Select Committee on Transport Minutes of Evidence


Memorandum submitted by Professor Chris Nash, Institute for Transport Studies, University of Leeds and Rail Research UK

  1.  My colleague Dr Andrew Smith and I recently reviewed the British experience of Passenger Rail Franchising for a conference organised by the European Conference of Ministers of Transport. I have also recently reviewed Europe wide experience of rail reform and presented the results in another conference paper.

  2.  I see the aim of franchising as being to use the forces of competition for the franchise to achieve the best value for money possible for the money made available for passenger rail subsidies. Broadly we found that a number of different approaches to franchising has already been attempted in Great Britain, but that there was not really sufficient evidence to determine their relative success.

  3.  In the first years of passenger rail franchising it appeared that the process was being very successful, with passenger traffic rising faster than would have been expected simply from the favourable economic conditions at the time, and with costs and subsidies falling. More recently costs have grown substantially however, offsetting all the early benefits. This remains true even after allowing for changes in track access charges and in payments to ROSCOs. There are many possible explanations for this increase in costs, including more tightly defined quality standards in franchises, the costs of introducing new more sophisticated rolling stock, including a period when it would inevitably be running in parallel with the old stock, increased pensions liabilities and the costs of running services on infrastructure which was subject to a very high level of renewal activity and therefore disruption. We have been unable to quantify these effects from published data and therefore are unable to say whether this cost increase is due to factors outside the control of the operators or whether it reveals a failure of the franchising process over this period.

  4.  It has been suggested that one cause of the cost increase has been the willingness of the Strategic Rail Authority to place operators on management contracts or otherwise to renegotiate franchises where operators have hit financial problems. We found no evidence that the cost increases had been any greater for these operators. However, whilst this approach may have been necessary in some cases in the circumstances following the Hatfield accident, I welcome the statement from DfT that it does not intend to follow this approach in future except in clearly defined circumstances.

  5.  Broadly we see two approaches to franchising. In the first, the franchisee is charged with operating a clearly defined set of services to fairly precisely set out specifications and heavily regulated fares. This has been the general approach in those continental European countries where franchising has been (generally successfully) used, and is essentially the current approach in Britain. With this approach, it is clear that the franchising authority is taking the key decisions regarding services, and therefore it should also be responsible for key investment decisions, including rolling stock, and for bearing a large part of the revenue risk (although obviously incentives must be built in to the franchise agreement for the operator to deliver high quality services and seek to attract maximum patronage).

  6.  In these circumstances franchises may be relatively short (certainly less than 10 years) in order to keep up the competitive pressure. Such franchises are most appropriate for urban or regional services, which are generally unprofitable, and where integration into the transport network as a whole is an important factor.

  7.  Under the second approach, the franchisee would have much more freedom to develop services, subject to minimum requirements. The franchisee in this case may be responsible for rolling stock investment, and indeed for negotiating over infrastructure developments. In this case a long franchise, at least 20 years (with appropriate break points for poor performance) is appropriate to provide adequate incentives for the long term development of services, and it is appropriate for the franchisee to bear a greater part of the revenue risk. However, difficulties would still occur should there be a significant downturn in the state of the economy in that time; I suggest that this risk should still be borne by the franchising authority, using an agreed formula to explain the impact of GDP on traffic. This approach may be more appropriate on inter city services, where services are largely profitable and where commercial approaches to yield management are an important part of providing a good quality service with little or no subsidy.

  8.  European evidence suggests that there are costs associated with vertical separation but that there are benefits associated with competition. I do not believe that it is possible to secure competition in the freight market and competition for passenger franchises without a degree of vertical separation of infrastructure from operations. However, this might be compatible with a much closer relationship between regional passenger operators and the infrastructure manager, possibly even extending to the operators taking responsibility for day to day operations and signalling. I see this as the most problematic area for vertical separation, and do not consider that third party operators would necessarily suffer seriously from such an arrangement provided that strong regulatory control was maintained. It would also be sensible to align such operations with a reform of infrastructure charges, whereby franchisees with long franchisees were charged essentially the "prime user" costs of the infrastructure they use (with other users simply being charged avoidable costs) and were in the lead on issues of how the infrastructure should be developed over time).

  9.  I consider that in general open access in passenger operations is unlikely to secure significant benefits and could lead to poor utilisation of track capacity and increases in subsidies as competitors seek to abstract revenue from franchisees. However, I believe it is appropriate for open access entry to remain possible in cases where the entrant can show that its services represent a good use of track capacity and will mainly offer improved services for particular groups of customers rather than abstract revenue from existing operators. They should however pay an access charge which reflects not just the marginal wear and tear costs they impose but also the opportunity cost of any track capacity they use which is desired by existing operators.

20 June 2006



 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2006
Prepared 5 November 2006