Select Committee on International Development Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 220 - 239)

WEDNESDAY 10 MAY 2006

DR NEIL COOPER, PROFESSOR MIKE PUGH AND DR JONATHAN GOODHAND

  Q220  Chairman: In the context of Africa, do you think that the UK and the French Governments should work more closely together?

  Professor Pugh: My understanding is that one of the initiatives which occurred as a consequence of the Great Lakes crisis, in part anyway, was closer co-operation between the British and the French, and you could trace this co-operation through to Operation Artemis and the EU's sending of a force to Bunia, was it not, in Ituri province. That needs to be solidified and underpinned by an EU policy towards Africa. At this point, I might add that I think DFID is ahead of the game, in many respects, in its approaches to regionalism, and perhaps one of the practical things it could do is transform Hilary Benn's approach into a European-wide thing.

  Q221  Ann McKechin: Regional conflicts obviously are dominated by shadowy and survival economies, as you have stated in your research. The question is how do you turn that into what you propose, audited and taxable economic activity, which, to say the least, is easier said than done? Two specific examples spring to mind. One is Afghanistan, which you have mentioned previously, and also now the DRC, which is about to go through a period of elections and a permanent government. How do you think the UK Government should be acting to try to bring back a legitimate economy to these two areas?

  Dr Goodhand: I will talk a bit about Afghanistan. First of all, going back to first principles, I think one thing, in research we have been doing, is that state-building is the primary objective, if you are talking about durable peace in the country, and we have been critical of, initially at least, a minimalist approach to this, which was focusing basically on counter-insurgency, a minimalist version of a state, which was related basically to an exit strategy. There has been a lot of work which shows that US pragmatic alliances with local warlords, which is a kind of trade-off of financial support and military support for stability, actually are working against the longer-term project of state-building. That has changed in the last four years and I think there is more of a consensus now about the need to develop and support a fiscal contract, and taxation is at the heart of that. There are still a lot of tensions and trade-offs around doing this, because there is still a lot of short-term security imperatives around counter-terrorism, as opposed to the longer-term and much more difficult task of building capacity. There has been a tendency to import capacity rather than build it within the state. In the security sector there has been a greater emphasis on the counter-insurgency activity rather than reforming the sector as a whole. I think DFID has been much more enlightened than most other donors; it has supported the Afghan Reconstruction Trust Fund and it has gone for budget support for the Government. I think that is the way it should be going, but the two biggest donors—the Japanese and the US—have tended to circumvent the Government and have gone for intervention and implementation through contractors and NGOs.

  Q222  Ann McKechin: I can understand this with regard to the provision of public services, in terms of schools and hospitals and transport and government infrastructure, but we are talking here about economic activity, where we would expect this normally to come from the private sector. Unfortunately, in Afghanistan, the private sector is dominated by heroin production. Quite how do you think that DFID should target its policies so that we have legitimate private economic activity in Afghanistan?

  Dr Goodhand: First of all, obviously, there is no quick fix and actually eradication is destabilising, in terms of the Government. There is a question here about sequencing.

  Q223  Ann McKechin: It is very destabilising in terms of the products and what the end result is for thousands of people, so what is the balance between the two?

  Dr Goodhand: It is a question of sequencing and of timing. Eradication has led to an increased reaction against the Government, particularly in the south. In Nangarhar, although there was "a successful eradication" which led to something like 96% decline in planting for that year, this was done through pragmatic arrangements with local power-holders, which solidified their control, who are unlikely to want to relinquish that control. Also it did not lead to sufficient alternative livelihoods for communities on the ground. The quid pro quo has got to involve substantive alternatives, and this is not going to happen in a year or two years. I think the DFID strategy on this is the right one. Ultimately, the poppy is a low-risk crop in a high-risk environment, and unless you start changing those incentives at their different levels in the kind of combat economy which Neil was talking about, the shadow economy in terms of the interdiction of those who are trafficking and in terms of alternative livelihoods for farmers, those things are not going to happen through a magic bullet of eradication. Just to give you a sense of priorities here, the US has committed eleven times more funding overall to military operations than it has to humanitarian aid, reconstruction and training of the security sector combined. That gives you a sense of where priorities have been in relation to the overall project of state-building in Afghanistan. If you are serious about trying to address these incentives then serious resources have to be committed to it.

  Q224  Ann McKechin: In the meantime, many of those resources are still in the hands of warlords, so should we have tried simply to move on and actually disarm the warlords and take them out of the equation? What you are really saying is, in practice, we are going to have to negotiate as the Americans are negotiating with them and you are complaining about that, but, in effect, what you are saying, with a gradualist approach, is that we would have to deal with the warlords in terms of economic activity as well as their military capacity. Is that the way forward or, basically, should we have sought to keep them out of the equation?

  Dr Goodhand: I think one can argue there was an opportunity to do that in 2002, but that opportunity was missed, and they have strengthened their position subsequently and now it is a much more embedded, long-term problem which has to be dealt with as such. Whoever we are talking about in terms of "we", if we are talking about military forces on the ground, what they should not do, in my opinion, is get directly involved in eradication. What they can do is build up then and support the training and institutional development of the security forces, of the counter-narcotics agencies, to strengthen that role of the state, as well as combining it with significant reconstruction funding.

  Q225  Ann McKechin: It is a kind of parallel, carrot and stick approach?

  Dr Goodhand: Yes; absolutely.

  Q226  Ann McKechin: Do they ever make any comments about the DRC?

  Dr Cooper: Not particularly about the DRC but about this idea of how you bring the shadow economy into the legitimate economies so that you can start taxing and getting benefits from these activities. It seems to me that actually there are solutions out there, not perhaps in the case of Afghanistan, but in a lot of cases what you have got is people engaging in shadow economic activity, not because they are committed mafia members or committed warlords, but for purely simple, instrumental, practical reasons. It might be down to the kinship links, it might be down to the fact that the transport infrastructure is so appalling in your country and you are nearer to a border, so actually it is far more convenient simply to ship your stuff over to a relative on the other side of the border than it is to ship it all the way to the capital or to a local port, or somewhere like that. Similarly, a lot of the incentive for shadow economic activity may be around exploiting these differences in currency regimes, differences in tax regimes, differences in regulatory regimes. Again, if you can look at that and harmonise things from a regional perspective perhaps, but even a national perspective, look at what you can do to shift the balance of economic interest so that you create a set of incentives for people to make it more likely for people to come into the formal economy. One could go on ad infinitum, but one other thing which I think is worth mentioning, in which I think DFID, certainly in Sierra Leone, deserves a tick, is that a big factor, of course, is that, in post-conflict environments, people are not necessarily convinced that the peace is going to be durable. If you are not convinced that the peace is going to be durable then there is an incentive to keep your monies and your profits either out of the country altogether or well away from the eyes of government. Actually doing things like providing the "over the horizon" security guarantee, which DFID has in Sierra Leone, that kind of thing, in a small way, can contribute to promoting this longer-term perspective about the balance of economic behaviour that you engage in.

  Q227  Ann McKechin: In terms of Afghanistan, how many warlords are directly controlling what percentage of the economic activity in Afghanistan? It still gets to this question about, at the end of the day, the amount of heroin which is coming out and landing in the streets of constituencies such as mine and other parts of this country and causing incredible suffering and a lot of death, to be honest with you. It strikes me, is it a quicker solution, would it be better, if there were 10 warlords, saying simply, "Here's the money: go," or taking them out, or taking them to an international tribunal and calling them to account for their actions? Are they the key players or do we have large-scale mafia-type operations going on, that they will simply move from one activity to the next, or is there any possibility of actually taking them over and persuading them, the ones that are controlling interests of regions, to come into legal activity and engage in negotiation about it?

  Dr Goodhand: First of all, in terms of facts and figures and how many warlords, however we define that term, control what, we do not have that information. We know that roughly 2.7 billion was generated through poppy last year and that 52% of the GDP is from the opium economy. The problem is, it is embedded. The idea that this is a kind of cartel economy which is controlled by a few evil warlords is not what it is like; it is highly decentralised, it is footloose, it moves as control regimes change.

  Q228  Ann McKechin: If you take some out you get just more coming in?

  Dr Goodhand: Absolutely. There is not this notion of a good state, bad warlord, here. In some ways, there are some power-holders in the regions who are providing more public services, in terms of protection, and some public goods than the Government itself. This economy, it is not just warlords who would suffer if you took them out, so to speak, if it were possible, and if you could turn off the tap; the population relies very much on it. This goes back to the question of alternatives. The economy and people's livelihoods depend on the poppy economy, so you cannot just turn it off, because it is not possible, and because ethically there is a question around doing that and what effects it would have.

  Q229  Ann McKechin: The Taliban did it, I think?

  Dr Goodhand: Yes, the Taliban did it for one year, but it was not sustainable and it is not sustainable now. There was a brief decline last year; now in 13 provinces it is increasing, in 16 it is stable and in three it has gone down, so you are not going to get a sustainable decrease through eradication.

  Q230  Mr Singh: First of all, as a Bradford MP, can I say what a pleasure it is to have Bradford University down here and that the international renown of your Department especially brings much kudos to Bradford, so thank you for that. I have got a paper here by Dr Cooper, Peaceful warriors and warring peacemakers, and in it there is a paragraph, a crucial paragraph to me, where you say aid workers and peace workers restore the local political economy, create shadow economies, in terms of the sex trade, and in some cases promote conflict. That sounds like a terrible indictment of what we are doing. Should we be there at all?

  Dr Cooper: Yes, I think we should be there. What that is asking, I think, is that we are sensitive to the local impact that we have when the externals go in. Obviously I think now everybody is aware particularly of the issue of the sex trade and the issues which have arisen in a number of conflict zones, post-conflict zones, with peacekeeping forces and aid workers going in and actually availing themselves of that sex trade and, in a sense, almost creating a market in it, where it might not even have existed before. Part of that is being sensitive to the economic repercussions of what aid is doing in a post-conflict society and to think through those actions. Obviously, in terms of the sex trade, for instance, part of what you do is try to educate the people who are going into those zones and try to put into place policies which actually discourage people from engaging in those kinds of practices.

  Q231  Mr Singh: When you say that in some cases intervention may even contribute and promote conflict, what kind of example do you have?

  Dr Cooper: In a sense that often you can find that aid may be siphoned off by local warlords and mafia groups, it may be taxed, for instance, so the aid itself may become part and parcel of the political economy of war-making, as opposed to peace-making. I think many aid agencies now are pretty aware of this and a lot of them are involved daily in a kind of balancing act between trying to assess how much of the aid is getting siphoned off to the local warlord, or how much of the aid being taxed is it worth to accept for the benefit of actually getting aid through to people who need it and deserve it. That is obviously a very difficult decision to make, but it is one which the aid community needs constantly to bear in mind.

  Q232  Mr Singh: This particular paragraph certainly has punctured my impression of how worthy we are when we know that actually we might be doing more harm than good sometimes. A more general question: you argue that regional borderlands are crucial in sustaining conflict; can they play a role in promoting peace? Presumably, borderlands are important in the shadow economy as well; in what context could they play a role in promoting peace?

  Professor Pugh: A good proportion of the world's production actually comes from offshore and tax haven type economies and it seems to me, for example, that in some circumstances, in some places, you could have entrepo®t zones where production is encouraged which would bring two neighbouring countries together, or a trading system which created a free trade zone in that area; there are some half-dozen already in Bosnia, for example. That kind of role might be possible in some circumstances. I am not suggesting in all. The trading links which are developed in these borderlands could be harnessed by the state, or states, if there was a borderlands policy. I think the problem is that the international economic institutions, financial institutions and the donors have this tendency to centralise the donations and economic policy, which actually further marginalises the borderlands, because if it is in the case of loans they want loans repaid, therefore they want a central bank, and so on and so forth. There is that happening. At the same time, economic policies are being introduced which actually will weaken people's identity with the state and weaken social cohesion, and that impacts particularly on the borderlands, I think. It is reaching towards a profound issue which relates not only to your question but to the previous question, and that is the nature of economic policy which is introduced from outside. If the economic policy which is introduced from outside actually makes things worse for poor people, because poor people are dependent on public provision, or public space, and that public space and provision are privatised, for example, then they are more likely to suffer as a consequence and therefore are not going to get weaned away from survival in the shadow economy. There was a riot, a couple of years ago, in Banja Luka, when the authorities tried to close down the black market which was engaged in trading, because people depended on that so heavily. If the state is not performing functions to displace the warlords in the shadow economic activity then the shadow economic activity will persist, and so one has to think perhaps a bit more creatively about how the state can replace a survival economy. That may mean, for example, actually allowing a bit more deficit spending than the international financial institutions would like. There is the tendency on the part of the external economic actors to have a very disciplinary approach—regulation, control, tight budgets, reducing government expenditure, perhaps even withdrawing the state from its role in economic activity—but perhaps we need to think more creatively and think could there be, for example, public works which might employ a lot of people and contribute towards income generation, increasing purchasing power. I am not suggesting that the Tennessee Valley Authority of the 1930's could be recreated in DRC but we do need to think more creatively about the economic role of the state.

  Q233  Mr Singh: For DFID it is easier to talk to a state, even if it is a weak state government. To whom do you talk in these borderland areas to promote peace or distribute aid? It does not seem to me a realistic possibility to talk to somebody, or some organisations, or a grouping, which might have the policy to be able to do something?

  Dr Cooper: It may be the case, in some circumstances, but very often there will be regional political leaders or any other kinds of actors within a borderland that one can connect up with; so you have got paramount chiefs in Sierra Leone, for instance, that one could envisage connecting up to, and to some extent the externals have pursued that kind of policy. Generally, I think there are actors there that one can connect up to and also one can conceptualise the borderland and think about how one can construct policy which will promote the borderland as an agent of peace, rather than as an agent of conflict.

  Q234  John Bercow: Which of you gentlemen is a professional economist?

  Professor Pugh: None of us.

  Q235  John Bercow: None of you is a professional economist; well I am grateful for that. I did listen to what might be described as a succinct encapsulation of the thesis advanced in your book, entitled War Economies in a Regional Context, and I think, Professor Pugh, I heard that succinct encapsulation a moment ago in response to Mr Singh's question. The reason why I asked is simply that it is true enough that you can encounter three economists and still find at least five opinions, but one perhaps might start, or some of us might be inclined to start, from a working premise that people with academic experience of economics and a professional discipline in that field would be, relatively speaking, well qualified to talk about the applicable economic policies in a particular area. My understanding, from what you have just said and from the book, is that your thesis, if one—forgive me—strips it of the jargon, the externally-derived paradigm, the free market element, I think what you are really saying is that free enterprise in other countries is not necessarily the best model to follow. Liberal economics is inappropriate in its purist form. Is what you are saying that a bit of deficit spending on public works projects is a good idea, which are, frankly, entirely compatible with capitalist enterprise though not with the pure model of markets, or is it something more than that which you are suggesting, and, if so, upon what evidence base?

  Professor Pugh: One of the things which struck me, in the course of our research, is that nobody has been able to define a free market. Economists point to a variety of economic systems which can fit into that label, and the Cambridge economist John Kay has written a book called The Truth About Markets: Why some nations are rich but most remain poor, and the main idea to come out of that book is that there is no such thing as an absolutely free market, there is regulation in some form in most countries, for example, in this country we subsidise certain industries, and so on, and we guarantee railway companies, and so on, against losses. I think it is important, when international financial institutions and organisations, such as the EU, talk about a free market economy, and it was actually in the Rambouillet Agreement of 1999 that Kosovo should have a free market economy, so you could argue that the coalition went to war partly to establish a free market economy, without defining what it would be. I think that certainly it would be a mistake to say that we are looking at the previous command economy models which were operating in the Soviet Union, or even in the former Yugoslavia.

  John Bercow: Right; that is helpful. I had not actually suggested that, but I am most grateful for your acknowledgement that it might be a concern people will have about those who are particularly stern and acerbic critics of the free enterprise capitalist model. I do not think one needs unduly to preoccupy oneself, if I may politely suggest it, Professor Pugh, with the question of the definition of a free market. I think it was Clement Atlee who was once asked to define an elephant and he said that personally he found it difficult, if not impossible, to define an elephant, but on the whole he rested content because he felt that if he saw an elephant he would be aware that he had seen it, so I do not think we should be too hung-up on this question of abstract models and what is pure. What I was trying to get at and what I am seeking to establish is the overall view, of all three of you, on the basis of your study of conflict-ridden parts of the world, as to the sorts of broad policies which should be put in place. If we accept that in scarcely any country in the world is either pure capitalism, a" la Von Mises or Alfred Marshall, or pure socialism, a" la Louis Althusser, Nicos Poulantzas, Joseph Stalin or Leon Trotsky, applied.

  Ann McKechin: Or none of them.

  John Bercow: Or none of them.

  John Battle: Or reformists?

  Q236  John Bercow: Or even the reformist position of others, or even Antonio Gramsci, writing in his prison notebooks, then I think that we are acknowledging that you are not applying a pure model, you are working instead at a broad idea. What I am intrigued by is that you think it worth telling us that there is a case for deficit spending and public works projects. It may be a perfectly valid view, I am bound to say it is not, if I may say so, a great discovery, it is not a particularly original view, there is nothing exceptional about it and I do not think that you would find, on the whole, even within the IMF and the World Bank, that there is a sort of resolute opposition to such a notion. I think those organisations often are pilloried for things they have not actually said, do not really believe and are not planning to do. What I would like to establish is this. If you talk about the twilight economy, if you like, you did not use the expression "a black market economy" but the informal economy, call it what you like, do you not think that, aside from cultural considerations, or considerations in some cases of transport infrastructure or distances to destination, or whatever, one motive force behind the conduct of such practices conceivably might be that it is the rational economic behaviour of individuals concerned? Might it not be the rational economic behaviour of the individuals or companies or areas concerned because there is not a broadly free enterprise model applied? You talked a moment ago about regulation and you thought we ought to get away from a sort of didactic regulation point, but insofar as there is didacticism on the part of the World Bank and the IMF it is didacticism in favour of less regulation, of greater market opportunity, of lower taxes, of recognition of the merits of property rights. Is this all objectionable to the Department of Peace Studies at Bradford University, and, if not, can we be told so?

  Dr Cooper: Can I make just a couple of comments here, first of all to defend my colleague, in terms of his complaint about the absence of a definition of free markets. It seems to me that actually there is a point to this, and one of the things that we were trying to highlight in the book was precisely the fact that I think, maybe because there is an absence of a definition, what you have had, particularly in weak and post-conflict societies, is almost like the application of an ideology of the free market, which often is a kind of bastardised child of the reality which is applied in the developed world. In the developed world actually deficit financing is not uncommon, protectionist trade policies are not uncommon, proactive employment policies are not uncommon, etc., etc. Certainly in the past, I think our critique was that, when you looked at past policy in a lot of post-conflict zones, what you found was more of a kind of application of a distorted ideology of the free market, the privatisation, deregulation, low taxation side of the free market, if you like, rather than protectionism, promotion of employment, promotion of the welfare state, deficit financing side of the free market, if you like. You get a kind of partial application. That is one thing. The other thing that I would also question you on slightly, I think, is that, yes, you get this kind of mantra of deregulation within post-conflict societies, but one of the ironies that I find, one of the things that I am interested in, is the whole approach, the global approach to issues to do with conflict trade and ethical trading. One of the anomalies that one finds when one looks at this is that there is an awful lot of regulation, quite punitive regulation, to prevent companies breaching the tenets of a free market, so if you breach EU competition laws, for instance, you can get fined quite substantial amounts of money. I think my favourite one, just to give you one example, a few years ago, British Airways got fined, I think it was £4 million[4]; they had provided incentives to travel agents to encourage them to book people on their flights rather than competitors' flights. In comparison, if you look at the level of regulation, certainly at the global level, around conflict trade issues and issues of ethical trade, you find a relative absence of regulation. The only example really that is pure, proper regulation is Kimberley, and even that is at a formal level a voluntary agreement, and other kinds of commodities are not covered. You can trade in coltan from the DRC and the only cost that you incur, potentially, is possibly a bit of bad publicity; you can give incentives to a travel agent to book some people on your flights and you can incur quite significant financial penalties. I would argue that there needs to be a kind of rebalancing out of regulatory priorities. I am not suggesting necessarily that British Airways, or Philip Morris, or whoever, should go unpunished for engaging in anti-competitive practices, but the other side of the equation at the moment is not being properly pursued, and what you have got instead is a whole raft of voluntary initiatives and transparency initiatives. You have got this kind of weak level of regulation at the global level and then you have quite disciplinary intervention, sanctions which are applied against a few pariah states that we have decided we do not like, but it is an arbitrary approach.


  Q237  John Bercow: I think, if I may say so, it is a perfectly legitimate view but I think we ought to be clear about what the view is. What you are really saying is there is too much of the regulation that you do not like and too little of the regulation that you do like; that is the central thesis. You talk about prohibitions on state aids and you refer to that as though it is regulation. In a manner of speaking it is, but essentially it is intended to be a liberating regulation, because it applies the principle that, as a state, you should not be able to operate in a discriminatory fashion such as to buck the market and, artificially, through the use of state funds, damage the prospects of the company which might be operating without them. Actually, when you reflect on it, that does not seem quite such a remarkable or unreasonable proposition. I understand also the point that you make, which I do not snuff out, about areas in which there is an argument for stronger regulation than actually exists, for example, in relation to ethical trading, and that is only one case in point but I accept there are others where the toss can be argued. I suppose what I am keen to ask you to do is to consider whether the biggest picture item of all, in terms of regulation/obstacles to development in the trading environment, is the massive trade-distorting behaviour of the richest countries in the world in the form of protectionism. There is protectionism which says we shall build up our domestic bases, develop in-country and be allowed a period in which to do so, and we should be able to put up barriers and resist products from other parts of the world. There is an argument for that and there is an argument against that, there are dangers in it but there are advantages in it on a time-limited basis. Surely there is a compelling argument against Western trade policies which distort trade and impede the prospects of recovery, growth and improved living standards by developing countries as a consequence of the use of state power, be it by the United States or the European Union, and yet this does not seem to be writ all that large in what you are saying to us today? Perhaps it is because I have not yet given you an adequate opportunity to do so.

  Dr Cooper: I agree.

  John Bercow: Success.

  Dr Cooper: I agree with you that those trade protection policies are distorting, and I guess my line would be that, as you were saying, you object to the regulation you do not like and the regulation that you do like, it is not an objection to regulation per se, or indeed an argument for no regulation per se, it is an argument for actually looking at what kind of regulation is effective and what kind of regulation is not effective, and where particular kinds of regulation can be applied and where they cannot. Take the issue of protectionism, for instance. It seems to me wholly correct to argue for the elimination of trade protectionism on the part of big, powerful, economically-developed trading entities like the EU, the US, etc. On the other hand, I think also that there is a fairly strong argument for looking at particular post-conflict societies and looking at the extent to which actually some form of trade protectionism for key industries may well be relevant for those kinds of societies. It is about looking at where the regulatory approach and where the free market is relevant and where actually other approaches may be more appropriate.

  Q238  John Bercow: Do you think, on the whole, the UK Government's policies are tailored, and therefore, by implication, calculated and applied differentially to the particular circumstances of individual countries that we have studied, or do you think that, in practice, whether deliberately or by default, the British Government really applies a "one size fits all" approach? When I say by default I mean to some extent, because, in trading matters, Chairman, as colleagues all know, we are, let us face it, I am not making a partisan point here, I am simply making what I think is a statement of fact, not entirely a free agent, we are part of the EU commercial policy.

  Dr Cooper: You are not going to like this answer because it is yes and no.

  John Bercow: As long as there are reasons helpful to our inquiry.

  Q239  Chairman: You must have studied economics at some time?

  Dr Cooper: I am an academic; it comes with the territory. I think there is a kind of differentiation which we are seeing almost at a global level, and particularly, of course, post-9/11, and so you have got differentiation which states make and the developed world in general is making between different kinds of conflicts that are occurring in different areas. On the one hand, you have got the emphasis on Iraq and a particular kind of approach to Iraq which is highly militaristic and lots of money being spent there, to some extent Afghanistan, and then you have got other conflicts which are not deemed to be economically important enough, or not strategically important enough, in terms of the war on terror, or whatever it might be, which are more likely either to drop off the radar screen altogether or at least not get the same level of attention. In that sense, I think there is a differentiation which goes on, which is perhaps less about what is happening in the individual countries and more about national priorities. I think there is also a sense in which aid distributors, and this is not just a criticism of DFID, do have a set of tools that they want to come into a country and apply, and these change over time so there is a set of aid tools which are fashionable at one time and then new things arise. At the moment, it is democracy, good governance, economic reform, anti-corruption and transparency initiatives, a bit of tokenistic gender initiatives thrown in as well, and so on and so forth. I think that kind of panoply of tick-box reforms does get applied automatically in each situation. For instance, a specific example which comes to mind is anti-corruption initiatives. There is this kind of fetish now for anti-corruption initiatives, anti-corruption commissions, which is good; nobody is in favour of corruption. I just wonder how far that fetish gets thought through, because, inevitably, in a lot of societies, what happens is that you set up an anti-corruption commission and it becomes simply a vehicle for political patronage and for the exercise of political power. You need to go beyond ticking that box and applying the model and thinking through what is the follow-on impact of setting up an anti-corruption commission in that particular society.


4   See table, Ev 136 Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2006
Prepared 25 October 2006