Select Committee on Office of the Deputy Prime Minister: Housing, Planning, Local Government and the Regions Written Evidence


Memorandum by the Confederation of British Industries (CBI) (PGS 43)

INTRODUCTION

  1.  The CBI represents companies of all sizes and from all sectors of the economy. With a direct membership accounting for 4 million employees and a trade association membership accounting for 40% of the private sector workforce.

  2.  The CBI believes that both an increase in the supply of housing and improvements in infrastructure are vital to the health of the UK economy and welcomes this opportunity to respond to the Government's consultation on Planning-gain Supplement (PGS).

  3.  The CBI's Minerals Group has submitted a separate response to the consultation highlighting the specific issues and concerns that relate to that industry. CBI Scotland has also responded to both the Treasury and Scottish Executive to complement the CBI's overall response.

OVERVIEW

  4.  The CBI supports the Government's aim to increase the supply of affordable housing and increase investment in infrastructure, both of which are key issues for businesses in the UK. However, the CBI believes that the Government's proposals to implement PGS are likely to lead to a number of unintended and negative consequences that would outweigh any potential benefits of PGS and we would strongly urge the Government to reconsider its proposals. There are three major areas which need to be recognised:

    (a)  The potential threat to the competitiveness of UK business and the long-term health of the UK economy:

—  placing an additional tax burden on business in the context of increasing costs and global competition could further threaten wider business investment;

—  the widening of the original proposals from Barker, without a correspondingly broader package of offsetting benefits, risks impacting on development and business growth;

—  making development more costly and complex risks undermining the important role that property plays more widely for business;

—  the proposals cut across the better regulation agenda and would entail a significantly increased administrative burden on business; and

—  the Government does not seem to have fully explored the potentially complex and negative consequences on the property market, specific types of development or the wider business community.

    (b)  PGS is likely to make it more difficult in many respects to achieve key Government objectives, for example increasing the supply of housing:

—  PGS could undermine the willingness of landowners to bring forward land for development;

—  the additional tax and complexities of PGS would increase the costs and risks of development and could threaten the viability of regeneration and wider development;

—  the relationship between development and the delivery of supporting infrastructure would inevitably be weakened with potential impacts on the acceptability and workability of development;

—  the proposals would be likely to undermine the broader agenda to streamline the planning process, with potential delays of two years for complex schemes; and

—  the proposed scaling back of Section 106 would be very difficult to achieve, with knock-on implications for the business-local authority relationship and the viability of schemes.

    (c)  The proposals for PGS are likely to be unworkable and do not sufficiently address past problems with development taxes:

—  the self assessment process would still impose a significant burden on business (particularly those companies for whom development is not their core business);

—  the valuation process would be highly complex and would cause major uncertainty thereby adding both to the costs and timescales of development;

—  the proposals would involve taxing expected gain rather than actual gain creating scope for unfairness and increasing the risks associated with investment in potential development;

—  the requirement to pay on commencement of development threatens to create cashflow problems for businesses;

—  PGS would impose significant resourcing pressures on local authorities, the Valuation Office Agency and other organisations; and

—  PGS is already affecting the market and would continue to raise serious problems during a transitional period.

  5.  Given these concerns we do not believe that PGS should be taken forward. However, we recognise the need to secure funding for infrastructure and will work with the Government to explore alternatives which may be more workable.

A.  THE COMPETITIVENESS OF UK BUSINESS

Concerns about the Increasing Business Tax and Cost Burden

  6.  The CBI strongly believes that this is the wrong time to introduce a new tax on UK business. We are extremely concerned about the impact of new taxation in an increasingly competitive global market when business in the UK is already having to cut costs, avoid new costs and is increasingly risk averse.

  7.  The overall tax burden on UK business is already high. Overall, Budget decisions since 1997 will have added an extra £8 billion to the tax bills of business and its investors in the fiscal year about to end—bringing the cumulative additional bill since 1997 to £50 billion. Business and its investors have borne a disproportionate share of the tax rise due to post-1997 policy action, even if the impact of above-inflation council tax increases is taken into account.

  8.  The major impositions have been the surprise £4 billion per annum rise in employers' national insurance, and the £5 billion per annum erosion of dividend tax credits, which have been only partly offset by reduced corporation tax rates. In addition, many businesses have been affected by the rising burden of stamp duty land tax, while some sectors (such as utilities in the past, and North Sea companies today) have been singled out for special higher-tax treatment. We also note several other ongoing initiatives (the prospect of compulsory employer pension fund contributions, the Pension Protection Fund, and HM Revenue and Customs' target to close an alleged but unproven £3 billion "tax gap"), all of which threaten to add still further to business' tax bills.

  9.  The impact of this on the available funds to invest (and the incentives to do so) and on international competitiveness is critical. By adding both to costs and uncertainty, these policies are already holding back business investment, which has recently been at its lowest ever level as a share of GDP.

  10.  The problem is that these fiscal policy impacts have come on top of other pressures making it more difficult for businesses to grow profits, compared with a decade ago. At present, this includes the impact of the economic slowdown. But while the economic cycle will turn upwards in due course, other—"structural"—pressures have also emerged:

    —  intense international competition due to globalisation and the rise of China as a major world trading power. This has helped to push prices down in product markets, but up in commodity markets, thereby squeezing margins. Imported goods prices (excluding oil) are 17% lower than a decade ago, and export prices are down by 14% on the same basis. By contrast, manufacturers' raw material and fuel costs have risen by 26% in just three years;

    —  the increase in employer-funded pension scheme deficits, which are having to be reduced through additional business contributions. Employer contributions to funded occupational and personal schemes amounted to £36 billion in 2004, having more than doubled from £17 billion in 1998.  Increased longevity, low long-term interest rates and—until recently—poor global stock market returns have all contributed to this situation, alongside the tax changes; and

    —  Government policies outside of the fiscal policy field, in particular labour market and other regulations which have added to business costs.

  11.  In turn, corporate profits recently peaked as a share of GDP, at a clearly lower level than the peaks achieved in the mid-1980s and mid-1990s, and even a little lower than the peak achieved in the late 1970s. Related to this, business investment has been depressed, reaching an all-time low as a share of GDP early last year.

Property and Development Important to Wider Business

  12.  Property is often perceived narrowly in terms of the "property industry". But this belies its wider importance. The property industry is indeed important in its own right but property is also a crucial ingredient of business success and is important to the overall performance of the economy and the attractiveness of the UK as a place to do business.

  13.  Business needs a constant supply of high quality development, offering a range of options to suit different and changing business needs. We need to ensure that companies can respond to varying economic and social drivers. Business investment in new property, redevelopment or a move from one property to another can transform the production process leading to substantial increases in output and/or greater efficiency. Increasingly property is also an important diversifier of investment risk—with a growing role in pension fund activity.

  14.  PGS must therefore be seen as a tax that has ramifications for the wider business community and the context of doing business in the UK—whether as a housebuilder, commercial developer, owner-occupier, tenant or inward investor.

PGS has significant implications for property/development

  15.  PGS, when initially conceived, was intended to apply to greenfield residential development where there was significant uplift in value from the planning permission. The current proposals cover a much wider range of developments (such as major mixed use or urban regeneration projects) which tend to involve more complexities and risks. As a consequence, development decisions and wider business decisions are likely to be impacted more significantly than appears evident from the consultation document.

  16.  In the UK, the level of taxes related specifically to property (eg business rates, SDLT) is already high relative to other countries, as our report (Is the tax system a help or a hindrance—UK As A Place to Do Business) and the latest OECD figures highlighted. In addition, business already pays in the region of £2 billion direct to local authorities through Section 106.  The proposals for PGS represent a new and additional tax on property development. While the Government intends to scale back Section 106, it is clear that the intention is for the combination of scaled back 106 plus PGS to raise significant additional revenue (although there is no clarity about how much extra).

  17.  The introduction of such a new tax burden would be expected to impact in a number of ways: to reduce both the viability of new development and the attractiveness of redevelopment and to add to the costs of doing business—depending on where the incidence of PGS falls. The complexity of the proposals, within an already complex tax system, would reinforce this. This is likely to have significant impacts for development specifically, but also for the wider business community for whom property is an important operational and commercial element, at a time when UK businesses already face a challenging environment.

  18.  The Government assumes that where possible PGS costs would be factored in to the price paid for land. This would have potential implications for the supply of land (see Section B) and consequent wider economic impacts. In many cases, however, the incidence of PGS (at least in part) would be on the development, for example where a land transaction is not involved (eg an owner occupier business developing their site) or where the full cost of PGS cannot be factored in. In these cases, PGS could impact in a number of ways:

    —  a reduction in the rate of return that the development can make;

    —  the need to reduce other costs—either within the development or more widely;

    —  a reduction in other agreements entered into eg with local authorities;

    —  less willingness to proceed with development; and

    —  an increase in the price of the development to the end user.

  19.  In turn, there could be significant implications for a variety of sectors of the business community:

    —  developers: a lower rate of return will impact on profitability with a knock on impact on wider investment. Or if there is less willingness to proceed with development this will impact on regeneration and business growth;

    —  owner-occupiers: if businesses face additional costs and complexities this may result in lower quality development, reduced profitability, changes to wider investment decisions or simply a decision not to proceed. This will have consequences for the wider UK economy and competitiveness agenda;

    —  occupiers (tenants): may face higher costs in terms of rents or a reduced supply of suitable high quality developments which will impact on their ability to compete; and

    —  investors: if profitability decreases this could impact on pension funds and inhibit diversification of risk.

  20.  Property development is accompanied by a number of intrinsic risks, which are considered when deciding whether or not to enter into development. The introduction of PGS would add risk to this process despite the "sensitivity" of the proposed system (for example it is payable regardless of whether the developer is a profitable concern at the time) and could tip the balance of risk against proceeding on a number of development schemes, especially those that are currently marginal. Even for specific developments where the total of PGS and Section 106 may be lower than previously, the complexities, risks and impracticalities of PGS could reduce the willingness to proceed.

  21.  PGS could be a barrier for businesses considering renovation, expansion or change of use. This could inhibit business growth and adaptation and undermine small business development. It could also undermine wider objectives for which development is essential, for example the aim to diversify the use of farm buildings and boost rural economies. It is important to note that in cases of business expansion, companies would be paying additional business rates in line with the relative increase in value.

  22.  The "do nothing" option (ie not proceeding with development) is likely to be higher than presumed for those businesses which have a choice of international locations to consider. Where the additional complexity and cost involved are perceived to be too high, new business investment/expansion simply may not take place or may take place elsewhere. In the context of seeking to attract (and retain) international firms, high value added and R&D investment to the UK, this is a key concern.

  23.  Ultimately property and the development industry is of fundamental importance to wider business. With property as a factor of production, an increasingly important element in pension provision, and an underpinning to labour market flexibility, the Government should not underestimate the potential wider impacts of PGS and the risks of slowing down development. This is particularly important given the background of increasing pressures on business and the far tougher economic context that we have outlined.

PGS does not fit with better regulation agenda

  24.  The CBI is concerned about the implications of implementing PGS for the better regulation agenda. We have long argued that an appropriate regulatory environment is a key factor for the efficient operation of markets and that a commitment to more effective regulatory enforcement practices has to be central to the UK competitiveness agenda. We believe that implementation of the Hampton recommendations represents a real opportunity to ensure that regulation and regulatory enforcement in the UK adhere to the principles of better regulation set out by the Better Regulation Task Force prescribing proportionality, accountability, consistency, transparency and targeting.

  25.  The CBI believes that the Government's proposals do not adhere to these principles because they would result in two parallel systems of revenue collection both of which, directly or indirectly, capture some of the gain in value from planning permission to fund local infrastructure. It would be extremely inefficient for central and local government and business to administer a two-tier system and it would contribute to the already significant bureaucratic burden placed on business and local authorities by the planning system. The proposed scaling back of section 106 is unlikely in practice to significantly reduce the administration of that system.

The lack of detail and impact assessment adds to business concerns

  26.  Given the wide implications of PGS for property and business, the absence of any real detail in the proposals is a major concern. There seems to be little assessment of the possible impacts of PGS on development or the wider issues highlighted above. The absence of such information further undermines CBI members' confidence that the proposals are consistent with efforts which help business to compete in an increasingly challenging global environment. And the lack of detail on the likely rates of PGS or the proportions to be re-distributed has heightened business sensitivities.

  27.  Given the risks involved, it is inappropriate for the Government to proceed with proposals for PGS without providing such analysis. This is particularly important since the Government has significantly expanded the scope of PGS from the original Barker recommendations. The burden of proof should not be placed on respondents.

  28.  We are willing to work with the Government to explore the issues further but we strongly believe that there are too many uncertainties and potentially negative consequences across business to consider progressing the proposals. As well as the detailed questions of workability (in section C), some of the issues that need to be addressed include:

    —  the level of revenue sought by PGS;

    —  the assumptions made in relation to how much of the additional money through PGS would be via extended scope (ie more developments being subject to PGS than Section 106) versus projects that already pay section 106, paying more in total through section 106 and PGS;

    —  the PGS rate at which the supply of land and development will not be adversely impacted;

    —  the proportion of schemes for which the Government assumes that PGS will be able to be "knocked off" the cost of land;

    —  where this is not possible (and particularly where the total of PGS and 106 is higher than previously), the assessment of likely impacts for different types of development;

    —  the offsetting measures to ensure that wider developments were not deterred (beyond the Barker proposals for housing);

    —  the baseline for Section 106 and by how much it would be scaled back;

    —  the budgeting processes for PGS and redistribution work in practice and mechanisms that would be put in place to provide certainty of delivery of infrastructure;

    —  the assumed set-up and running costs for PGS; and

    —  interaction of PGS with other Taxes eg SDLT, CGT.

B.  GOVERNMENT OBJECTIVES AND WIDER IMPLICATIONS

  29.  The CBI believes that PGS would not achieve the Government's core objective, namely to increase the supply of affordable housing, would threaten some of the Government's wider objectives and would have a number of unintended negative consequences for business, local communities and government (both centrally and locally). These include:

    —  PGS revenue is likely to be lower than Government expects because development would be likely to decrease (a reason for failure of past attempts at taxing the uplift from development);

    —  Government revenue such as Capital Gains Tax (CGT) would decrease because of the slowdown in development;

    —  many brownfield developments in particular may not be viable which would be detrimental for the Government's regeneration agenda;

    —  activity in the minerals industry—vital for the provision of materials for house-building and infrastructure would decrease;

    —  local authorities could lose out from fewer section 106 agreements or other initiatives because of the slowdown of development; and

    —  ultimately local communities would lose out both from the lack of development in their area and from the related lack of investment in local infrastructure.

PGS threatens the release of land

  30.  The CBI notes that the Government's objectives have the aim of increasing the supply of affordable housing which dates back to the original set of Barker recommendations. The CBI fully supports these aims and the Government's intention to increase investment in infrastructure—the lack of affordable housing and infrastructure are both key constraints on business productivity.

  31.  However, we fail to see how a new tax on development in the form of PGS would achieve these aims. Instead, a consequence of PGS is likely to be a decrease in the amount of sites that are brought forward for development—with landowners and developers exercising their "do-nothing" option. Although the Government proposes a "modest" PGS rate there is no clear evidence to support the assumption that the supply of land would be unaffected.

  32.  The CBI is concerned that PGS would have a disruptive effect on the release of land in the short to medium term. Two scenarios are possible; both would distort the market and neither are desirable:

    —  there would either be an immediate incentive to increase development and the release of land before 2008 would increase to avoid PGS, followed by a decline in development post-2008; or

    —  land-owners would refrain from releasing their land thereby decreasing opportunities for development, in anticipation of a change of Government (which has happened with three previous attempts in the past).

  33.  The scope of the proposals has been extended significantly from the Barker Report in terms of moving from housing to wider development. It is inappropriate simply to extrapolate from assumed impacts in relation to housing and the supply of land for housing. There is little to suggest that the Government has examined in detail the likely impacts on commercial development or has understood the implications for the wider market or specific types of development.

  34.  The Government has argued that PGS should be seen in the context of a package of measures that they believe would offset potential impacts. But there is little clarity in relation to the positive measures that would offset potential impacts on commercial development and little certainty that those related to housing would be sufficient.

PGS likely to hinder supply of housing

  35.  The Government's claim that increasing investment in infrastructure would allow house-builders to obtain planning permission and build more houses presupposes that the lack of infrastructure is the biggest constraint on housing development in the UK. Infrastructure is undoubtedly a factor but it is unlikely that the additional cost, associated risk and level of administration that PGS would introduce into the planning system would be directly outweighed by the benefits of increasing infrastructure provision.

  36.  The Government's proposals also fail to address the timing issue—PGS from development is intended to fund infrastructure to draw in development, but in practice development usually follows the provision of infrastructure or is provided alongside development through planning obligations. Even without this complication there would inevitably be a lag of several years between the introduction of PGS and the actual delivery of any infrastructure.

  37.  As highlighted, we support the Government's aims of trying to increase affordable housing and secure funding for investment in infrastructure necessary to underpin sustainable development and support economic growth. Therefore we are willing to work with Government to explore potential options which may be more workable than current proposals. This may include building further on section 106 (also looking at the feasibility of the tariff-based approach), CGT or mechanisms such as Tax Incremental Financing.

  38.  But it is too early at this stage to be more definitive: issues would need to be addressed in any such options. For example, we recognise the Government's concerns about the relatively blunt nature of tariffs and the potential impact on viability of development (or alternatively the level of complexity that might be necessary in some areas to ensure sensitivity). But using existing mechanisms is a far less risky—and more cost efficient—approach than introducing a major new tax.

PGS likely to have adverse impacts on planning reforms and timescales

  39.  The CBI is anxious that the Government is considering such a radical change to the planning system, whilst in the middle of implementing other major reforms that emerged from the Planning and Compulsory Purchase Act 2004. While the CBI has consistently sought improvement to the system of planning obligations, this is not a reason to introduce PGS. Not withstanding some variation across the country in the application of section 106, it is generally recognised as a tried and tested mechanism to deliver positive physical and social infrastructure benefits directly to local communities. The current system should continue to be developed—building on the recent positive work (circular 2005/05, the best practice guidance on planning obligations, and developing practice within some local authorities). We are concerned that the proposal to introduce PGS could undermine this.

  40.  The Government claims that business would benefit from the proposed scaling back of planning obligations, but has not yet provided an established baseline for current payments through planning obligations or how much the proposed scaling back could save business. In fact the nature of section 106 arrangements is such that it would be almost impossible to gauge how much is currently received through planning obligations either in cash or non-money contributions, which in turn would make it very difficult to retain transparency and ensure additionality of funding through PGS.

  41.  The CBI also reminds Government that planning is a devolved policy area and therefore while the Government could, within its powers, implement a tax across the whole of the UK it could not direct the devolved administrations to scale back their own planning obligations. There is therefore a particular issue for businesses in Scotland, Wales and Northern Ireland which could face higher costs through PGS with no promise of reduced planning obligations.

  42.  In addition there is much concern in Scotland about the implementation of such a major change to the planning system when the Planning etc (Scotland) Bill, which could itself introduce major reforms to the planning system in Scotland, has only just gone before the Scottish Parliament.

  43.  The planning system has been subject to considerable change and upheaval in recent years, and as our recent report showed, business is still not significantly benefiting in terms of an improved system, in fact in some instances the system has worsened. This would simply add further disruption and resource pressures and could threaten to deter development simply by adding to the overall complexity and uncertainty of the planning system.

  44.  Given that PGS calculations would need to be made after the conclusion of Section 106 negotiations and on grant of planning permission, this would add another delay to the planning process. The strong likelihood is that valuation would be a complex and protracted process, with potential for significant debate. This would further extend timescales for development—with developers unwilling to start development until certainty about PGS liability had been provided. Looking back at Land Tribunals, this could take anything up to two years for complex and disputed cases. The certainty and timing of the assessment is critical.

  45.  Resource pressures could further exacerbate such delays, with significant expertise required to manage the system. Reducing the tax level would not remove the uncertainty and scope for delay. It would merely reduce the revenue and further undermine the economics of the tax.

  46.  The original proposal in the Barker review was for PGS to apply when permission was granted in order to encourage implementation. The current proposal is for PGS to be payable on start of development. While this recognises the problems inherent in seeking to extract earlier payment, it could cause delays to development—contrary to the Government's objectives.

  47.  The issue of Development Stop Notices is also of concern. There is little clarity about how notices might be used but it is difficult to see how they would not introduce lengthy delays on certain developments. There is also deep concern that it could make a development unlawful which could interfere particularly with commercial developments involving complex arrangements between a number of parties.

Proposals for streamlining section 106 are flawed

  48.  We have never questioned the principle of planning obligations, in terms of development contributing to supporting infrastructure and mitigating impacts, but have been a critic of the way the system has been implemented. However, these concerns are not an argument for replacement by PGS. Instead recent efforts to improve the operation of section 106 must be continued. We have worked with the Government and others to strengthen the guidance and improve the system and recent changes, for example to allow pooling of contributions, offer opportunities to address the issues more effectively.

  49.  The Government argues that scaling back section 106 will partly offset the impact of PGS but we are far from convinced that this will be effective in practice. There are a number of significant issues:

    —  even a "streamlined" system would need to cover a wide range of issues and still involve (potentially lengthy) negotiation over detail, delivery and timescales;

    —  affordable housing, which is often the biggest element of a section 106 agreement in terms of cost and negotiation time, remains within the scope of section 106;

    —  the situation with regard to the interaction of PGS with section 278 and 6 of the Highways Act is unclear—but is a key issue given the importance of delivery of such infrastructure;

    —  there would be difficulties in terms of how tightly the definitions of some of the elements could be drawn eg environmental improvements can stretch far beyond the actual scope of the site;

    —  as yet there is no explicit baseline for section 106 against which to assess the proposed scaling back. In the absence of such information—which is very difficult to calculate with any certainty—the commitment is unconvincing;

    —  it would be very difficult to police the system and could create an antagonistic relationship between business, local government and central government;

    —  with a less certain and direct source of funding for local authorities there would still be pressure for them to seek to maximise commitments under section 106, despite Government intentions to exclude certain elements. Given all the difficulties highlighted, it is likely that the scaling back will not happen as intended with potential impacts on development costs and viability; and

    —  this could also reduce expected PGS revenues since section 106 needs to be accounted for in Planning Value.

  50.  In addition, there would be nothing to stop local authorities seeking other payments or provisions outside the scope of planning obligations, which would allow them to maintain their direct income levels, but represent significant additional costs for business. Conversely the cost of PGS could mean that business was less willing or able to work with local authorities on more innovative opportunities to deliver local infrastructure or initiatives, leading to a worsening relationship between business, local authorities and local communities and a reduction in such schemes across the country.

  51.  We therefore have real concerns that the proposed system would lead to:

    —  loss of flexibility in negotiating planning obligations;

    —  potentially increased anti-development pressures;

    —  greater incentive for local authorities to seek to use other arrangements outside the scope of planning obligations to achieve certain local benefits but with even greater cost for business; but

    —  less incentive for business pro-actively to enter into goodwill agreements with local authorities outside the scope of planning obligations because of the additional cost of PGS.

  52.  There are significant difficulties in trying to develop a national solution when the issues to be tackled vary between regions. A one-size fits all approach would not be able to tackle the different problems of low value areas in need of regeneration versus higher value areas with challenges and pressures of growth. The answer is not PGS or the redistribution of revenues away from higher value areas—which would risk undermining the acceptability and sustainability of development in these localities. Clearly funding needs to be secured for infrastructure investment in lower value areas—but the proposals in the document are not the solution. Making development more complex also works against the need to encourage and facilitate regeneration and business investment in these areas.

Less certainty of delivery of infrastructure

  53.  The proposals would effectively provide developers with less certainty of delivery of any infrastructure classed as off-site (which could still be integral to the success/viability of the development) and therefore funded through PGS rather than section 106.  The benefit of section 106 arrangements is that they are a legally binding contract between local authorities and developers for the delivery and funding of specific projects/outputs often with detailed timescales for delivery. In many cases, developers have the certainty that if the infrastructure is not provided their money will be refunded. They also have the option to deliver infrastructure themselves providing even greater certainty. PGS could not offer this degree of transparency or certainty for either local authorities or businesses.

  54.  Unless the Government was prepared to pump-prime PGS there would inevitably be a time lag between the identification of infrastructure need and the local authority receiving the PGS money to pay for it. It is therefore unclear what agreements would be possible between the local authority and the developer ahead of the stream of funding. In addition future funding commitments would always be dependent on the actual future tax take. It is unclear how this would impact on the conditionality of a planning permission for a major complex scheme. A developer would be unlikely to proceed in the face of significant uncertainty about whether necessary infrastructure or associated services (eg bus service) which are important for the development (in terms of its workability, sustainability and marketability) but outside the proposed scaled-back scope of section 106 would be delivered.

  55.  We are also deeply concerned about the lack of safeguards to ensure the additionality of investment in infrastructure and fear that PGS revenue would simply replace other Government expenditure or Local Authority grants (particularly in the longer term). While we support the Government's intention to increase investment in infrastructure, business has too often had empty promises in relation to hypothecation and additionality of tax revenues.

  56.  The Government would need to overcome many obstacles to make this workable and it is hard to see how business could receive the required certainty in relation to the delivery of infrastructure. This is crucial—the Government would need to demonstrate clearly how the system would work and what mechanisms would be put in place to ensure this if PGS was pursued.

  57.  In addition there has been little clarity from Government on the infrastructure deficit that they are intending to address. This would need to be clearly detailed in terms of which infrastructure issues were to be tackled, at what spatial level and how far PGS would be expected to contribute.

  58.  PGS might also be an inefficient means of delivering infrastructure. Some benefits may be paid for but provided off-site at a potentially higher cost to the local authority.

Threat to business/local authority/local community relationships

  59.  Collecting and redistributing PGS centrally would undermine an important local link. While there is a commitment that the monies received by a local authority would be at least roughly equal to that under section 106 it is a far less direct mechanism, and the budgetary processes are far from clear. With the inevitable time lag and less clarity in the linkage between developments and the provision of infrastructure there might be increased anti-development pressures within local communities.

  60.  While we recognise the desire to secure funding for regional and national priorities, redirection of revenues from some areas to others could create significant difficulties in terms of the local acceptability and sustainability of developments. We are extremely concerned therefore that PGS would be redirected via central government with a proportion siphoned off for national purposes—particularly in the absence of any clear accounting mechanisms or delivery structures. There may be a case for some revenues to be directed (in a transparent way) regionally, but the vast majority must be directed locally—back to the area where the funds originated—to be spent according to locally-determined priorities.

  61.  Given this, PGS seems an extremely inefficient system—with significant recycling of resources entailing additional delays and uncertainty.

  62.  It follows that 100% of any revenue raised through PGS within Scotland, Wales and Northern Ireland would have to be returned to those devolved administrations.

  63.  The Government argues that the revenue would need to be collected centrally and redirected to local and regional levels to allow for infrastructure provision across local authority boundaries. We fully recognise the need to provide more strategic infrastructure but believe that other options to achieve this must be promoted. New pooling arrangements could help to support this, as could a number of other mechanisms. The business community is also interested in whether arrangements such as those in Milton Keynes might be more widely applicable because they combine the local element, an opportunity for business to help identify infrastructure need and transparent delivery of infrastructure. It would be much more difficult to track the revenue and see the benefit of the tax if it was re-routed via either HMRC or HMT.

Implications for public services and infrastructure projects

  64.  There are specific issues in relation to the impact of PGS on organisations that are either wholly or partially funded from public sources or are involved in infrastructure delivery. The impact of PGS in terms of the additional cost and bureaucratic burden on local authorities, providers of transport infrastructure and higher education institutions, all of which would currently be within the scope of PGS, could be very damaging and threaten the Government's wider objectives. It would also be extremely inefficient to circulate funds through various public bodies in this way.

  65.  There are also significant questions in relation to partnerships involving local authorities or community schemes and how PGS would work.

C.  THE PGS PROPOSALS ARE NOT WORKABLE

  66.  The CBI does not believe that the proposals set out are workable. Even if the proposals were in tune with both the Government's own objectives and the CBI's objectives for the long-term health of the UK economy, the complexity and administration involved would outweigh any potential benefit.

  67.  In theory PGS may seem to provide sensitivity in terms of value uplift, but the complexities involved are likely to undermine its workability:

    —  the proposals are unlikely to improve sufficiently on past attempts at taxing planning gain;

    —  the self-assessment process would fail to mitigate the bureaucratic burden;

    —  calculating the value uplift in land is intrinsically complex and would lead to significant disputes about valuations;

    —  the payment procedure would be both impractical and unfair;

    —  there would be significant avoidance attempts; and

    —  PGS may relate to assumed value uplift, but is not necessarily related to actual gain.

Consultation does not learn from past attempts

  68.  The CBI recognises the Government's effort to learn from past mistakes of introducing a development land tax but remains unconvinced that this version would be any more likely to succeed for a number of reasons:

    —  The Government claims that "PGS should only capture a modest portion of the uplift, thereby preserving incentives to develop". The Government has failed to disclose what a "modest" rate would be, however the CBI believes that there would have to be different rates (or exemptions) to account for the complexity of development across different sectors and types of scheme. All of these rates would need to be low so as not to disincentivise development but it is likely that some rates would need to be so low as to make the net revenue gain for Government (once administration costs are accounted for) negligible.

    —  The Government also claims that "the cost of valuations should be managed through clear definitions of value and a self-assessment process". The CBI believes that the valuation process would still be very costly to administer as in previous attempts. The definitions of CUV and PV set out in the document are too simplistic and costly/lengthy disputes are inevitable in any valuing system. The self-assessment process may seem an improvement on previous attempts but by no means addresses all of the problems that are intrinsic to any value-based tax system. At the very least it is anticipated that a system of audits or spot checks to self-assessment would need to be put in place.

    —  The Government further claims that "PGS should be designed in a way which minimises avoidance opportunities". We believe that it is incredibly difficult to create a tax based on land values that minimise avoidance. It is therefore far from clear at this stage whether the Government has managed to improve this aspect from previous attempts.

    —  In the absence of cross-party support for PGS it is likely that—as happened previously—landowners and developers would defer development in the hope of repeal.

Self-assessment adds cost and time to planning process

  69.  The Government claims to have made the valuation process simpler by introducing the self-assessment process. However, the CBI believes that this process would still introduce significant additional administration costs and potential delays both before a business decides to enter into development ie when assessing the costs and benefits of a development project and in complying with the process once planning permission had been granted. Valuations are already one of the most complex and disputed elements of the tax system and PGS would require (at least) two such valuations for each site for which planning permission was sought, making the proposals unwieldy from the start.

  70.  Self-assessment would not necessarily decrease the administrative costs for the Government because of the need to regulate and monitor the valuations that businesses submit (even in a risk based approach) and the need to introduce an appeals process to handle disputes over valuations. Even in the absence of a formal appeal, there would inevitably be lengthy and costly negotiations between businesses and the Valuation Office Agency.

  71.  The ramifications of introducing a new stage to the planning process with an associated appeals process would be considerable. Complex sites, of which there are many, take time and resource to value. This resource would be an additional cost for business but also a significant cost for Government in ensuring there was sufficient human resource and expertise both centrally and locally to cope with the additional volume of work. The alternative would be to slow the rate of development even further.

  72.  It is unclear how the validation and risk based approach would work in practice, but what is clear is that developers would not start development until they had certainty in relation to their assessment. This would slow development down. It should be noted that this is a problem intrinsic to PGS that couldn't be mitigated by a low rate. There has been some discussion of a prior agreement process, but it is far from clear how this would work in practice.

  73.  There would need to be a formal validation process—otherwise there could also be impacts on corporate activity if an acquiring company was concerned about the Inland Revenue challenging previous self assessments.

  74.  Even developments where there was a relatively low uplift—and low PGS take—would have to undergo the same complex process. In this sense the tax is regressive and even small added costs could threaten development.

  75.  The extra costs of the self assessment process for business should not be under-estimated and would need to be mitigated, for example by being allowable against the tax charged.

Complexity of valuations would threaten to stifle the planning system

  76.  The CBI believes that any tax system based on land values, including PGS, is intrinsically flawed because:

    —  no two property developments are the same and therefore nearly all sites would require development appraisals (average or comparable valuations could not be used);

    —  calculating the value of land both before and after planning permission would have to take account of a number of variables and costs which would inevitably be debated between the developer and the Government's valuer. The degree of variability in valuations is often plus or minus 15% (and far more in some cases); and

    —  wherever the land valuations were disputed the District Valuer and possibly the Land Tribunal would have to be consulted, which would delay the start of development (with impacts on both costs and timescales).

  The proposed valuation system would therefore neither be as simple (or potentially fair) as the Government claims.

  77.  The valuation would need to take into account costs incurred prior to the planning permission, such as payments for access, decontamination, rights of lights, ransom strips and so forth, otherwise there would be significant overestimation of values and liabilities with a consequent impact on the viability of development. All acquisition and improvement costs must be factored in—the CUV in many cases would not capture this since the value would not necessarily be enhanced by such expenditure. If such costs were not taken into account a significant number of developments would become financially unviable and if the costs were taken into account many developments might have a negligible PGS liability where the low revenue would be outweighed by the cost of administration.

  78.  There is a presumption that the PUV would take account of all relevant future costs, output values, fees and so forth—but this is likely to be extremely complex (particularly where some costs may not be known) and could be contested. But there would be significant implications if valuations did not properly factor in these costs.

  79.  An example provided by Tesco illustrates this point. When hypothetically calculating the Planning Value of two mixed-use/regeneration sites (Dartford and Highham's Park), Tesco discovered that the price they paid for these sites reflected the "existing use property value of the individual property of interest and the cost of relocation or extinguishment of that interest". This is the opportunity cost to the seller and could therefore be defined as the Current Use Value. On both cases the Planning Value was very close to the CUV, which would have resulted in a zero or negligible PGS liability: very little gain in revenue for the Government but with administrative costs for both Tesco's self-assessment and the Government's regulation of the system. However, if the PGS calculation was as simplistic as that proposed with the assumption that values would be assessed on the basis of unencumbered freehold interest with vacant possession, these sites would have been unviable for redevelopment.

  80.  Even on "full" planning permissions, it is often the case that conditions will be imposed which require further details to be submitted for approval which could (depending on their ultimate form) affect the PV.

  81.  In short the points and definitions of valuation are too vague or inappropriate to be workable especially for commercial and industrial brownfield and mixed-use and shared-ownership sites and phased developments. The deterrent to development could be significant.

  82.  The proposed PGS system assumes that the land is freehold which immediately introduces a bias into the system. For example where the developer does not own the freehold but has a development lease the PGS liability would fall entirely on the lease-holder even though the free-holder would share in the uplift in value. This type of lease arrangement is relatively common in central urban areas. It is highly unlikely that the lease could be renegotiated—and even if it could, it is questionable whether such impacts on the market have been properly considered in relation to PGS. If this issue was not addressed, it could impact on the willingness to proceed with redevelopment and the process of urban renewal.

  83.  Given the complexities, there is significant scope for inaccurate valuations. And there would seem to be more likelihood of this leading to an over-estimation of PGS liabilities with consequent implications for the viability of development.

  84.  More widely, the process of redevelopment and renewal may be affected as companies seek to refurbish existing stock in ways which avoid the need for planning consent. For example, this would lead to more internal decoration rather than recladding buildings which would impact on the quality of the public realm and the ability of business to expand or up-grade their buildings.

PGS could jeopardise brownfield development

  85.  It is extremely difficult to see how PGS might work efficiently in relation to large scale, mixed use and complex developments that involve many partners, are phased and take many years.

  86.  The Government suggests that we should not be overly concerned about brownfield sites because the PGS is proportional. But the administrative costs of PGS falls equally whether it is in a low or high planning gain context—indeed the burden is likely to be greater for brownfield developments given the complexities.

  87.  There may be some developments where it is assumed that high returns would mean that PGS liability should not be a problem. However, these may be extremely high risk with little certainty about the ultimate returns—and PGS might deter such investment.

  88.  The Government implicitly seems to recognise some of the challenges by highlighting the possibility of a lower tax rate. There is a very strong case for this, but inevitably it would introduce new difficulties in definition and implementation. What is more the Government would need to assess the benefits/returns of a lower rate against the arguably higher costs of administering PGS for complex brownfield sites.

  89.  The Government also highlights the possibility of a threshold. If PGS was to be introduced, there would certainly need to be a threshold and most likely a number of different rates and exemptions. It is extremely difficult to identify what these should be and, again, this would introduce additional complexities and could create distortions. As a starting point, PGS should only apply where new and additional floor space was created—and then above a minimum threshold.

  90.  If the Government presses on with PGS, this needs to be addressed. Some people have suggested a value threshold, but this would require having to go through the valuation process which is a key problem.

  91.  The lack of a liquid market for brownfield land and the diverse existing planning permissions would also complicate the valuation process and impose a costly informational burden on developers. Some major companies have estimated that their valuation costs alone would increase by up to £500,000 per year.

Implications of market changes make PGS even more difficult

  92.  Paying PGS on expected value gain rather than actual gain is a significant issue and affects the perceived "fairness" of PGS. Changes in value do not just arise because of grant of planning permission but also as a result of wider factors such as market conditions.

  93.  We are concerned about what would happen in a number of scenarios:

    —  there are significant market changes (eg downturn) from when the PV and PGS are calculated to the actual delivery of the development which impacts on the value realised;

    —  the development may be phased and some phases may not start;

    —  the development may start but be substantially amended during construction; and

    —  the development may start with the intention of completion, but factors prevent this and cause it to be unfinished thus affecting its value.

Impractical Assessment and Payment Procedure

  94.  The CBI appreciates the Government's effort to put back the point of payment to commencement on site. However, the CBI still has concerns that it would be impractical to expect payment at this stage before any of the gain from planning permission had been realised. The commencement of development is one of the most expensive stages of development because businesses are outlaying significant sums in order to pay for the start of construction. In effect many businesses would need to increase borrowing in order to pay their PGS liability with no guarantee that the development would pay off. This adds to the risks and could make businesses more wary of entering into development, particularly for longer-term investments where profit may not be gained for a number of years.

  95.  This could also affect existing financial arrangements with lenders and investors and business models with impacts in the short term as developers sought to replace existing arrangements. It would also be likely to increase costs as earlier funding tends to be more expensive.

  96.  Many developments are phased in terms of their delivery and realisation of value. Also commercial developments built speculatively may remain vacant for some time after completion and potential tenants may be offered initial rent free periods. This means that developers may not see a return on their investment for some time. PGS will impact more on schemes that are not prelet, presold or divisible into phases or units. Large speculative developments that are an essential part of the property market will be disadvantaged.

  97.  Wider business investment eg in new distribution facilities, factories, offices would be based on longer term business plans and the value would not be realised at any specific point in time (rather it would flow through in the form of increased productivity, increased profits, etc). For such developments, having to pay more up front could affect their decision to proceed or wider investment decisions. Even where the value uplift—and thus the PGS liability—was not high, the complexities and administrative costs involved would be an issue.

Concern about resourcing pressures

  98.  We are concerned that the Government has not set out the direct cost or level of resourcing likely to be required to implement PGS. This would impact on both local authorities and other organisations. At a time when local authority resources and planning departments are stretched this is a real concern. The role that local authorities might play in administering and monitoring the PGS is unclear but it is likely that at least some of the burden would fall on them.

  99.  Set at a low and more "acceptable" level, the PGS would not justify the upheaval and substantial costs of implementation and administration and it is important to note that the inherent complexities of the tax would impact to some extent regardless of the rate.

Transitional impacts

  100.  It has been noted by some of those involved in the property industry that there are already impacts as a result of the PGS proposals, with a reluctance to finalise agreed figures for potential development sites.

  101.  In many cases, there would not be opportunities to pass the costs of PGS onto the landowner since the transactions would have taken place already. While for many developments this may be corrected in the longer term, there could be significant impacts on a large number of sites in the interim (and if the exact quantum of PGS liability was not known when purchasing land, pass-through would be more difficult than assumed). And, in the longer term, there would still be developments for which this would not be possible, for example where a business develops its own land.

  102.  The debate about PGS is creating significant uncertainty within the development industry and beyond. It is also likely to impact on the willingness of local authorities to develop schemes such as those in Milton Keynes and Ashford given the necessary lead time and resource commitment.

CONCLUSIONS

  103.  As highlighted, the CBI supports the aim to deliver more housing and greater investment in infrastructure but strongly believes that PGS is not the right way to achieve these objectives. The CBI is aware that the concept of a planning tariff/roof tax is favoured by some organisations while others favour improved section 106 agreements that contribute locally, potentially combined with an area-wide charge. A number of other options such as an enhanced planning obligations system, tax incremental financing or changes to the CGT regime have also been mooted.

  104.  However, there needs to be considerable work done on the details and wider implications for business and local communities before these or other schemes could be more widely applied. The CBI is willing to explore with the Government and others a range of options that may be more workable and acceptable to business than the current PGS proposals.


Memorandum by David Reed BSc DipTP DMS MRTPI, Director of Community & Environment Services, Canterbury City Council (PGS 44)

  Many observers appear to have great doubts about the proposals for a planning gain supplement (PGS), but I am firmly supportive of the idea having waited 25 years for a government to tackle the betterment issue. I believe the planning profession should be influencing the proposals in a positive way rather than opposing them. Although some of the detail has not been thought through yet, and there would be many practical implications, the concept is a good one. The objective of a new tax hypothecated for infrastructure purposes, in addition to legitimate s106 requirements, would be very valuable.

  The proposal at present does have a number of flaws which need to be addressed, the most basic of which is where the funds will go. There is only one acceptable answer to this, they must go back to the local level where the development occurs and the related infrastructure needs arise. The funds raised should not be diverted to the growth areas (which may need other sources) or distributed via a complicated bidding system but returned directly, without argument. Local level should mean none other than the local planning authority (LPA) concerned. This is vital to "incentivise" development and to satisfy the landowner, developer and local objectors that the tax is just and will enable the more general infrastructure concerns arising from the development to be addressed. Local authorities are now beginning to receive funds through the ODPM's local authority business growth incentive scheme and PGS receipts could be similar, automatic money as far as the authority is concerned and even more directly related to the decisions made locally.

  The funds raised should be dedicated to address infrastructure needs which arise more generally from development in an area but which are difficult to require from particular schemes. With a reasonably reliable stream of funds local authorities could use prudential borrowing powers to bring forward much needed infrastructure improvements which were holding back development in the area.

  To ensure transparency in the use of PGS funds each local planning authority could produce an annual statement setting out it's proposals for using PGS in it's area and what has been spent so far. This statement could be the subject of consultation with interested parties, and to ensure a fully rounded consideration of the needs of an area, could be debated by the local strategic partnership involving all the key local agencies.

  In relation to the use of PGS funds for "regional" needs, it is accepted that there will be some wider infrastructure requirements that cannot be addressed by each LPA alone, so I would accept a maximum of 30% of the funds could be used regionally or sub-regionally. But an alternative mechanism would be to allocate all the funds to LPAs and make them accountable for meeting wider needs by clubbing together to commission critical improvements from the appropriate agency.

  It might be desirable for there to be some redistribution of PGS funds from more prosperous areas to the less prosperous, for example in relation to housing completions or employment floorspace constructed, but only if the system would be grossly unfair without it because the direct link between planning decision and receipt should be maintained if at all possible.

  The other big problem is the relationship of PGS to the infrastructure provided directly by a scheme and secured by s106 agreements or similar. These agreements cannot be scaled back as far as is being suggested, they may need to include for example off site highway infrastructure and community facilities (including schools) in the case of larger schemes, anything in fact that is directly required for a scheme to go ahead acceptably or must be provided in a definite timescale in relation to that development. No developer (or community) will be prepared to rely on the PGS system to deliver time critical infrastructure in relation to a scheme, nor should the PGS system be required to do so as this could frustrate the speed that development could proceed.

  Finally, there is a critical issue about how the PGS should relate to the emerging roof tax systems being developed for major growth areas. Some of the strongest objection to the PGS idea comes from such areas, essentially on the grounds that current s106 agreements deliver more infrastructure than PGS will as currently proposed. There is a big danger that might turn out to be true unless the "directly required" test is applied more widely, giving LPAs in growth areas full scope to deliver what their area will need through the s106 mechanism. In case this approach might overlap with the collection and use of PGS, why not allow LPAs the option of conceding PGS will not apply in relation to a particular major scheme if it is satisfied that the s106 agreement is comprehensive enough to address all the issues raised. If it is the LPA's own money that is being conceded, that would be reasonable.

  As an alternative to PGS, the "tariff" approach, favoured by some, has significant disadvantages which should be recognised. A tariff approach in a typical local authority area differs from a roof tax in a major growth area in that it would be applied to a large number of small schemes across the council's area. Whilst some schemes like this are in place—and a few work well and are quite lucrative (West Berkshire is the best example I have come across)—most LPAs have not tackled the issue seriously yet. If the PGS idea falls every LPA will begin to develop it's own scheme, every one is bound to be different, leading to complexity for developers and inconsistencies between authorities. Inevitably there will need to be a process to endorse each tariff scheme before it will be fully accepted which could impose another burden on the LDF process. Then the tariffs will need to be collected by hard pressed development control officers as part of each individual planning application. There will be frequent claims that the tariff makes a scheme unviable, leading to a difficult dilemma or delay as valuers are brought in to advise. The effect of widespread tariff policies on the development control process is potentially a big issue, the job is hard enough already without the additional task of tax collection when dealing with relatively modest schemes. PGS would be so much simpler with the tax system fulfilling this task leaving development control officers to concentrate on their main role.

  There are considerable flexibility and fairness advantages of PGS. Tariffs do not relate well to the ability to pay since they tend to be inflexible flat rate figures based on development types. They are not sensitive to the scheme involved, and will require frequent updating to take account of changing needs and market conditions. PGS on the other hand would be a proportion of land value uplift which relates directly to the value and difficulties of each scheme and would rise and fall naturally as market conditions fluctuate.

  In conclusion, I am confident that with the changes outlined above the PGS can be made to work successfully. The loss of a taxation approach to this issue for another generation would be an historic missed opportunity, providing as it does a much needed opportunity to raise additional resources to tackle infrastructure shortfalls, which in turn can only speed up further housing and other development as those shortfalls are tackled.





 
previous page contents

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2006
Prepared 11 May 2006