number 249. Back
185
Talbot, JF (2002). Is the International Water Business Really
a Business? World Bank Water and Sanitation Lecture Series. 13/02/02.
http://www.worldbank.org/wbi/B-SPAN/docs/SAUR.pdf Back
186
WDM. (2005). Dirty Aid, Dirty Water: The UK Government's push
to privatise water and sanitation in poor countries. World Development
Movement. London. February 2005. Back
187
Hall, D and Lobina, E (2006). Pipe dreams: The failure of the
private sector to invest in water services in developing countries.
WDM, PSIRU and Public Services International. London. Forthcoming
March 2006. Back
188
Hall, D and Lobina, E (2006). Pipe dreams: The failure of the
private sector to invest in water services in developing countries.
WDM, PSIRU and Public Services International. London. Forthcoming
March 2006. Back
189
Kessler, T (2004). Who's taking risks: How the World Bank pushes
private infrastructure-and finds resistance in some surprising
places. Citizens Network on Essential Services. July 2004. Back
190
Water Service Subsidies and the Poor: a Case Study of Greater
Nelspruit Utility Company, Mbombela Municipality, South Africa.
Julia Brown. 2005 http://www.competition-regulation.org.uk/conferences/mcr05/brownwoodhouse.pdf Back
191
DFID (2005). Partnerships for poverty reduction: rethinking conditionality.
A UK government policy paper. London. March 2005. Back
192
WDM. (2005). Sierra Leone's privatisation timeline http://www.wdm.org.uk/campaigns/aid/sierraleone/timeline.htm Back
193
Watt, P (2004). Whose reform is it anyway? How development aid
is driving water privatisation in the world's poorest countries.
Tribune. London. 30 January 2004. Back
194
http://www.adamsmithinternational.com/services_eur_psp.html (Viewed
on 14 January 2005). Back
195
Martey, E (2001). The Ghana Experience: Initiating and managing
the reform process in the water sector. Vol II, Papers and Presentations,
Reform of the Water Supply & Sanitation Sector in Africa.
County Report: The Political Economy of Water Sector Reform study.
http://www.wsp.org/events_archive/v2_ghana.pdf Back
196
DfID. (2004). Procurement contracts 1997-2004. Obtained
by WDM from DfID through the Code of Practice on Access to Government
Information. Received 19 October 2004. Back
197
Hall, D and Lobina, E (2006). Pipe dreams: The failure of the
private sector to invest in water services in developing countries.
WDM, PSIRU and Public Services International. London. Forthcoming
March 2006. Back
198
Hall, D and Lobina, E (2006). Pipe dreams: The failure of the
private sector to invest in water services in developing countries.
WDM, PSIRU and Public Services International. London. Forthcoming
March 2006. Back
199
Bricen¥o-Garmendia, Estache, Shafik: Infrastructure Services
in Developing Countries: Access, Quality, Costs and Policy Reform.
World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3468, December 2004. Back
200
World Bank: Infrastructure Action Plan. 2003. http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTTRM/Resources/InfrastructureActionPlan.pdf Back
201
IBRD and IDA lending: finance through the IFC and MIGA increased. Back
202
An Empty Glass: The EU Water Initiative's contribution to the
water and sanitation Millennium targets. WaterAid and Tearfund.
December 2005. Back
203
Hall, D Lobina, E, Viero O-M, Maltz, H (2002). Water in Porto
Alegre, Brazil-accountable, effective, sustainable and democratic.
London. Public Services International Research Unit. Back
204
Maltz, H (2005). Porto Alegre's Water: Public and for All. In
Hoedman, O (ed) (2005). Back
205
Hall, D, Lobina, E, Viero O-M, Maltz, H. (2002). Water in Porto
Alegre, Brazil-accountable, effective, sustainable and democratic.
London. Public Services International Research Unit. Back
206
Hall, D Lobina, E, Viero O-M, Maltz, H. (2002). Water in Porto
Alegre, Brazil-accountable, effective, sustainable and democratic.
London. Public Services International Research Unit. Back
207
World Development Movement (2005). Dirty Aid, Dirty Water.
A policy report. London. February 2005. Back
208
World Development Movement (2005). Dirty Aid, Dirty Water.
A policy report. London. February 2005. Back
209
Meacher, M (2001). Keynote speech delivered at International
Conference on Freshwater, Bonn, Germany. 04 December 2001. Back
|