Select Committee on Office of the Deputy Prime Minister: Housing, Planning, Local Government and the Regions Written Evidence


Memorandum by the Royal Town Planning Institute (RTPI) (PGS 35)

INTRODUCTION

  1.  The Royal Town Planning Institute (RTPI) is the professional body for planners. It has over 19,000 members working in every aspect and sector of planning. The RTPI's members are at the forefront of securing agreements under section 106 and of striving for the achievement of sustainable development. The RTPI is a learned and a learning body and, as seen below, has had a long involvement in the whole question of betterment. More recently, it has put forward suggestions in 2000 for a tariff-based approach to address some of the problems of the current system.

  2.  The RTPI fully supports the concept of, and need for, using the changes in the value of land in order to provide the infrastructure to support the creation of mixed and sustainable communities and to achieve sustainable development. Over 65 years ago, a Town Planning Institute Committee on Compensation and Betterment concluded that "we are satisfied that essential planning and, particularly, re-planning cannot be carried out effectively under the existing legislation regarding compensation and betterment". As the White Paper on "The Land Commission" [Cmnd 2771, September 1965] pointed out, "there is no novelty in proposals to secure for the community at least a share in the values it has itself created. An Act of 1427 sought to recover increases in the value of property attributable to public expenditure on works for sea defence .  .  .".

  3.  It is one of the key shortcomings of the current planning system that, despite a number of attempts, no satisfactory system of capturing value has been implemented. The RTPI, therefore, very much welcomes the fact the current Government is keen to devise an acceptable, workable and effective system to achieve this. All the comments we make below should be read within the context of a clear acceptance of the principle of using land or development value to support sustainable development.

  4.  Additionally, these comments should not be taken as indicating a belief that the current system of Section 106 agreements is fully effective either in raising the necessary funding in all cases or in delivering effective and transparent decision making and certainty. However, there is evidence that this system is starting to work more effectively at a time when the Government intends to scale back its operation.

THE RTPI'S POSITION

  5.  Whilst the RTPI wholeheartedly accepts the principle behind the proposals for Planning Gain Supplement (PGS), we do not believe that the approach set out will achieve the objectives for PGS as set out in 1.14 of the consultation paper. There are seven main reasons for this:

    —  It is not certain that significant additional revenue will accrue.

    —  The proposed PGS scheme appears to break the link between the infrastructure1 needs of a community that are generated by a new development and the provision of that infrastructure before the development commences.

    —  It is not clear how money derived from PGS will be distributed in practice—not least in relation to devolved administrations—nor, consequently, how transparent PGS will be.

    —  There is the danger that those communities most in need of infrastructure investment, particularly those with failing markets, will lose out to those with development pressure—with a consequent "overheating" of the local economy for the latter areas.

    —  The proposed scheme appears to have been written with a green field development model in mind. This makes it less relevant given that, for example, 67% of housing is built on brown field sites.

    —  The retention of affordable housing within s1062 as opposed to within PGS, albeit understandable, may have adverse effects on the achievement of this key aspect of Government policy.

    —  There are a number of more detailed criticisms related to the methodology set out for valuation, which may lead to uncertainly, delay and a failure to deliver. In this context, it needs to be borne in mind that previous attempts at capturing and returning the uplift in value3 failed not only because of political differences between administrations but because of their complexity and difficulty in delivering the objectives of those schemes.

  Each of these issues will be dealt with in turn, below.

  Notes:

  1  In the context of this paper, "infrastructure" is taken to relate to such aspects of sustainable communities as health, education, social services, recreation, environmental protection, community facilities and affordable housing as well as physical infrastructure such as transport, drainage, utilities and flood defence.

  2  "s106" is used here to denote planning obligations agreements in order to follow the usage in the consultation document. It is recognised that other legislation applies in devolved administrations and the difficulties posed by a consultation that relates a UK tax solely to an English system are covered in this response.

  3  The Town and Country Planning Act 1947; the Land Commission Act, 1967; the Community Land Act, 1975; and the Development Land Tax Act, 1976.

ADDITIONAL REVENUE

  6.  One of the main rationales for introducing a PGS is that it will lead to an increase in funding for necessary infrastructure. The RTPI fully supports this aim. However, in practice, it is not certain that such revenue will accrue at levels that will make the introduction of this tax cost effective. There are a number of reasons for this, some of which are covered in the points below. These include the fact that on brown field development there may well not be an uplift in value when remediation is taken into account. Secondly, one element which contributes a significant proportion of existing s106 related expenditure—affordable housing—is not included within the PGS regime. This fact appears to preclude affordable housing from benefiting from any additional funding raised through PGS—in effect the contribution that development can make to affordable housing will remain the same as it currently does under the s106 regime.

  7.  Additionally, developers will rightly take a pessimistic view of the value of land following a planning permission when the longer term prospect for property markets is uncertain. They may well be able to demonstrate little or no uplift in value for a development. Fourth, PGS payments may be treated as an allowable business expense for tax purposes—thus potentially offsetting the yield from other taxes. In addition, s106 payments will be taken into account in determining the final value for PGS and, therefore, the amount of "new" resources entering the system need to be offset by those already gained through the existing system. Finally, there must be a tension between the desire to set a rate of tax that will bring in additional funding and one that is low enough not to deter development and not to encourage developers to land bank to a greater extent than now happens.

THE LINK BETWEEN INFRASTRUCTURE AND PAYMENT

  8.  In seeking to limit the operation of s106 to a "development-site environment" approach, there is the danger that elements of infrastructure required to both make a development financially viable and, importantly, to enable it to contribute to the creation of sustainable communities will not be delivered for that particular development.

  9.  The Section 106 system that operates currently can be seen, basically, as a contract between a developer and a local planning authority (LPA) with the authority agreeing to deliver certain elements of infrastructure, to which the developer has contributed, within a certain time. Many authorities will return the developer's contribution if that contract is not fulfilled. It is hard to determine from the details in the consultation paper how such a direct relationship between payment and delivery will exist under PGS.

  10.  Some elements which contribute to the creation of sustainable communities, such as education and health provision, will be provided by PGS rather than s106. Without a clear means of identifying how PGS revenue will be returned directly to fund those elements, it will be impossible for a contract for delivery to exist between a developer and an LPA. It will also make it very difficult for an LPA to require that all or part of a scheme is not started until certain elements of infrastructure are in place. It will be doubly difficult in some cases as the financial payment is not made until the development starts.

  11.  This lack of direct link between the developer and the provision of infrastructure will also make it much harder for a development to be acceptable in terms of an Environmental Impact Assessment. Currently, developers can mitigate or obviate adverse impacts by providing or funding ameliorating actions or developments, such as provision for public transport. Unless there is a more direct link between payment and delivery then it will not be possible to demonstrate conclusively that impacts identified in the assessment will be addressed.

THE DISTRIBUTION OF PGS REVENUES

  12.  There are four main issues relating to the distribution of revenues back to local areas, The first—the relationship between PGS payment and the infrastructure required for a particular site, has been covered above. The second relates to the geographical distribution, the third relates to the distribution in respect of a "shopping basket" of infrastructural needs and the fourth relates to timeliness.

  13.  On geographical distribution, the consultation paper states that a "significant majority" of revenues will be returned to the local level and an "overwhelming majority" will be recycled within the region. This somewhat confusing statement is further compounded by a more recent statement by the Minister for Local Government and Communities that "the majority of funds will be spent at the local level, with the rest to be spent in the sub-region". The re-distributive mechanism is at the heart of making a workable infrastructure funding system and it is regrettable that the consultation document is uncertain on this.

  14.  The consultation paper is silent on an extremely important aspect of geographical distribution—that relating to the devolved administrations. As the tax is payable to HMRC, it is a national tax. There is no indication of the role (if any) of devolved governments in influencing, or playing an active role in, the re-distribution of this national tax. This omission is compounded when planning agreements are considered. This is a devolved responsibility and, for example, the Welsh Assembly Government is currently considering reviewing the operation of s106 in Wales. The situation could arise where a national tax regime is predicated on changes to legislation (5.15 in the consultation paper) which may not apply in devolved areas.

  15.  Equally important, is the way in which the distribution of revenue will relate to the requirements of local and regional areas in terms of infrastructure. The consultation paper is silent on this although it is understood that recipients could include health trusts and others as well as local government. There is the need for local authorities working in partnership with utility and infrastructure providers and adjoining and regional authorities, to draw up investment plans for the infrastructure needs of their areas. Many already do so through local planning and regional planning processes but the possible introduction of a PGS will require that this is put on a more substantive footing. There is a strong case to be made for local, regional and national spatial investment plans to be drawn up as documents which form the basis of bids for PGS funding. This gives added weight to the RTPI's long standing calls for a spatial development framework for the United Kingdom—indeed it is hard to see how PGS could operate effectively without this.

  16.  The final element in relation to distribution is timeliness. It is recognised that the taking of the revenue at the point at which development is started is necessary in terms of the cash flow of a development. However, this means that the funding for necessary infrastructure is not available in advance of the development for which it is required. It may be assumed that local authorities and others will establish infrastructure funds which may draw in other sources of funding—such as the Community Infrastructure Fund. However, in terms of the funding of a flow of infrastructure projects, the timing of revenue collection will mean that the element of such a fund which is derived from any additional PGS derived money will always be in debt to itself and will require pump priming funding from elsewhere.

  17.  An added complication arises when developments are necessarily phased but where the infrastructure need relates to the overall completion of the development rather than simply to the first phase. In this case, there will be no certainty that subsequent phases will provide the levels of revenue required but it would be inequitable for the "pathfinder" development to have to provide a significant proportion of overall funding requirements.

EFFECTS IN DIFFERENT MARKET AND GEOGRAPHICAL SITUATIONS

  18.  PGS is promulgated as a national tax but is one that will impact in very different ways in different geographical and market situations. It is clearly built on a model of development on a greenfield site in an area with growth pressures and it is relevant that the table of uplift in values (paragraph 1.10) shows uplift from mixed agricultural land. Currently, in England, only 33% of housing development follows that model. The reality in many other cases is one where a site without permission (or even with permission) will have a negative value taking into account the need for remediation or where the uplift in value is low as the Planning Value itself will be low. The consultation document does not make it clear how PGS will benefit local areas in such situations.

  19.  In such cases, the role of infrastructure investment will be to stimulate markets rather than service them or to help to turn existing communities into sustainable ones. If, however, there is little revenue accruing through PGS because of no, or limited, uplift in value, then those areas that can be in most need of infrastructure will not receive funding for it through PGS. Rather, PGS may be seen as adding fuel to potentially overheated local economies through continued investment in such areas. This tax can, therefore, be seen as being potentially regressive.

  20.  In order to counter this, there does need to be some element of the revenue diverted for strategic infrastructure investment in areas which would benefit from it. This may be done through "top slicing" PGS or through taking PGS revenues into account in determining the regional allocations of national spending. Otherwise, PGS could be a deterrent to the regeneration of run-down and deprived areas.

  21.  The Government is considering having different rates of taxation on greenfield and on brownfield sites. It is worth looking at the extension of this differential rate approach to different uses in order to encourage a range of uses which would contribute to sustainable communities by reducing tax rates on those that may be desirable in planning terms but less attractive in commercial terms. This may include types of use, such as individually owned shops as opposed to chains, which planning does not currently have the ability to control.

  22.  Additionally, it is clear (see PPS1) that one of the purposes of planning is to create high quality development. It is not certain how PGS will affect those developers who wish to invest in a greater quality of development in ways that may not necessarily be reflected in the final monetary value of the scheme.

AFFORDABLE HOUSING

  23.  The logic behind keeping affordable within the s106 arrangements is recognised—both that the provision of affordable housing needs to be related directly to a site if mixed communities are to be achieved and that payment will most often be in the form of land or stock rather than a payment. However, the exclusion from affordable housing from PGS could have two detrimental effects. First, it is not stated in the consultation document whether some of the revenue from PGS will be used to support affordable housing in addition to the resources gained through s106, by for example including the Housing Corporation as a recipient of revenue or through returning to the equivalent of Local Authority Social Housing Grant. If this is not to be the case, then the opportunity to support the delivery of a key Government agenda will be lost.

  24.  Secondly, s106 agreements for affordable housing are only meant to relate to residential developments above a threshold. PGS is to apply to all types of development with a very low threshold set. There is a strong case for requiring commercial development to contribute to the development of the types of housing that many workers will need in order to staff that particular development.

  25.  Taking both these concerns, it is necessary for re-consideration to be given to the relationship between PGS and affordable housing—even if a key funding route remains s106 agreements—so that the development of affordable housing can benefit from the PGS regime.

DETAILED ASPECTS

  26.  It is not necessary to go into detail on some of the more specific aspects of the proposals in the consultation paper as we consider that the case against the scheme suggested has been made above. However, while we welcome the fact that the Supplement would be payable by all types of development and that the threshold for payment is to be set as low as possible, we have concerns over other detailed aspects including the difficulty in assessing a value before permission—particularly on green field sites—and in separating out those elements of the uplift that can be attributed to a specific permission being given.

  27.  The greatest uplift in value may occur at outline planning permission stage but the paper is not clear at which point in the permission process the value is assessed. This fact, combined with the point at which the tax is collected, still allows for a market in land to take place without permission being implemented. There are also concerns—already expressed in broad terms above—about where the line should be drawn between "development-site environment" infrastructure and that falling under PGS. For example, flood defence is listed as being within the new scope of s106 rather than as suitable for funding by PGS.

ALTERNATIVE APPROACHES

  28.  Given our strong support for the principle behind these proposals, the RTPI is very keen to work with HM Treasury, the ODPM and HMRC to develop proposals that will overcome the concerns about the current proposals set out above. One clear basis for further thinking is a tariff-based approach and we set out further thinking on this below. However, it is also worth considering both extensions to existing mechanisms, including s106 and Capital Gains Tax and more fundamental suggestions including examples from abroad such as Tax Incremental Financing and the Irish Republic's system of Development Contribution Schemes which is embodied in their Planning and Development Act 2000. The RTPI would be pleased to prepare further evidence on alternative approaches and includes an example of one approach at the end of this section.

A Tariff Based Approach

  29.  The RTPI fails to understand why a tariff-based approach was not included as part of the proposed approach—or even one of the options—in the Consultation Paper. Whilst the consultation paper states reasons for rejecting this option, we do not consider these to be robust.

  30.  Five years ago the RTPI issued a policy paper on Planning Gains and Obligations [December 2000—http://www.rtpi.org.uk/resources/policy-statements/2000/dec/pol20001202.pdf] which stated that: "the Institute proposes a new look at policy, which rejects antipathy to formulae but rather directs itself toward the development of a tariff or scale based approach where a balanced and well-planned development can be secured best by developer contributions to infrastructure."

  31.  The RTPI statement went on to specify that, "the foundation of a scale, or tariff based, approach should be the development plan. This should: set out the basic policy for the approach and should clearly incorporate the tariff expected and, wherever practical, set out on a spatial basis the "area by area" requirements for the provision or renewal of infrastructure in new developments, including redevelopment of previously developed areas."

  32.  Given this, the RTPI very much welcomes the approaches being taken in Milton Keynes, Peterborough and other areas in adopting a tariff-based approach. We recognise that that the situation in such growth areas—with significant pressure for, and acceptance of, growth, an analysis of the infrastructure needs created by development and an ability to deliver housing in significant trenches—is not replicated in many other areas. However, there are elements of such an approach, including the certainty that it brings to the development process and the transparent nature of both payment and infrastructure requirement, that need to be incorporated into any further proposals to capture value uplift.

Land taxation

  33.  A more far reaching approach could stem from a recognition that there is a fundamental difference between land values and uplifts in value created by the grant of planning permission. In the planning Acts the definition of land includes buildings but in the law of economics it does not. Classic economic theory states that land is simply the natural resource upon which all human activity depends. In economic terms buildings and development are capital.

  34.  Economic principles state that if the cost of producing goods (eg development) and services is increased then supply will be reduced. Thus if the cost of the charge is applied to development, as is proposed through the PGS, it will have the effect of reducing the supply of new development. In contrast to this, if the charge is applied to land (in its economic sense and not its planning sense) it will not have the same adverse effect. This is because land has no cost of production—it simply exists as the natural resource. In addition it is also fixed in supply indicating that a charge on land cannot reduce the supply.

  35.  To improve the situation, in this model, it would be necessary to split the value of property (and proposed development) into their separate land (the natural resource) and capital (building) elements and amend the existing property taxes—the business rates and council tax—so that the charge is moved away from the building element of property value to the land element.

CONCLUSION

  36.  The RTPI strongly supports the Government in the actions that it has taken to try to find a mechanism through which some of the increment in value created through the planning system is used to fund the infrastructure necessary for sustainable communities and development. For all the reasons given above, however, we feel that the proposed scheme for achieving this will not have the desired effects and could, in some circumstances, work against their achievement. We urge the Government to work closely with all those involved in the creation of sustainable development to devise another system that is acceptable and effective and which meets the Government's own objectives. The RTPI is very keen to be part of the process that leads to the identification of such a system.





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2006
Prepared 11 May 2006