UNCORRECTED TRANSCRIPT OF ORAL EVIDENCE To be
published as HC 1024-ii
House of COMMONS
MINUTES OF EVIDENCE
TAKEN BEFORE
OFFICE OF THE DEPUTY
PRIME MINISTER:
HOUSING, PLANNING,
LOCAL GOVERNMENT AND THE REGIONS COMMITTEE
Planning Gain Supplement
Monday 8 May 2006
MR JOHN CALCUTT, MR TREVOR BEATTIE and MR DENNIS
HORNE
MS BRIGID SIMMONDS
Evidence heard in Public Questions 121 -
207
USE OF THE TRANSCRIPT
1.
|
This is an uncorrected transcript of evidence taken in
public and reported to the House. The transcript has been placed on the
internet on the authority of the Committee, and copies have been made
available by the Vote Office for the use of Members and others.
|
2.
|
Any public use of, or reference to, the contents should
make clear that neither witnesses nor Members have had the opportunity to
correct the record. The transcript is not yet an approved formal record of
these proceedings.
|
3.
|
Members who
receive this for the purpose of correcting questions addressed by them to
witnesses are asked to send corrections to the Committee Assistant.
|
4.
|
Prospective
witnesses may receive this in preparation for any written or oral
evidence they may in due course give to the Committee.
|
Oral Evidence
Taken before the Office of the Deputy Prime Minister:
Housing, Planning, Local Government and the Regions
Committee
on Monday 8 May 2006
Members present
Mr Clive Betts
John Cummings
Mr Bill Olner
John Pugh
In the absence of the
Chairman, Mr Betts was called to the Chair
________________
Memorandum submitted by English Partnerships
Examination of Witnesses
Witnesses: Mr John Calcutt, Chief Executive, Mr Trevor Beattie, Corporate Strategy
Director and Mr Dennis Horne, Chief
Operating Officer, English Partnerships, gave evidence.
Q121 Mr Betts: Welcome to the Committee for our session on
planning gain supplement. Can I first
of all give the apologies of the Chairman of the Committee, Dr Phyllis Starkey
MP, who unfortunately has a visit in her constituency today at which she has to
be present. With that I will first of all
ask if you would, for the sake of our records, identify yourselves.
Mr Calcutt: Good afternoon,
gentlemen. My name is John Calcutt and
I am the Chief Executive of English Partnerships, I will add by way of a rider
of four-days standing. I have my colleagues
here, Dennis Horne and Trevor Beattie who I will ask to respond I think to the
majority of your questions.
Q122 Mr Betts: I hope that was not a plea for easy questions
- the fact you have been there for only four days. We accept that you will pass to your colleagues, that is only
appropriate. Could we begin by dealing
with the issue of the West Bedford scheme and also eventually the Milton Keynes
scheme as well. You referred to your
role in brokering the West Bedford scheme to deliver yours and the Government's
objectives. Could you explain how the
model works and the role that you played in developing it?
Mr Horne: In simple terms, there is a situation in
Bedford where 2,250 homes have been granted outline consent but subject to
funding of a by-pass road that was beyond the abilities of fragmented land
ownership, so English Partnerships was asked by the Government Office if we
would look into how we could assist the situation. We worked with ODPM, the Department for Transport as well as the
land owners, to broker a funding arrangement whereby we would forward-fund the
road but subject to a share of land value capture over and above the section
106 obligations of the land owners. So
in simple terms, we were acting as a banker in some respects who is investing
in the road contract but then taking a share of land values at a later date.
Q123 Mr Betts: So is it a collective form of 106 in a way?
Mr Horne: It is over and above the 106 obligations
which are placed on the land owners.
They are obviously funding the normal requirements but because the road
spreads over a number of different land interests it was not possible for them
to fund the infrastructure, it had to bridge various areas and the local river
there on I think two occasions, and there would have been disproportionate
impacts on different land owners. This
issue had actually held up development for over ten years.
Q124 Mr Betts: Do you think that sort of approach could be
replicated for similar schemes or even for different schemes of a significant
size in other parts of the country?
Mr Horne: I think it is possible depending on the
individual circumstances. I would add
that although English Partnerships were involved, we would not necessarily say
there is a single solution which is applicable without looking at the individual
circumstances. The principle of looking
at forward-funding infrastructure to unlock difficult planning areas and
permissions is something we could carry forward in other areas.
Q125 Mr Betts: If we had planning gain supplement, would you
not simply be able to collect the planning gain supplement from all the
different land owners, put it into a pot and do what you have done?
Mr Horne: There is a timing issue in that the planning
permissions could not come forward until, in this case, the funding solution
had been found for the road. That was
the impasse. There may have been other
niceties to the discussions but the reality was that the planning permissions
could not be unlocked until the road was funded, the land owners were unable to
have viable schemes with funding the road upfront, and it needed a public
sector injection to meet the initial costs to make it come forward. The planning gain supplement would come
after, as they went to start on site, but it would not provide the road
necessarily, although the exact mechanics of planning gain supplement have not
been worked out through the consultation document and it may be possible
through some of the monies which go into central government that monies could
be set aside either through the Communities Infrastructure Fund or other
sources to enable those types of strategic transport works to come forward in
advance of development.
Q126 Mr Betts: Moving on to the Milton Keynes tariff system
which we had some evidence on previously, is this scheme preferable to planning
gain supplement? Are you suggesting a
tariff scheme should run parallel to planning gain supplement? Is Milton Keynes not really a unique
situation which means that approach probably is not applicable to many other parts
of the country?
Mr Horne: The tariff situation, as you will be aware, is
based on looking at the infrastructure, both local and strategic, that is
required to support a fairly defined number of houses in terms of their growth
and employment opportunities. In Milton
Keynes we know in terms of designated areas for growth, 33,000 houses have to
come forward by 2016 and from the areas which are going in you can plot the
infrastructure that is required, look at the total costs and available sources
and then work back to a tariff which can be applied against individual housing
units and employment, so we end up with a calculation which says we need
£18,500 per house and something like £250,000 per hectare on employment to fund
all the infrastructure necessary to support the growth of Milton Keynes. There are three issues which I think are
fundamental to make the tariff work.
One is the co-operation of the land owners. We are somewhat fortunate in the Milton Keynes situation that
over 90 per cent of the land acquired is in the ownership of five owners. The co-operation of land owners is
important. Second, you need a
co-ordinated planning approach because it has to be based in planning
allocations which are coming forward.
Third, similar to the West Bedford scheme, you need the ability to
forward-fund infrastructure, so that in terms of the role English Partnerships
is playing we are still forward-funding elements of infrastructure in
co-operation with the highways authority and the Highways Agency to support
growth and then receiving payments back from developers as consents are granted
and development takes place.
Q127 Mr Betts: You indicated there is a backward working out
of how much we need to invest in infrastructure, divide it by how many houses,
and that is the amount per property, but when Milton Keynes came to speak to us
they said they had not got enough money for infrastructure and an additional
residue of funding was needed. Does
that suggest that the tariff was not set at a high enough level?
Mr Horne: The thing with the tariff is that it has to
be set at an amount which enables development to come forward and does not set
an artificial barrier to development, and it has to be done, as I said before,
in co-operation with the land owners.
It is cemented through an over-arching section 106 arrangement, and that
has to be defensible. That is why the
calculations are done to show that it is a defensible sum. Under the Milton Keynes model, some 100 per
cent of strategic infrastructure is funded and 75 per cent of all the local
infrastructure needs are funded. The
Council therefore on a bill of £1.6 billion has to find some £40-50 million to
make up the 25 per cent in local infrastructure, but they already receive
substantial amounts in terms of capital allocations from DfES for education and
through other government funding streams.
So in terms of the calculations we made, we believe it was a fair and
equitable funding arrangement which enabled existing funding sources to
continue but also for development to not be adversely affected. Just to make a final point in closing on
this, I think it is really important whether it is a tariff arrangement or a
PGS arrangement that it does not substitute for existing government funding
streams, and that is the way the MK tariff has been calculated. Milton Keynes Council's point is that they
have no certainty in the long-term government funding streams which have been
anticipated under the MK tariff.
Q128 Mr Olner: On the West Bedford one, are we talking about
land which was zoned for residential use or green belt land or agricultural
land, where there is a massive uplift in the value of the land? Or are we just talking about land which was
zoned residential where planning permission has been granted?
Mr Horne: It is land which is zoned for
residential. There is a substantial
uplift. I have to stress that there are
very complicated arrangements in terms of both the road that is going through
and also the requirements the local authority have placed on the developers
through section 106 arrangements. The
issue here is very much that to meet the obligations under section 106, which
involved meeting all of the costs of affordable housing without housing
corporation grant, and building of the schools and so forth in advance of
development, they could not viably bring forward the cost of the road as
well. As I say, there has been an
impasse there for some ten years.
Q129 Mr Olner: Milton Keynes have given us evidence, as Mr
Betts alluded to, and were fairly sceptical as to whether the scheme they had
got for the tariff would work anywhere else.
Milton Keynes is a new town compared to many areas of the UK, have they
got a unique position with the housing corporation and the fact they were a new
town?
Mr Horne: I would not say they have a unique position;
not entirely. The position is where you
have a comprehensive area for development, you can plan out exactly across that
area what is required to support growth and the different funding sources and
infrastructure requirements to make it happen sustainably. I would have thought there are examples in
other places where that could happen in terms of new towns, as you have alluded
to them, without naming places but within the growth areas.
Q130 Mr Olner: Could you make a stab at one?
Mr Horne: It is invidious to do that but Harlow is
within the growth area where it may work in terms of the growth to the north of
Harlow. But the point I wanted to make
is that you have to have a willing land owner who wants to enter into these arrangements,
and if you have a fragmented approach where you have umpteen land owners it is
going to be very difficult to construct a tariff arrangement in that
situation. At Milton Keynes we were
very fortunate that you could get the five major land owners who hold over 95
per cent of the land allocated for the expansion of the town into this
arrangement and then, because it is based very much on local and strategic
needs, you could enforce that against other planning applications as they come
forward.
Q131 Mr Olner: You did say, Mr Horne, that there are varied
interests in the provision of infrastructure to increase areas of residential
housing. There is the local one, there
is the regional one, there is a national one.
Given that this tax is going to go firstly to the Treasury, how do you
see that being redistributed to all of
the players ie local, regional and national?
Mr Beattie: English Partnerships' contention of course is
that there would be scope under PGS to run a tariff alongside the PGS
mechanism. Where local authorities and
groups of local authorities can get together, where the conditions which Dennis
has mentioned would be satisfied, where the right relationship exists between
the uplift to be captured on the site and the cost of the infrastructure, there
is scope to get together to produce a tariff.
In our consultation response, we have suggested in that situation the
top slice, the 20 per cent Communities Infrastructure Fund, should still be
chargeable but otherwise the area should be exempt from planning gain
supplement so it should not go up to the Treasury in the first place.
Q132 Mr Olner: But most of us who have been representing
coalfield communities for many years know about the problems we had with
additionality with the money we had from Europe to boost the
infrastructure. It would be very easy,
would it not, for national government to keep to itself some of that planning
gain supplement instead of feeding into the infrastructure they would normally
fund?
Mr Beattie: That is why our contention right at the front
of our consultation response is that this should be seen as additional, and
what is raised should be additional to and there should be no take from central
government.
Q133 Mr Olner: What would you do about the geographical
problems of some people being able to raise more planning gain supplement but
have a harder fist to fight for a better section 106 than others? How would you smooth out within the planning
gain supplement the differences between the North East and the North West, and
the South East and South West?
Mr Beattie: Planning gain supplement generates more value
where there is a higher value uplift to be achieved, but that is already the
case in the coalfield areas where English Partnerships spends
disproportionately more, where values are low and there is very little value to
be unlocked. We already do that in
support of section 106. We will
continue to do that in support of planning gain supplement. That is one of the merits of a national
agency like English Partnerships.
Q134 John Pugh: You favour a mixed economy - section 106
agreements, planning gain supplements and tariff based systems. It could be argued that is slightly
confusing for the developers, they do not have predictability, they do not have
clarity, they do not know what they are going to be hit by. Is that a fair surmise and does it matter
anyway?
Mr Beattie: Certainty for developers is the key to
this. Whatever system of planning gain
supplement comes out, it should be based around giving a clear, transparent and
certain system for developers. It is
our contention that you can implement PGS to provide such certainty, although a
lot of the details are not in here yet, but that the tariff is a very simple
arrangement of developers using enlightened self-interest effectively to get
together to define what they need and get the resources for what they need; a
very clear prospectus. It is perfectly
possible to achieve the same through PGS but the consultation as it stands at
present has not sketched that out.
Q135 John Pugh: What would be the consequences of a degree of
uncertainty?
Mr Beattie: They would be a possible reduction in the
amount of land coming forward for development.
Q136 John Pugh: You argue for greater research to be done on
the impact of removing education from section 106 agreements. Why do you do that?
Mr Beattie: Our response included seven case studies and
when we ran them we found that education accounted for the vast majority,
between 45 and 80 per cent, of the section 106 which English Partnerships would
no longer be paying under the new system.
A lot of what we currently do centres around the provision of new
primary schools - for example the new school at Greenwich, the new school at
Northampton - because we find you need
the school to attract the high quality development, you cannot wait for the
development to come along and provide the school later. It determines most people's choice of
community and where they want to live.
So we think that education funding is very central to this. If you included education funding within the
site-specific section 106, you would in effect be acknowledging the way people
treat and relate to their local primary school; it is a local, site-specific
facility servicing that community.
Q137 John Cummings: In your memorandum you include a number of
case studies which show that the impact of the introduction of PGS would vary
greatly depending on the rate at which it is set. How adequate can any assessment of the impact of PGS be without
the knowledge of the rate at which it is to be set?
Mr Beattie: We had to take a series of assumptions and
our case studies are based on assumed rates of PGS of 20 per cent. We have made a number of other assumptions
as well just to work it through, but we worked it through on a consistent
basis. What I would say about those
case studies is that they are real sites, they are seven real sites, and what
they show is on unviable brownfield sites, as we know, no PGS is payable, on
some of the most marginal sites, because there is only a marginal uplift in
land values, there would be an overall reduction in the PGS/section 106 burden
under the new system. In other words,
part of my answer to the coalfield site issue is actually the amount of take
from them will reduce increasing their viability.
Q138 John Cummings: So you are quite confident in the studies you
have carried out?
Mr Beattie: We are confident in the studies we carried
out on the basis of the assumptions which we have taken where the information
did not exist in the consultation document.
We have made assumptions.
Q139 John Cummings: If the Government were to proceed with its
proposals for PGS, at what level do you think the rate should be set? What do you consider to be a modest amount?
Mr Beattie: It is not for us to speculate on what a
modest amount is, it is for ministers to set the rate.
Q140 John Cummings: But you argue that a modest rate of PGS can
be absorbed in some areas. What would
be a modest rate for my area in the North East, do you think?
Mr Beattie: It is not for us to take a view on that. We have run it through at a rate of 20 per
cent and the figures are there in our consultation response.
Q141 Mr Betts: You are the experts in development, are you
not? You know what works and what does
not work, so I think we have an interest in knowing what your view is of the
rate.
Mr Beattie: We think at 20 per cent it works. Can I give an example of why I think at 20
per cent it works which I know reasonably well? One of our examples is a greenfield site where at 20 per cent the
take from PGS and section 106 under the new system is greater than the existing
section 106 take. If you run at a rate
of 15 per cent, interestingly the old and the new system takes are exactly the
same. That is for a greenfield site
needing substantial infrastructure.
That suggests to me that for that sort of site, that is roughly the
right area.
Q142 John Cummings: I am trying to tease a bit more out of you
here. Is the rate of PGS which could be
absorbed before PGS becomes a disincentive to investment consistent across the
country or does it vary with different types of development and different
locations?
Mr Beattie: It varies very dramatically. On page 8 of our consultation document we
show that the PGS rate at which PGS and new section 106 would equate to the old
106 for greenfield sites actually varies between 7 per cent and 22.5 per
cent. So it is very variable site to
site.
Q143 John Cummings: You have mentioned the PGS rate set at 20 per
cent, is this a cash equivalent of developers' contributions to infrastructure
provision, or would it actually be less under PGS than it is at present?
Mr Beattie: That depends on the site, it depends on the
section 106 obligations already on the site.
As I was explaining, on some sites the new system under our figures
shows you will be paying less, on some it shows you will be paying more.
Q144 John Cummings: Why do you argue that only a low rate of PGS
can be accommodated?
Mr Beattie: Because the new system will apply
comprehensively to development across the piece. It is equitable in that respect in that it applies to development
across the piece, whereas currently only about 40 per cent of development is
subject to section 106 obligations.
Q145 Mr Betts: Is there a case for a variable rate?
Mr Beattie: I do not think so, no. We were talking about clarity and certainty
and a complex range of different rates would obstruct that clarity and
certainty. We have, however, suggested
there might be a case for a discount of the rate for five-star environmental
developments, actually linking up fiscal policy and environmental policy. We think there is a great opportunity to do
that here. But a framework of different
rates - no.
Q146 Mr Olner: It is okay having planning gain supplement if
that raises more revenue for infrastructure than 106 does, but if you are going
to have a rigid 106 system and it is argued the reason for bringing in planning
gain supplement is that some authorities are better at negotiating 106
agreements than others, there is going to be some disparity. How do we bridge that? Mr Horne is nodding so he knows what I am
saying.
Mr Horne: It is obvious if you apply a constant rate
across the country, it will have different impacts in different areas. English Partnerships are not saying it will
not. What we are saying is that if you
are bringing in planning gain supplement, you need to do it in a way which
gives absolute clarity to the developers.
We are sub-dividing, as it were, the section 106 negotiations because
certain elements are staying under section 106 and others are going under
planning gain supplement. From a
development point of view, that is a benefit if they gain certainty through
that and there is a value to that certainty.
When we look at the consistency argument, it is important we have a consistent
rate.
Mr Calcutt: To add slightly on
that, I think you substitute the characteristics of the site for the planning
skills and abilities of the local authority which is doing the
negotiations. In other words, obviously
you are going to lose the input of what I would call key negotiators, but on
the other hand you are going to more equitably distribute the tax insofar as
its impact, as I understand it, is going to be those intrinsically difficult
sites with low inherent land values which are automatically going to have a
lesser tax payment than those which are intrinsically more valuable in areas
where you need less infrastructure.
That seems to me to be a level of equity that is wholly desirable rather
than, as it were, key negotiating powers bringing about an anomaly.
Q147 Mr Olner: But in shire counties the major planning
authority is the district, and it is usually the district which does the
negotiation on 106. How widely is that
going to be spread in the future? As I
said before, you have local infrastructure to provide, the local authority
ones, you have regional, the shire county ones, and then you have national
ones. At the moment you have one clear
negotiator for the section 106 stuff.
It seems to me that this issue is going to be clouded in the future in
providing infrastructure because it does not only rest with one set of people.
Mr Beattie: There will continue to be one clear
negotiator for the site-specific element of section 106, but for the national
infrastructure there will be the Communities Infrastructure Fund.
Q148 Mr Olner: So it is essential that as well as planning
gain supplement there is also section 106 agreement as well?
Mr Beattie: Under this new system, site-specific
infrastructure will continue to be negotiated in the same way but for a
narrower range of facilities.
Q149 John Pugh: I think we are reaching a view that you
accept there is going to be a degree of diversity, although we are not in a
position to be able to say how much diversity and what degree of clarity we are
going to have here, but taken in the round you also seem to be saying that the
new system will generate more money by increased land values for the public
good than the previous section 106 agreements by themselves. That is fairly common ground, is it not?
Mr Beattie: Yes.
Q150 John Pugh: Do you think it is going to be significantly
more to the extent there will be a real substantial uplift in the amount of
money available for strategic infrastructure?
Mr Calcutt: Can I start and then
let my colleagues come in? I think it
depends how you are drafting the tax.
We have seen previous attempts to tax windfall gains and they have run
into enormous efficiency problems insofar as the cost of administration and all
the rest, and things get locked up in litigation for years, and the practical
take is poor. I think there are two
sides to whether you achieve it. Does
it in principle, if the model is just dropped out and everybody paid their due
amount? The numbers equation is, as I
understand it, that it would raise significantly more revenue. On the other hand, if in fact practically
the way the tax is administered results in it being bogged down with every
chartered surveying company and legal firm inside the country and offshore,
then clearly as a matter of practice you are not going to get the revenue take
you want. So the devil is in the
drafting of detail which enables this thing to be what I would call efficiently
administered.
Q151 John Pugh: So when the regulation and legislation come
forward, there is a need for real scrutiny?
Mr Calcutt: As a former lawyer,
I would say this is going to be a parliamentary draftsman's either nightmare or
paradise, I know not which. Certainly
the devil is in the detail here.
Q152 John Pugh: If the planning gain supplement raises less
than section 106 does at present, does that mean in fact the tax rate is too
low or that the purpose of the introduction of PGS itself is frustrated?
Mr Calcutt: I am going to push my luck here and say to
you that the dilemma is that if you set the tax rate too high then clearly the
incentives people have for going down the route that I have described in terms
of trying to avoid paying this thing with schemes or just withholding it in the
hope that it will change in the future, which is a common one, and again go up
on a curve, and so part of the cleverness of this, I think, is first the
drafting but also setting rates at a point at which perhaps people's incentive
for avoidance is not going to be as high as it otherwise might have been.
Q153 John Pugh: So the Government, like a good parasite,
should not kill off its host?
Mr Beattie: One or two of the proposals in our
consultation paper were designed exactly to hit this point. We argue that the payment should be phased;
it should not all be up front at the point of starting on site but, as happens
as present in Milton Keynes, it should be 25 per cent up front and 75 per cent
on completion so you can give an incentive through the operation of the system
for developers to come forward with sites.
Q154 John Pugh: How long do you think it is going to take the
land markets to adjust to the new regime?
Mr Beattie: One of our submissions is that the
transitional arrangements for this are going to be absolutely crucial. I do not think it will take the markets
terribly long to adjust. I think the
short term impact will in many cases be a reduction in the value of sites
because the PGS will in effect be taken off the site value. That might work in favour of those of us
trying to bring forward major strategic developments but there is going to be a
period of transition, it is going to be very important to protect the tariff
arrangements in that transition and markets will certainly swing around before
they stabilise under the new system.
Q155 John Pugh: In arguing for greater simplicity and
clarity, as you have, do you think there should be a scheme that allows a very
few exemptions rather than a lot of well argued, cogent exemptions?
Mr Beattie: Yes.
I do not see the need for exemptions.
If you have a site with very little or no value you will pay no
tax. On brownfield sites, as we have
shown in our case studies, where there is very little uplift, there will be
little planning gain supplement to pay, and by and large on serious brownfield
sites there is less tax under the new system than under the old system. It is to some extent a self-regulating tax:
the more uplift, the more tax.
Q156 John Cummings: What is the merit of exempting sites with
option agreements from PGS liability?
Mr Calcutt: As a former developer perhaps I am qualified
to answer on this one.
Q157 John Cummings: I thought you said you were a lawyer.
Mr Calcutt: I was the company solicitor and subsequently
I became chief executive of a major house builder, and so I do both, I am
afraid. I think that "option" is a generic
term for those parcels of land that have been secured on fixed terms that we
are holding at the moment, so it will cover conditional contracts, options,
uplifts and the like. The only point
there is that lots of developers and house builders have entered into
agreements that provide for a specific sum to be paid on the grant of planning
permission and in the event that a tax is then levied on that those contracts
will probably plunge the developments themselves into deficit or sub-normal
profits which again will have one of two effects. You will either have people carrying out the very sorts of
avoidance tricks they can get away with or, much more probably, simply sitting
on land, not bringing it forward for development, causing housing supply to
move sharply downwards, trying to wait out the consequences of a bad
contract. I think it would have very
undesirable effects and would damage the house building industry. Whether that is a good or a bad thing I do
not know.
Q158 Mr Betts: Would there not be a case then for saying
that if sites with option agreements on them are going to be exempt that
exemption only applies for a period of time to encourage the development of
those sites because once the time runs out there is not going to be the
exemption?
Mr Calcutt: That does sound as though it would have quite
a lot of merit in it. The only thing I
would say is that quite a lot of options and conditional contracts take land
now ten years before it comes forward and it is then promoted through the
planning system and therefore we are talking about very long timescales
here. I think the sort of thing that
you are talking about might well be able to be achieved by other means.
Mr Beattie: Linking the planning system to it.
Q159 Mr Betts: You might like to reflect on that and let us
have a note about it because I understand it is a technical issue. Perhaps you would like to give us a note
after the meeting on your further thoughts on that. Let us come back to the point we were discussing before about
your general commitment to hypothecating planning gain supplement going to the
local authority where the development is taking place. I heard what you said about English
Partnerships being the knight in shining armour that goes into places like the
coalfields and assists where there is not the money for infrastructure
development around, but is there not a danger that if we concentrate all or the
vast majority of the resources from planning gain supplement in those areas
with high land values we are simply going to add to the overheating in those
areas?
Mr Beattie: We are also going to provide more resource in
order to tackle the consequences in terms of strategic infrastructure of that
overheating. You will be generating
more resources where you need more strategic infrastructure. You have to have a body like English
Partnerships in existence to deal with areas like the coalfields, but this
generates resource where it is needed.
Q160 Mr Betts: We are quite convinced that we have
sufficient, say, in the south east to provide all the sewage and the water and
the transport infrastructure that is needed?
Mr Beattie: The Treasury has said that the Community
Infrastructure Fund will be an additional sum and on their figures that is 20
per cent of the total planning gain supplement, albeit a substantial amount of
additional resource, to deal with strategic infrastructures.
Q161 Mr Betts: You do say that there might be an element of
redistribution, that essentially most of it should go to the local planning
authority.
Mr Beattie: Yes.
Q162 Mr Betts: Have you got an idea of the proportion? Have you got a figure in mind?
Mr Beattie: The consultation document talks about 80 per
cent going back to the local area and 20 per cent for the Community
Infrastructure Fund, and that certainly seems to be about the right level from
where we are coming from.
Q163 Mr Betts: If we are then going to hypothecate and
ring-fence most of the money is there any case for keeping existing tariff
systems?
Mr Horne: Obviously we are a little while away from the
planning gain supplement coming into force and therefore it is a mechanism that
promotes and accelerates development at this point in time. The point was previously made about
transitional arrangements and I think it needs to be looked at very carefully
through the transitional arrangements for PGS because nobody will enter into
tariff arrangements unless they get some sort of conditions regarding how
planning gain supplement will impact on the tariff arrangements. For instance, in Milton Keynes the tariff arrangements
are entered into by the landowners but only on the basis that they do not get
doubly taxed through planning gain supplement, so if planning gain supplement
comes in in a number of years' time to the extent that that duplicates the
arrangements under the tariff there will have to be some system of refund to
them. The sooner the transitional
arrangements are clear the more confidence people will have to continue
entering into tariff arrangements to accelerate developments in the meantime.
Mr Calcutt: The point that I think we are making is no
more than, when circumstances permit and enlightened self-interest bring the
public and private sectors together to try and cut a deal to bring development
forward or do things more efficiently by agreement, then it would be a shame if
that opportunity were no longer available and there was some mechanism for
saying, okay, you have struck a good deal here, maybe more than you might get
under the tariff for an accelerated programme or some such economic bargain,
and in those circumstances should you be precluded from doing so? That is, I guess, the only logic that you
can apply.
Mr Beattie: That is why our consultation response says
that tariffs should only be allowed to run alongside PGS where they would raise
at least as much as PGS.
Q164 John Cummings: You appear to be wary of the extent to which
self-assessment is likely to work. Do
you not think it is a valuable way of reducing bureaucracy or do you believe it
is just a recipe for tax avoidance?
Mr Beattie: We are wary because we think that the detail
and the information is not in the consultation document. There was a pledge to consult further on
self-assessment. A lot more detail is
necessary. Self-assessment as it stands
is a perfectly good mechanism for doing this; indeed, you would probably need
an army of inspectors to do it any other way, but the information simply does
not exist on self-assessment. There
will be a natural check and balance in the system, ensuring that developers
will want to put a proper assessment down of their PGS liability because they
will not want to be hit subsequently with any uncertainty over the land or the
development and so we think that self-assessment can work very well but the
information just is not there and a lot more guidance is needed.
Q165 John Cummings: What mechanism for assessment would you
prefer?
Mr Beattie: I think we have said that self-assessment
would work very well but we need more guidance on it. I do not think it could work with a central inspectorate assessing
it.
Q166 John Cummings: So you are quite happy with self-assessment?
Mr Beattie: We need more details on it. The principle of self-assessment is fine.
Q167 John Cummings: Do you have any alternatives in mind?
Mr Calcutt: No. I
think that any alternative would be a bureaucratic nightmare, so I think what
you need to have is self-assessment backed up with the very clearest guidelines
on how those assessments are carried out and some fairly interesting penalties
should that system be abused. That is
the best you can do.
Q168 John Cummings: What appeals system would you envisage?
Mr Calcutt: I would go along the line that, where
applications were made, in the circumstances where people made valuations or
views that had no reasonable basis in reality then I would be expecting very
significant penalties for clear, dishonest behaviour to be imposed, like
multiples of the tax.
Mr Beattie: The evaluation of this will take a view on
all these matters, and they will be running the system and checking
self-assessments.
Q169 John Pugh: Is the Community Infrastructure Fund,
together with regional funds, an essential ingredient for the PGS proposals to
work effectively?
Mr Beattie: Yes, we think it is fundamental to PGS
working because PGS pivots on the distinction between site-specific
infrastructure and the broader strategic infrastructure which the Community
Infrastructure Fund will make available.
One of the fundamental pieces of logic behind here is, as I have said
before, the additional resource it will free up for that essential strategic
infrastructure.
Q170 John Pugh: You cannot think of any other mechanisms that
might be used to overcome the gap between the point at which investment is
required and the PGS revenue flows?
Mr Beattie: You are talking about phasing and timing?
Q171 John Pugh: Yes.
Were it not there, what other mechanisms are perceivable?
Mr Beattie: Plenty of other mechanisms are
conceivable. It would be perfectly
practicable to use the existing section 106 procedure to create a Community
Infrastructure Fund. There are plenty
of other ways of doing it but the good thing about this is that it is built
into the structure of PGS and the Treasury have said it will be additional.
Q172 John Pugh: With regard to the national element of the
Community Infrastructure Fund who do you think should be administering
that? Would English Partnerships seek a
role?
Mr Beattie: We could certainly be one candidate,
yes. It will need a body with a more
than just a local or regional overview in order to distribute that money fairly
and take a view on major cross-regional infrastructure.
Q173 John Pugh: So you would not mind dispensing capital or
helping to distribute that?
Mr Beattie: Certainly we would be one candidate for that
role.
Mr Calcutt: Obviously, it can be used in an integrated
manner to the extent that one can have infrastructure pump-priming viable
regeneration, and we can bring those together.
I think we would have something to offer in that particular
circumstance.
Q174 Mr Betts: You have looked into certain exemptions to
PGS and you have talked about the Code for Sustainable Homes and that the land
on which homes that met that might be exempt from PGS. Again, it is another exemption into the
system. Is it reasonable for developers
which, for example, install grey water recycling to say that they are exempt
from PGS when surely the demands those developments place on the infrastructure
are not actually much different?
Mr Beattie: Can I just talk you through what we
propose? We do not propose a complete
exemption. We propose a reduced
rate. We do not propose that such
developments - and for the sake of consistency let us call them five-star
developments - should be exempt from the Community Infrastructure Fund because
they make just as big a draw on strategic infrastructure, but it does seem to
us self-evident that developments that have a very high level of environmental
sustainability, that use less water, that are more energy efficient, should be
encouraged and they will by definition make less demand on local services than
inefficient forms of development.
Therefore we think this is a great opportunity to tie up environmental
and fiscal policies and provide incentives for high quality development that we
need particularly in the growth areas, for the reasons you have given.
Q175 Mr Betts: So would a calculation have to be done in
some way to ensure that the reduction on demand on local infrastructure that
came from having these environmentally friendly homes was no different from the
reduction in the planning gain supplement?
Mr Beattie: No.
We would create a whole industry if we allowed some kind of
proportionality. We are proposing quite
a simple reduction for homes that meet a five-star rating under the proposed
code. It would be a set reduction.
Q176 Mr Betts: How much would it be?
Mr Beattie: We have not made proposal. It would be a discount. We would need to model that and it is one of
the areas we have said we are going to do further work on.
Q177 Mr Betts: Do you really think that the current Draft
Code for Sustainable Homes is sufficient to merit a reduction or do you think
it ought to go further?
Mr Beattie: I am talking about very high quality
developments, whether they are EcoHomes excellent. However they are measured, we are talking about high quality
developments.
Mr Calcutt: We would have a single standard. For the purposes of the proposition one
would stay with the only game in town at the moment, which is EcoHomes. We would just say that if this was EcoHomes
excellent, or excellent plus as the hurdle rate rises, then against that single
top standard there would be a discount for those that were able to achieve it
and whatever elements it would have to contain in its new and expanded form.
Q178 Mr Betts: In terms of housing and non-housing, if this
discount were offered for certain housing schemes do you think there is a
danger that that might skew the market in favour of housing development or
would you consider offering some discount to eco-friendly non-housing schemes?
Mr Beattie: It should relate to commercial as well, but
we are trying to skew the market in favour of high quality environmentally
friendly development.
Q179 Mr Betts: Does that mean you would have to have
therefore a set standard for eco-friendly commercial development as well?
Mr Calcutt: There is one. The same system in principle applies to both . The Building Research Establishment has
EcoHomes for domestic and something called BREAM for commercial, so all the standards
are there and all the measuring equipment is available to do that.
Mr Betts: We probably will have one or two more
questions to follow up on in writing to you on technical points as well the one
we asked you to come back on about option agreements. Thank you very much indeed for giving your evidence.
Memorandum submitted by Business in Sport and Leisure Limited
Examination of Witness
Witness: Ms Brigid Simmonds, Chief Executive,
Business in Sport and Leisure Limited, gave evidence.
Q180 Mr Betts: Welcome and thank you for attending our
session. Can I begin, as I did before,
by giving apologies for Dr Phyllis Starkey, Chair of the committee, who is in
her constituency on important business this afternoon. Would you for the sake of our record like to
introduce yourself?
Ms Simmonds: Thank you, Chair. My name is Brigid Simmonds.
I am the Chief Executive of Business in Sport and Leisure, which is an
umbrella organisation for sport, leisure and hospitality companies. I would also like to give evidence on behalf
of the Tourism Alliance of which I am Chairman, which is 46 different trade
associations, very much the voice of tourism, and I am also Chairman of the
CCPR, which is 270 voluntary bodies and governing bodies of sport.
Q181 Mr Betts: You wear a number of hats. If we restrict PGS in any way on
commercial-type developments is that not going to skew the market? If PGS is charged, say, on housing
developments would that not be more fair?
Ms Simmonds: Our concern is the opposite, particularly if
you are going to give the PGS to local authorities to distribute, that local
authorities are only going to be interested in receiving planning applications
from those types of development which produce high value and that is everything
other than sport and leisure. There is
not a value in sport and leisure types of development. They struggle to pay the site costs you
would spend on retail, commercial or offices, and that is our main concern,
that you would be further restricting a market that already suffers from the
fact that very few local authorities think about it when they are putting
together local development frameworks and regional spatial strategies.
Q182 John Cummings: Why do you believe that PGS is inherently
more complicated for commercial sites than for residential sites?
Ms Simmonds: I do not think it is inherently more complicated,
although I have various reservations about how the scheme would work. Our concerns are mainly to do with the fact
that you have to recognise where that value lies. Most of the things that I represent are things that should be
provided for the community anyway. BISL
has given evidence twice to ODPM when they have been considering their planning
guidance on housing. Both times they
failed to put into that guidance the requirement for the sorts of facilities in
leisure or in sport which are needed by people if they are going to have new
housing development. You need a
community pub, you need a sports centre, and whilst section 106 agreements have
worked in some places very well they have been patchy. You need those types of development and
there needs to be leadership from the top to ensure that happens.
Q183 John Cummings: If a distinction has to be made between
residential and non-residential development for PGS assessment, how should the
Government deal with mixed-use sites?
Ms Simmonds: Kate Barker only recommended that this
planning gain supplement applied to housing, so I think that is the starting
point, and I think it is obvious that there is a planning gain uplift when you
develop a housing site. That planning
gain uplift is not so obvious when you come to leisure or some other forms of
commercial development. We would prefer
to stick with the section 106 agreements which we already have. If I could give you some examples,
particularly where it has worked well for sports, in Catterick on a £196,000
project for new pitches for drainage for sports pitches section 106 contributed
£38,000. In Sandy Town, that place on
the A1 that you come to in Bedfordshire, again for drainage and changing rooms,
the total project cost £800,000 and £250,000 came from section 106
agreements. We believe that we would be
better off keeping the section 106 agreements.
The alternative, if you keep planning gain, is that you have a system specifically
for sports-based projects where part of that distribution is mandatorily
providing sports facilities.
Q184 John Cummings: Do you have any suggestions or ideas for how
the Government should deal with mixed-use sites?
Ms Simmonds: If the planning gain supplement only worked
for housing and it was a mixed-use site then obviously it would not apply to
other forms of development within it. I
agree with the previous witnesses that if you have a phased development you
should only be paying your planning gain supplement as the various phases continue. A further complication is how you value
those sites. A lot of sites are bought
with hope value in mind. Are they going
to have the planning gain supplement based on the value they bought it for or
the actual value which is assessed by somebody when they come to develop the
site? The alternative for us is that
either you only apply planning gain supplement to housing or you apply it to
the rest of the schemes but have something that specifically encourages sport
and leisure development.
Q185 John Pugh: You argue, and we had some difficulty in
following the point here, that leisure developments do not generate the same
revenue as retail and housing developments and "cannot afford to pay high
prices for site development", but is that kind of disparity not taken into
account in the way the PGS is calculated in the first place? In other words, if the land uplift is
greater then so is the PGS liability. I
do not see how it makes any difference.
Ms Simmonds: It only makes the difference because the
sorts of development we are talking about you want to encourage and if PGS acts
as a disincentive then there will not be any encouragement for those facilities
to be provided in the first place.
Q186 John Pugh: But why would it act as a disincentive?
Ms Simmonds: Because it does not provide the value and
therefore the local authority is not going to get the sort of value that it
wants in order to do the rest of its infrastructure developments.
Q187 John Pugh: I see; so it is going to alter the behaviour
of local authorities in terms of what they will allow to be developed or not?
Ms Simmonds: Yes.
Q188 John Pugh: Why particularly should they do that, because
after all local authorities have a lot of interest in providing leisure
facilities for their communities because they are the voters, they are the
constituents, they are the people who turn out at elections and so on, whereas
housing is often for people who are not currently part of that community?
Ms Simmonds: One reason is that there is no evidence at
the moment that local authorities do provide, particularly at planning officer
level or in local development frameworks, planning guidance which is specific
to leisure developments. In fact, I
mention in my evidence that I hope later this month ODPM will be publishing their
good practice guide -----
Q189 John Pugh: That in a sense is a separate point. Under the current section 106 agreements
local authorities make far more from giving the go-ahead to a supermarket or a
housing development than they will for allowing leisure development. I do not see why PGS would change that in
any way because local authorities at the moment get more money out of allowing
those sorts of developments and yet do go ahead in allowing, presumably, a fair
number of leisure and community developments as well.
Ms Simmonds: They do, but in our view they do not provide
enough. Many pubs provide CCTV for town
centres all over the place under section 106 agreements. I think the scheme has been given more
certainty over the last few years.
There have been two reviews of section 106 agreements. I think the scheme works very well, so why
do we need to introduce a further scheme which can only be seen as a tax on
development?
Q190 John Pugh: But if your thinking is correct and local
authorities have an opportunity to acquire funds which possibly they cannot at
the moment, would not the average local authority, looking at local authority
expenditure currently on leisure, which is by their own acknowledgement fairly
low, want precisely those sorts of funds to put back into community provision
and leisure facilities, not necessarily private facilities but nonetheless good
public leisure facilities?
Ms Simmonds: The South West Regional Sports Board three
years ago put out a policy that they would only fund certain local authorities
if they put section 106 agreement funding into sport. I telephoned them this morning and they agreed that it has had
almost no effect at all on the local authority. Some local authorities are very good. maybe the top 30 per cent,
but an awful lot of local authorities do not see it as a priority, and I think
particularly where we have a situation such as now where it is a government
objective to increase participation in healthy activity by one per cent a year,
and in fact it is even a target for both the Departments of Health and
Education, there is a concern about how sport and leisure fit into it. If you look at page 27 of the consultation
draft it actually suggests that leisure facilities will be outside the remit of
planning gain supplement and if that were the case maybe we would not need to
have this conversation. What is perhaps
stark in this is that there is no mention of sport at all one way or the
other. It may be that there was a consideration
that it was included within leisure facilities but otherwise if you have no
exemption to this you are going to be in many cases taxing things that are
funded by the National Lottery, that are funded out of the public purse, and
then you are going to put a tax on them to develop it further.
Q191 John Pugh: Is a fair way of summing up what you are
saying that there are some authorities who are authorities who are virtuous,
who give priority to leisure, use section 106 agreements and planning gain if
they get it for the right causes, in order to provide community and leisure
facilities, and there are other local authorities who are profiteering, if you
like, and will try to get what gain they can wherever they can and will give
priority to retail and housing? Given
that point, are you saying that the new regime will accentuate or encourage the
bad authorities to be worse, if I can put it like that, and the virtuous
authorities to cease to be so virtuous?
Ms Simmonds: Yes, absolutely.
Q192 Mr Betts: Sport England apparently have argued that the
public sector and not-for-profit organisations might well be exempt from
planning gain supplement but you seem to be going an awful lot further and
arguing for some quite significant businesses.
My understanding is that your organisation represents businesses with
around £40 billion of capital. Is that
not special pleading?
Ms Simmonds: Can I differentiate between some leisure
facilities, like hotels, for example, which probably would be included within
your planning gain supplement and the other end of the scale, dare I say it,
with health and fitness facilities particularly with sport, which are very much
needed. It is my belief that we should
not be taxing people who are providing what I would call and like to define as
active leisure facilities. If you were
going for an exemption you would exempt all facilities which are providing
active leisure, whether they be private sector, voluntary sector or, indeed,
community amateur sports clubs, so they would not have to pay this planning
gain supplement. It is hugely difficult
and we are already seeing some of our members developing abroad because they
find it so difficult to get planning permission in this country. There are various complications in the way
that particularly ODPM sees health and fitness which exacerbates that problem
within PPS6. This is not a sector that
is often thought about either nationally in terms of planning - I am talking
specifically here about planning - or, indeed, locally by the local planning
officer. In a sense, we are arguing for
some better guidance there which we are about to have, certainly on the leisure
and hospitality side, because ODPM recognises the problem.
Q193 Mr Betts: The exemption level could still apply to some
quite profitable large companies.
Ms Simmonds: If you did an exemption for active leisure, the
other way you would do it is you would define it just for community amateur
sports clubs which, as you know, are defined, there are just over 4,000 of them
at the moment and the Government is keen for more clubs to become community
amateur sports clubs. You could define
it as not-for-profit organisations and that would run across the cultural
sphere. You could define it as anyone
who is in receipt of a National Lottery grant because the rules around that on
not-for-profit could be exempted from this scheme. I do have a concern that you do have people who own facilities
which have no economic use but want to bring them back into economic use. If they keep that ownership should they pay
a planning gain supplement? Yes, there
will be an uplift, maybe a small uplift, and therefore the tax will be small,
but it may mean those types of developments never come forward in the
future. If I can give you the example
of the Docklands in Portsmouth where they have a whole series of buildings
which are unusable: if the Docklands Trust wanted to bring it back into
economic use, would they find the planning gain supplement as a real barrier to
that type of development going forward?
There are lots of non-profit making organisations who would have the
same problem.
Q194 John Cummings: What other mechanisms, other than exemption
from PGS, could be used to encourage local authorities to identify sites for
leisure development? Why is exemption
from PGS your preferred method?
Ms Simmonds: I think the exemption from PGS may not
necessarily be the preferred method if you then had some funds coming out of
the other end for actually funding those sorts of things which would not
naturally get funded otherwise. I do
believe that maybe it is time for some good practice national guidance from
ODPM to encourage local authorities to put together sites particularly for
sport. I do think that it is important
where we have housing developments and we have section 106, and I think there
is a danger they may disappear over a period of time for sporting developments,
that that mechanism is somehow kept. If
I could give you another example of the Harrods Repository which was developed
in West London: this part of the section 106 improved dramatically the towpath
that runs along from Putney to Hammersmith and is very well used for
recreational use. Our concern is if
section 106 is only concerned with things that are actually around the site and
if the local authority does not identify that scheme as something they want to
put the supplement towards then it will lose out. I think local authorities would be more interested in putting
together funding for something that was infrastructure based but not perhaps as
good for its local community.
Q195 John Cummings: Is your organisation contacted on a regular
basis by respective government departments to seek your advice on such matters?
Ms Simmonds: Yes, it certainly is by ODPM. We have tried very hard, particularly
through the Tourism Alliance where we wrote to every authority that was putting
together a Regional Spatial Strategy and asked them to contact us and, in fact,
we had absolutely no response at all.
In the past Whitbread have tried to talk to every local authority where
they wanted to develop sites for their David Lloyd leisure centres. It is very difficult for national
organisations or, indeed, individual companies to fit in and make contributions
to Local Development Frameworks.
Q196 John Cummings: Would including community sports facilities
in Local Development Frameworks adequately mitigate against the risk of local
authorities no longer prioritising such developments?
Ms Simmonds: Local Development Frameworks are quite
different from local plans and they are not as site specific as they used to
be, they are much more about general policies.
The whole idea was that the system would become more flexible and it
would also be faster. In many ways we
lost the ability for local authorities in their Local Development Frameworks to
give that sort of advice and to be very site specific.
Q197 John Cummings: Are you saying it does mitigate or it does
not mitigate?
Ms Simmonds: I think some guidance could make it easier
but I do not see any evidence from the way the system is evolving at the moment
that it would.
Q198 John Cummings: Would an inability to provide community
sporting facilities under section 106 arrangements jeopardise planning
permissions for other developments?
Ms Simmonds: Specifically, since this is very much about
housing, if you are going to put in new houses for people to live they must
have adequate sport and leisure developments to go with them otherwise you are
not providing for the fabric of people's lives and you are just encouraging
people to spend all their leisure time at home, which is neither good for them
nor for our economy.
John Cummings: Thank you.
Q199 Mr Betts: If you consider the planning gain supplement,
surely local politicians are still going to be under pressure when they grant
planning permission for developments to use the planning gain supplement money
they receive for exactly the purpose, ie providing community sports facilities,
that they would have used section 106?
Ms Simmonds: It is not our view, or our experience of
section 106, that that is the case.
There are too many local authorities who never think along those sorts
of lines at all. There is an urgent
need for more cycleways and more walkways within local authorities. As an Olympic legacy we should be thinking
along those lines throughout the country now.
There is no evidence that many local authorities do think along those
lines. Many of them think of things
which may be hugely necessary for the infrastructure in that particular area
and also possibly that do not cost as much to maintain, because there is a
maintenance and revenue issue here as well.
Q200 John Pugh: If I was a director of leisure in a local
authority and I was looking at the local authority getting section 106
agreement, planning gain supplement and so on, I would be seeing that as an
opportunity to invest further in leisure facilities within the community, for
which wherever you go there is a demand.
The only people who I think would be troubled by the prospect of a
planning gain supplement would be big commercial leisure parks who are looking
at the possibility of an additional commercial cost which would reduce their
profit margins. Could I ask you how
many of your members operate in the not-for-profit sector?
Ms Simmonds: We have all the major operators of local
authority sports facilities which are operated by the private sector. If you look at local authority facilities,
they are either operated by a trust or provided in-house or by the private
sector. All those who operate in the
private sector are members, as are most of the large sport health and fitness
clubs.
Q201 John Pugh: You can see that they might react differently
to the prospect?
Ms Simmonds: Yes, I can.
One of the concerns I would express is there are now very few directors
of leisure within local authorities, many have amalgamated them and they have
gone into bigger departments and that expertise is fast disappearing. I will give you the example of Cambridge
Parkside where the director of leisure put out a brief for the development of a
new swimming pool, which eventually was built but first time around the
planning department said, "There is no chance you are going to get planning
permission to build this on that site".
That does happen. There is not
that co-ordination internally within local authorities between planners, who
are very hard-pressed to do the job they want to do anyway, in terms of
planning expertise and development planning expertise. That co-ordination does not exist.
Q202 John Pugh: In terms of your fears, have you factored in
that some obligations under section 106 will disappear as other possibilities
for charging appear on the horizon?
Ms Simmonds: Yes.
Q203 John Pugh: Have you factored that in?
Ms Simmonds: We have.
That was my example of the Harrods Repository and the towpath. Would improvements to a towpath used by
hundreds of thousands of people be the sort of thing that planning gain
supplement money would be used for? I
think there is a great danger that it would not and yet the developers of that
housing site would equally say, "That is not immediately necessary to the
success of this site in infrastructure terms, therefore we are not providing
the funding".
Q204 John Pugh: Assuming that the new regime is inevitable,
what level of planning gain supplement could be sustained by organisations in
your sector, or does it vary depending upon the organisation?
Ms Simmonds: I think it varies. As you rightly say, the commercial end of the market may be able
to sustain a planning gain supplement.
It is the not-for-profit end particularly within the membership of the
CCPR that I would be very concerned about. Sports clubs which are meant to be making that link and keeping
people healthy and fit over a period of years is the area where we would
concerned.
Q205 John Pugh: Your general perception is that the burden
will be greater across the industry, as it were?
Ms Simmonds: No. I
think my general perception is the concern that you are not going to be funding
the sorts of sports and leisure facilities to make people active in the future. I would still maintain that even if they are
provided by the private sector, which of course then has no revenue impact on
the public purse, they still deserve special ----
Q206 John Pugh: You are not saying you expect the burden to
grow, you are saying the nature of the new system will encourage local
authorities to do different things?
Ms Simmonds: Yes.
Q207 Mr Betts: Just for clarification: you have given
evidence on behalf of BSL but could you say this afternoon whether you also
represent the views of Tourism UK and CCPR?
Ms Simmonds: They cover both the Tourism Alliance and
CCPR. Yes, I have taken into account
all of those views and they have all made submissions to this inquiry.
Mr Betts: Thank you very much for that.