Select Committee on International Development Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 100 - 119)

THURSDAY 27 APRIL 2006

PROFESSOR PAUL COLLIER

  Q100  Ann McKechin: Your theories seem to stress that there is a strong link between levels of growth and per capita income as a determinant of the likelihood of conflict. What do you believe to be the implications in terms of donor policies? Some may say that this is an interesting theory but it may not necessarily apply in every single situation that a donor comes across?

  Professor Collier: Nothing in social science applies in every single situation. One could talk about propensities but it would be crazy to say that it applied everywhere. It is a pretty good guide to general policy lessons, but it is not the only one. One must always know the particular circumstances. I should emphasise that the relationship between income and especially growth and the risk of conflict is not just a theory; it is as good as we can establish empirically. The link between growth and conflict risk is not just my work; there is some very distinguished studies by other people. The top article in the top economics journal in the world established rigorously a link between growth and lower risk of conflict, so it is as good as we know. Doubtless there will be exceptions as you say, but it is there. It is not theory; it is as robust a relationship in social science as we can reasonably get.

  Q101  Ann McKechin: In effect, it would be a risk assessment strategy?

  Professor Collier: Yes. The implication of it is that economic development will be a major component of any longer-term strategy to reduce the global incidence of civil conflict. Without economic development other strategies look very difficult. They are working on the margins, whereas with economic development one can basically get away with a lot of poor governance.

  Q102  Chairman: You said that resources could fuel a rebellion. If one takes a poor country like Malawi which does not have any resources or economic growth, nobody suggests that that country is about to burst into civil war. There is the counter-argument, is there not, that if one does not have any resources or money one is less likely to have conflict? That is not a very encouraging one for the people.

  Professor Collier: Basically, there are three economic components of risk: low income, low growth and natural resources. If one comes up with all three cherries one is in trouble. Malawi has two out of three, so there is still a risk. Cote d'Ivoire managed to get two out of three and look what happened. It had peace for a long time. Nobody in 1990 would have said that that was a country at risk. Africa is distinct in its endowments, not its risks, but a lot of it has all three cherries: low income, economic decline and richness in resources. The resource richness is becoming more important as one has more and more discoveries in these fragile states and a price boom.

  Q103  Ann McKechin: You say that economic development in relation to income can be a high risk. I take it from that you say it must be directly related to employment?

  Professor Collier: You misheard. I am saying that economic development and growth will bring down risks.

  Q104  Ann McKechin: Provided it is linked to employment, because in some cases it is not?

  Professor Collier: The presumption should be that growth will reduce risks. That is the normal relationship. Therefore, normally if there is growth it is good news; it will promote peace. Can one think of ways in which one gets growth that does not help? Of course one can. Take Equatorial Guinea and Chad. Oil is discovered and the Government wants to spend the money on the army. It shows up in the figures for GDP because oil will be a big part of it but it does not do any good.

  Q105  Ann McKechin: But there is a link between economic growth on the one hand and employment on the other. The third factor which you mentioned earlier is the question of taxable income streams collected by governments. It is the correlation between those three factors which is essential to avoid conflict, not just economic growth and nothing else?

  Professor Collier: Undoubtedly. I am not saying that it is economic growth and nothing else. I am saying that there is a presumption that economic growth is good for peace and is peace-promoting, unless there is a form of economic growth which is pretty weird. One comes across cases of pretty weird growth and I have given the two current examples of Equatorial Guinea and Chad. The growth statistics show that the economy is growing, but nothing is happening on the ground except that oil is coming out of it.

  Q106  Ann McKechin: One can say the same of the Middle East where there is a lot of economic growth but high unemployment and a high risk of strife?

  Professor Collier: That is right. It is the non-oil economy that must benefit in some way. The most likely mechanism as you suggest is the labour market. I do not disagree with that, but I do not want to get away from the fact that the normal presumption is that growth is beneficial for peace.

  Q107  Richard Burden: The word "inequality" has not entered your vocabulary so far. Whilst there is evidence that high levels of growth can reduce inequality, do you think that inequality is a relevant factor in all this?

  Professor Collier: It seems to be much less important than I expected. When I started all this work seven or eight years ago I thought that what would leap off the page was the idea that inequality caused conflict. It does not. Statistically, it is not a very strong factor. I would like to tell you—it would make a lot of sense—that if you reduced inequality you would get rid of the problem. It is just not there in the data. There is some evidence that where there is a lot of inequality once a conflict begins it goes on for longer. In my view, the factors that are over-emphasised in conflict resolution are inequality and elections, and the matter which is under-emphasised is basically economic development, which may emerge as jobs, but the political fixes through elections do not seem to reduce the risks of conflict. We have a lot of examples of conflict in very equal societies and examples of the absence of conflict in some extremely unequal ones.

  Q108  Ann McKechin: What would be an example of a very equal society?

  Professor Collier: Sri Lanka is one of the most equal societies around.

  Mr Singh: The Tamils do not think so.

  Professor Collier: It is economically equal. If you look at income distribution in Sri Lanka it is very equal compared with most other places. One of the factors that has sustained the conflict in Sri Lanka is external finance from the Tamil diaspora, not from natural resources. We know that the Tamil diaspora has been massively funding the Tamil Tigers. For example, the bomb in Colombo that killed and injured 1,400 people was traced back to finance from the Tamils in Canada. There is currently a move within the European community to try to get the Tamil Tigers declared a terrorist organisation, and I think we should do that. The diaspora financing statistically seems to be one of the factors that makes countries more prone to conflict. We should discipline the diasporas to try to curb that financing.

  Chairman: On the issue of resources, we have looked at the Kimberley process and extendibility. Mr Singh has a couple of questions on that matter.

  Q109  Mr Singh: I think that others will ask questions on the issue of grievance and rebel movements. One of the matters you identified in the strategies to reduce the risk or try to stop conflict was the squeezing of the resources available to rebel movements. I think that you see the Kimberley process as a model of international action. I know that that process is to be reviewed after three years, but in your view has that process been an unqualified success to date, or does it have problems?

  Professor Collier: I think that the whole tension around conflict diamonds produced results and helped to squeeze UNITA. I have seen interviews with the top UNITA leadership that describe how basically it started to run out of money and guns in the closing years. By the time it was defeated it was starving, and that was a transformation from a few years earlier. In the run-up to Kimberley one had much greater scrutiny which helped to make a big difference. De Beers, which had been saying that there was no problem and it had nothing to do with it, withdrew from the diamond market. That was a massive switch in its policy. That killed rebel access. It is not just the moment that Kimberley starts; it is the build-up to it. In my view Kimberley is getting better as time goes on. The next technology in Kimberley, as I understand it, is the use of smartcards for miners in alluvial diamond areas which can do a lot to track the source of diamonds within a very small area. New technology is making feasible a lot of things that were not in the original Kimberley agreement. I am very hopeful. It is a model of what can be done in timber, perhaps even in oil. Oil-bunkering, as it is called, in the delta region of Nigeria involved rebel groups stealing a lot of oil from the pipelines and selling it. Trace elements in the oil can make it much harder to sell it, if there is proper certification and scrutiny. The object is not to make it unsaleable but to create a deep discount in the price at which rebels can sell it.

  Q110  Mr Singh: You are talking about legitimate and illegitimate products?

  Professor Collier: Yes. One is creating an illegal market for a product that is legitimate, and one differentiates the markets by some identifiable measure. In diamonds it would be the certification process; in oil it would be a trace element in the product; and in timber it would be an attempt to trace the source of the trees.

  Q111  Mr Singh: Could the process be made more effective by, for example, the United Nations applying sanctions to particular areas, for example Cote d'Ivoire, which are rebel-held to make sure that resources from those areas cannot be traded?

  Professor Collier: Yes. Sanctions go hand in hand with information that makes the sanctions enforceable.

  Q112  Mr Singh: Do sanctions work in this kind of area?

  Professor Collier: I think they can. One does not want them to get too far ahead of the technology that provides the information; otherwise, they are discredited, but the technology that provides the information really is advancing, so these measures are becoming much more feasible.

  Q113  John Battle: I want to ask about the role of rebel groups. It is almost trite to say that some rebels become the leaders of the country later. Therefore, there is not always clarity in motives. I spent some time today meeting people from Sierra Leone and listening to them at a very basic family level. If your argument is that part of the Kimberley process will lower the price that rebel groups rather than governments get for commodities, does it not assume that the rebels' grievances are not the real issue? The real issue is simply that they can get their hands on the dosh and worm their way into power and keep control. Therefore, there is a dichotomy between rebels and government but once they become government their motives are not the same?

  Professor Collier: I believe that it is very dangerous to go down the route of saying that rebels and governments are equal. In most developing societies lots of people have legitimate grievances against governments. Most of them by our standards are pretty poor, rough governments, so there are a lot of legitimate grievances. Usually, these legitimate grievances do not translate into armed violence, but sometimes they do. Basically, armed violence does not appear to be closely related to the level of legitimate grievance. There is always a strong case for addressing legitimate grievance. There is no evidence that armed violence promotes the redress of grievances; on the contrary, the legacy of armed conflict is far deeper problems than one starts with. Even where one has legitimate grievances and the rebels are addressing them, which is a big assumption because usually the rebels are no better than the government, it is a lousy way to do it because the cost of the violence far exceeds the usual redress.

  Q114  John Battle: As I have been listening to you I have heard a completely counter-argument. As part of my background I have been heavily involved in Northern Ireland and the conversation has been quietly in the background. I have been listening to what you say within that template. For example, one has Boston funding the IRA and its move into drugs and the rest of it. A lot of my time was spent making comments on the ground in West Belfast to the effect that perhaps it was better to get round the table and talk about the weather than kill each other in the street, including relatives and friends in the post office down the road. Provided they are sitting round a table having a conversation they are not out on the streets shooting people. Therefore, the aim is to try to get a conversation going to end the conflict, because in my experience once people go down the road of armed conflict to get them back to conversation is the most difficult of political tasks. I just wonder what would be the overriding objectives if we wanted to reduce and eliminate conflict, because it might mean compromise. To pretend that rebels and governments are equal forces and should even be respected equally, or to say there is a moral equivalence between them, might not be appropriate, but in the practical world of politics it might be important to get them round the table and listen to the rebels and understand that sometimes their grievances are not actual but perceived grievances which still need to be dealt with?

  Professor Collier: One would want to make a distinction, in that where a rebellion is going on as a practical matter one has to try to deal with the rebel group to get peace. That is a massively difficult thing to do for a variety of reasons. One is that the rebel group becomes an organisation that gets used to conflict. It knows how to swim in conflict and peace becomes some sort of mythical thing with which it is not very comfortable. When the FARC finally met the Colombian Government a few years ago the Government said, "This is a private meeting. What do you want?" The FARC leaders did not know what they wanted; for years they had been used to fighting. The major reason why it is very difficult to achieve peace is that once peace is arrived at governments become progressively more powerful relative to rebels. Rebel forces disintegrate during peace. Therefore, governments have an incentive to promise the movement and then renege on it. Because rebels know that one cannot get peace in the first place. The rebels will not be duped into peace. There is no offer the government can make that is credible. External actors like ourselves have a role in trying to guarantee peace settlements.

  Q115  John Battle: Does that include listening to the rebels, or someone engaging with them?

  Professor Collier: Of course it does. Once one has a rebel group, no matter how awful it is, it must be given an interest in peace, which means that sometimes it has to be literally bribed into peace. RENAMO[4] in Mozambique was bribed into peace because Italian aid agencies were sufficiently cavalier in their accounting that money could be diverted into setting up the leadership of that organisation. For the best of reasons DFID could not have done that.


  Q116  John Bercow: A few moments ago you said that in your judgment there was fairly conclusive evidence that the use of violence did not result in the redress of grievances. It does not follow from that statement, even if it is true, that the non-use of violence by aggrieved persons, whether as a result of a calculated choice not to deploy it or because of an insufficiency of weaponry or numbers of troops to do so, would achieve any better result. In other words, whether there is use or non-use of violence the grievances might not be redressed. What is the significance in that sense of a multilateral intervention from outside, if that takes place; or do you suggest that the use of rebel violence is more likely than not to discourage an external actor from becoming involved? In the event of such intervention is it more likely than not that not merely will one achieve peace but that the government whose behaviour has caused the violence and multilateral intervention will be prepared to come to an agreement which at least in part resolves those grievances?

  Professor Collier: I caution you against assuming government behaviour which has caused the violence. In these low-income and low-growth but resource-rich societies sometimes, no matter what the government does, the opportunities for violence are so great that one will have violence. In southern Sudan a terrible government has bought peace with the SPLA[5]. There are 30 armed groups in southern Sudan. It is so easy to be an armed group in southern Sudan, and with oil coming out it will be so profitable to be an armed group. It is a desperate situation. There are some environments in which even with good governance the opportunities for violence are just too great. You ask about the scope for external intervention. "Intervention" is a broad word. Of course, in these environments one has struggles. One has brave local heroes, for example John Githongo in Kenya, who are peacefully sustaining a force for reform, and it is our proper business to do everything we can to strengthen their position. Usually, that will be non-military. Our opportunity for military intervention is post-conflict or in the very late stages of conflict. Our intervention in Sierra Leone both to establish and guarantee was absolutely brilliant. In my view, that is the future. I just hope that the difficulties in Iraq will not lead us to learn the wrong lesson, just as the difficulties in Somalia led to the wrong lesson—not to intervene—which produced Rwanda within a year. If we draw the lesson from Iraq that we should never intervene we will have another Rwanda.


  Q117  John Bercow: In your experience, is the presence or absence of television cameras during a conflict a relevant variable which points conclusively in one direction or another in terms of the likelihood of conflict being resolved and grievances redressed, or is the picture too varied and unpredictable to allow a conclusion to be drawn?

  Professor Collier: I have not studied it statistically. It probably cuts both ways. Clearly, there are situations in which the presence of the external media disciplines government behaviour. We must also not forget that the media are used by rebel groups to try to stimulate their own financing. One notices that all of the public relations of a lot of rebel groups is done in English. The audience of the rebels is us, not their own people, because they are appealing to a diaspora which harbours ancient grievances. Diasporas tend to be less forgiving than the local population. Quite often the local population comes to a modus vivendi, whereas the diasporas just want vengeance for some real or imagined past slight.

  Q118  Chairman: Does it imply that the Department for International Development should reconsider some of its policies? Some of us went to Uganda. I think of a meeting that Quentin Davies and I had with the Prime Minister of Uganda. There is an unresolved conflict and general belief that it suits the Prime Minister of Uganda to keep it unresolved, and yet we are providing direct support to him and his state. We are giving his Government support; the international community is providing policing and medical aid in northern Uganda. I think that Quentin Davies will confirm that when he and I met the Prime Minister and asked about the relationship with the Democratic Republic of the Congo (DRC) he sneered contemptuously and said that that was not a serious country and Uganda had every right to pursue anybody it wanted as far as it liked. As you know, reparations have been awarded but I imagine they will never be paid. The question is: is it right for our own Department to continue to provide support to Uganda which is not fulfilling its responsibilities in the north even though it has jurisdiction there and is effectively freely invading its neighbour?

  Professor Collier: I think that in a lot of these countries it is legitimate for us to try to influence both the level of military spending and the conduct of the governments. One simple reason for that is that we are financing a lot of African military spending. On average about 11% of aid leaks into military spending. When one adds that up it means that in Africa about 40% of its military spending is inadvertently financed by aid. What is more, unfortunately aid seems to increase the risk of a coup d'etat. That is the honey pot effect. Aid is a little like a natural resource. The greater the aid the bigger the incentive for armies to try to capture power. In response to the high risk of a coup d'etat governments tend to spend more on the military to try to buy it off; they buy off the military in part with our money because we are financing so much of it. Therefore, it is entirely legitimate that we try to place demands on governments in the areas of security, behaviour and military spending. In the particular case of Uganda the history is more complicated because for years Sudan has financed the Lord's Resistance Army (LRA). It is hard to see the LRA as other than a deeply warped phenomenon and it is not easy to negotiate a peace arrangement with it. The south sent a clergyman to negotiate and the LRA killed him, so negotiation is not easy.

  Q119  Richard Burden: If we can go back to Sierra Leone for a minute, one problem is the large number of unemployed youth which is closely related to instances of conflict. Reading your analysis, is it right that you attribute to that unemployed youth, who arguably do not have very much, the motivation of greed?

  Professor Collier: No. I see them more like cannon fodder. My advice is that we should not get too hung up on motivation. Most of these phenomena have very complex patterns of motivation: grievances, lunacy, the allure and glamour of violence and the frustration of desperate circumstances. The cocktail of motivations is very complicated. As implied by the question, when one has a lot of unemployed youth with no hope what does one expect? One wants to try to create jobs for those people and kick-start the economy in these post-conflict situations. Unfortunately, economic recovery takes time to deliver significant effects. It will take a decade to rebuild an economy and the risks are the here and now. That is one major reason why one needs an external military presence for quite a long time just to keep the lid on whilst one is rebuilding the economy and providing the jobs so there is less cannon fodder for opportunists to use.


4   Resistência Nacional Moc"ambicana (Mozambican National Resistance). Back

5   Sudan People's Liberation Army. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2006
Prepared 25 October 2006