Select Committee on Transport Minutes of Evidence


Supplementary memorandum submitted by the Association of Train Operating Companies

RESPONSE TO SUPPLEMENTARY QUESTIONS RAISED BY THE TRANSPORT SELECT COMMITTEE IN RELATION TO ITS INQUIRY INTO TRAIN FARES AND TICKETING

1.  INTRODUCTION

  We have set out below our responses to the Transport Select Committee's supplementary questions in relation to its inquiry into Train Fares and Ticketing. Many of the Select Committee's questions were substantive in nature and we have taken the opportunity in the time available to set out the fullest possible response in each case. We have answered questions in the same sequence as they were posed to us in the letter from the Committee dated 1 December 2005.

  This response from ATOC is complementary to the individual responses that are being submitted by GNER and Virgin Trains.

  As a precursor to answering the Committee's questions, we believe it would be useful to highlight the work undertaken by the Passenger Demand Forecasting Scheme, about which the Committee asked questions during the hearing on 30 November 2005. As we stated at the hearing, the Scheme is largely funded by train companies but also includes within its membership the Department for Transport, Network Rail, the Office of the Rail Regulator and Transport for London. We have attached, as Appendix A, a list of research projects into price elasticities either reviewed by the Scheme or commissioned by it over the last 10 years. It demonstrates the amount of work undertaken in this area and shows that the currently recommended price elasticities were reviewed by the Institute of Transport Studies at Leeds University as recently as 2005.

  As we will be quoting price elasticities later in our response, we also believe that it may be useful to set out a layman's guide to how these values work. Elasticity measure the effect of price changes on the volume of demand and total revenue. If a fare price elasticity is below -1.0 (for instance -0.3) then total revenue will be increased if prices are raised. In other words, the reduction in demand that will result from the price increase will be more than offset by the higher level of fares charged. Conversely, if the elasticity is more than -1.0 (for instance -1.5) then revenue will be increased if prices are reduced. The value of -1.0 is the point on the demand curve at which revenue is maximised and at which either price increases or decreases would result in a reduction in total revenue.

2.  ELASTICITY

Question A.   Regular passengers such as commuters may not desert the railways right away if ticket prices are too high, but it will affect their long-term choices of where to live and work. Explain why the current high ticket prices won't result in regular passengers fleeing from the railways in the long term?

  As Season Tickets are tightly regulated it is, of course, a matter for the Government as to what the appropriate price level should be. However, we would point out at the outset that, even at current price levels, commuting markets are heavily subsidised and that, as we will demonstrate below the experience of the last 10 years does not suggest that commuters are deserting the rail network. Given the fundamental nature of the question posed by the Committee we have taken the opportunity to answer the question in appropriate depth.

  The commuting market, which is the focus of this question, very largely uses Season Tickets. We assume that the reference in the Committee's question to high ticket prices relates to our original Memorandum to the Committee, where we highlighted that Season Tickets prices, as measured by the average pence per kilometre paid, are relatively high in Britain when compared to general rail travel rates across Europe. We calculated that the average pence per kilometre for Season Tickets in Britain is around 8.6 pence whereas the average pence per kilometre across all European railways is between 6p and 7p. We believe that two factors underly this:

    (i)  The relatively high cost of providing services to commuters. The commuting market is characterised by very significant demand peaks on weekday mornings and evenings, which drive capacity both in terms of track and signalling infrastructure and rolling stock. Outside these peak periods demand is significantly lower and there is, in effect, an excess provision of capacity. The resulting unattractive economics of this market have historically led to Season Tickets being set at relatively high price levels compared to the broad average of rail fares across Europe, although as already noted, high levels of subsidy are still required to support commuting markets.

    (ii)  The average prices paid by commuters are also high because of the relatively short distance of most commuting journeys (we estimate that the average journey length of Season Ticket holders is 26 km compared to 48 km for the non Season Ticket market). This will result in a higher than average pence per kilometre because, as we highlighted in our original Memorandum to the Committee, there is an inverse relationship between distance and pence per kilometre (the longer the journey, the lower the pence per kilometre). We believe that this distance related effect exists on most European railways.

  However, it is important to note that the relatively high pence per kilometre for Season Tickets users is a product of history rather than any real price increases imposed since privatisation. Indeed due to the regulatory formula introduced at privatisation, which was based on Season Ticket price increases being capped each year at 1% below inflation (as measured by the Retail Prices Index), the real cost of fares paid by customers using Season Tickets has fallen by 8% in real terms over the last nine years, as the graph below illustrates:


  This is also reflected in the increase in the number of commuters using Season Tickets over the same time period. Volume has grown by 41% since 1996 as the graph overleaf illustrates:


  Thus trends over the last nine years do not indicate long term demographic changes with consequential reductions in rail demand of the kind suggested by the Committee's questions. In fact, conversely they suggest that at current price levels, people are choosing to join the commuting market, possibly reflecting related residency and employment decisions. The decline in real price levels will also have contributed to the significant increase in demand experienced.

  Given this, the Committee may find it useful to understand what current evidence suggests would be the effect of future real price increases or decreases to Season Tickets. The current Demand Forecasting Scheme recommended elasticity values for the commuting market range between -0.6 and -1.0 (almost all values are below -1.0). These values suggest that overall revenue would increase if prices were raised although volume would fall. In other words, the market is relatively inelastic.

  It is clear from all available evidence that a reduction in current price levels would lead to a decrease in total revenue, an increase in commuting volumes (and overcrowding on some routes) and a concomitant need to invest in additional capacity. The overall effect would be to require an increase in subsidy levels.

  Real increases in current price levels would reduce volume both in the short and long term (although this has to be considered in the context of background changes to housing costs, employment, etc, all of which have significant impacts on commuting demand). However, it is our commercial judgment that the current RPI+1 formula is unlikely to cause major shifts in employment and residency patterns of the kind suggested by the Committee in the short to medium term (5-10 years). Real increases will increase total revenue and reduce the level of subsidy required.

Question B.   The cost of rail has increased relative to other modes of transport over the past two decades. Will this not serve to drive passengers away from rail in the long term?

  Since the Committee hearing, we have undertaken further work to analyse the relative cost of rail and other modes of transport over the last 18 years (the longest period for which we can find consistent data). The results are summarised in the table overleaf:

Table 3

CHANGE IN TRAVEL COSTS 1995-2005


Type of Travel Cost
Change in Real Terms
1995-2005
Change in Real Terms
1987-2005


Standard Class rail fares
+3%
All rail fares (including First Class) +6%+24%
Local Bus fares+15%
Bus and Coach fares+15% +32%
Petrol+25%+31%
Vehicle tax and insurance+12% +44%
Vehicle maintenance+25% +43%
Purchase cost of motor vehicles-37% -43%
Total motoring costs-7% -5%
Other travel costs+9% +3%


Source: SRA's National Rail Trends 2004, Office of National Statistics, Transport Statistics Bulletin (Department for Transport) September 2005. "Other travel costs" are a combination of all other modes including air, ferry and cycling.

  The analysis demonstrates that over the last 10 years the cost of all other modes of transport has risen compared to rail with the exception of motoring. However, even here, all elements of motoring cost have increased with the exception of the purchase price of vehicles, which has fallen very significantly and outweighs the effect of the other cost increases. However, the marginal cost of motoring, which is most likely to be considered by consumers when making modal choices for specific journeys, has clearly risen.

  A similar pattern is true for the period since 1987, although the cost of rail has increased compared to "other travel costs" over this period.

  In the 10 years since privatisation, rail has become relatively less expensive than all other modes except motoring, where costs have been very significantly affected by the real decrease in the cost of motor vehicles. The increase in rail volumes over the last 10 years (38% growth in journeys and 40% growth in passenger kilometres) does not suggest that passengers have been driven away from the rail network. Indeed, conversely it suggests that rail may have benefited by the changes in relative price levels identified.

  We stated during the Committee hearing on 30 November that we had undertaken further work on the average price actually paid by rail users since 1995-96. We have analysed the amount of revenue raised by train operators in each of the 10 years since privatisation and compared this to the number of passenger kilometres travelled each year. This allows us to derive pence per kilometre measure which reflects the actual cost of travel for passengers. In order to provide a comparison with a period immediately pre-privatisation, we have also analysed, on the same basis, revenue and passenger kilometres between 1986-87 and 1995-96. The results of this analysis are shown in the graph below:


  The above table illustrates that the actual cost of rail travel to passengers has fallen slightly by around 1% in real terms since privatisation. By contrast, in the nine years preceding privatisation, the average cost of rail travel for passengers rose by roundly 11% in real terms.

  The average cost of rail travel has fallen (by 1% in real terms) by comparison with rail prices which have risen (+6% in real terms) due to two factors:

    (i)  the average distance by customers has increased (journeys have increased by 38% since 1995 but passenger kilometres have increased by 40%) bringing into play the previously observed relationship between distance and pence per kilometre; and

    (ii)  there has been switching between higher priced rail fares and lower priced rail fares, partly reflecting that customers have a greater range of fare options to choose from and partly reflecting the price increases applied to full fare standard and First Class tickets.

  Whilst, in the absence of comparative competitive data, we cannot draw firm conclusions from this additional analysis, it does highlight the remarkable stability in the real cost of fares paid by rail passengers since privatisation.

3.  COMPLEXITY AND TRANSPARENCY OF FARES

Question C.   What are the benefits of moving away from a traditional price-per-mile system towards so-called dynamic yield management where the price of a ticket depends on a whole range of factors, such as the time of travel and how far in advance the ticket was booked?

    (i)  Who benefits from these new systems?

  The railway industry has not used a traditional price per mile system for some considerable time. British Rail moved away from this approach in 1983 when it first introduced its range of Saver and Supersaver fares. These were supplemented in the early 1990s by advanced purchase fares and the trend towards market pricing has been continued and extended by train companies since privatisation.

  There are three main advantages that come from a more sophisticated market pricing approach (supported on longer distance routes by dynamic yield management) as compared to a simple mileage based tariff:

    (i)  prices can be varied to reflect the related competitive strength of rail in specific point to point markets;

    (ii)  prices can be varied by market segment to reflect willingness to pay; and

    (iii)  demand can be managed so as to minimise overcrowding at peak periods and encourage utilisation of spare off-peak capacity.

  The latter two points can perhaps best be understood in the context of the three principle markets that rail serves: business travel; leisure travel; and commuting travel.

  The business travel market is relatively price inelastic (current Demand Forecasting Scheme suggested values are -0.5 to -0.8) and is prepared to pay a relatively high price in return for the ability to turn up and go, flexibility in regard to travel arrangements and refunds and, in the case of first class, added value services such as more spacious carriages and lounges at stations. This is the primary market that full fare first class fares and standard single and open returns are targeted at.

  The leisure travel market is highly price elastic (current Demand Forecasting Scheme suggested values are between -0.9 and -1.5, with most values over -1.0) and price is a key determinant in the consumer decision to travel. It is worth highlighting that leisure rail travel, as well as having strong direct competition from express coaches, low cost air carriers and private cars, also has strong indirect competition from other leisure goods and services. The majority of the market is discretionary travel (such as visiting friends or shopping) and at the margin this can be substituted for by any other leisure good or service. It is in this market that Saver and other discounted walk-up and advance purchase fares are targeted.

  The pre-booking requirements and time of travel restrictions associated with these fares are to reduce the risk of them being bought by business travellers and to manage demand so as to fill spare, off-peak capacity and reduce overcrowding at peak periods. On longer distance routes, in particular, train companies actively manage sales of these fares using the new National Reservation Service (NRS) and yield management systems. These systems allow demand to be managed much more precisely and overall yields per seat to be increased.

  The commuting market has already been discussed in some detail. Season ticket prices, the primary product in this market, are, in effect, controlled by the Government, reflecting rail's relatively strong position in the market.

  The overall effect of this approach is to increase both revenue and volume. In addition, using yield management systems, demand can be managed and overcrowding reduced or eliminated. There are three principle beneficiaries from this: rail customers; the tax payer; and train companies.

  Customers benefit from there being a wider range of fares available and, in particular, very cheap fares for travelling in the off-peak. Customers also benefit from the fact that increased revenue allows train companies and the Government to invest more in the rail network. The tax payer benefits because increased revenue means that a lower level of subsidy is required to support the rail network. Train companies benefit because it provides the opportunity to use their commercial skills to grow revenue and, within the profit capping and sharing constraints now built into most franchises, increase profits for their shareholders.

  Market pricing and yield management of the kind described fits well with the current industry model, which allows train companies to build revenue growth into their franchise bids and agreements. This provides a strong incentive for them to grow revenue and volume, creating a virtuous circle that benefits all stakeholders, as illustrated above. Franchise agreements, with their associated profit sharing and capping arrangements and, where appropriate in economic terms, fares regulation are the mechanisms which allow the Government to ensure that there is an equitable balance of the resulting benefits between customers, taxpayers and train companies.

Question D.   How do you know whether rail users and non-users are aware of the full range of fares and ticket types available?

  Train companies promote their fares widely through advertising, leaflets, direct mail and, increasingly, email. The last method of communication is especially effective at letting known users and potential users know of promotional offers.

  In addition, the industry provides a multitude of ways in which customers can find out about fares:

    —  through the circa 1,400 staffed stations across the network, which are obliged through regulation to provide information impartially and accurately on the full range of fares offered by all train companies;

    —  through National Rail Enquiries, which provides impartial information on fares either through its 24 hour, seven day a week telephone enquiry service or the National Rail website;

    —  through any of the website or telephone booking services, provided by the major longer distance operators (such as GNER, Virgin Trains, Midland Mainline or First Great Western), which again through regulation, are obliged to provide impartial and accurate information; and

    —  through ATOC-licenced rail retailers such as the Trainline (also an impartial retailer) and 550 travel agents.

  It is also worth noting that ATOC, on behalf of the DfT, mystery shop all stations annually to ensure that they are selling accurately and impartially. As this is a mandatory, regulatory activity, results are reported to and vetted by the DfT. A threshold of 96.5% accuracy/impartiality is set and train companies that fail to meet this target are obliged to prepare and implement action plans. Repeated failure to meet the threshold ultimately results in penalties being imposed on the train company concerned.

  In 2003 and 2004, the average results achieved by train companies were 98.2% and 98.8% respectively. The results for 2005, currently being calculated look like being similar. In 2005, mystery shopping has been extended for the first time, to internet and telephone retailers. NRES is also subject to regulated mystery shopping to measure the accuracy of the information, which it provides.

  Whilst we believe that train companies already provide many opportunities for customers to find out information about fares, we also accept, as made clear at the Select Committee hearing, that more can be done. Two specific current initiatives are:

    —  simplification of the range of advance purchase fares by some longer distance train companies, with the introduction of a single advanced purchase fare type, available up to the day before departure; and

    —  improvements to web retail sites to make the presentation of information clearer and to give customers more ways of selecting the best fare for their needs.

Question E.   What is the rationale for ticket prices to be cheaper via the internet than other media?

  Currently, rail fares sold through the internet are not generally cheaper than tickets sold through other channels, although internet retailers do sometimes offer promotional discounts to encourage sales.

  However, ATOC estimates that information provision and ticket retailing costs the rail industry between £400 million and £500 million per year. Train operators would like to reduce this "cost of sale" and see the internet as one possible method of doing this.

  Whilst initial experience with internet retailing has not produced the economies expected, this has partly been caused by very significant start up costs and the complexity of the rail network compared to other modes of transport (having to provide fares between 2,500 stations for instance, not counting London Underground and other destinations).

  Train companies believe, nevertheless, that significant opportunities through internet retailing exist and have invested in developing the national Ticketing on Departure (ToD) network to support internet and telesales retailing and are now moving forward with plans to introduce low cost electronic ticketing (Stagecoach's Megatrain is an early example of this).

  Ultimately the key to successful internet retailing will be to reduce transaction costs, partly through initiatives such as e-ticketing but also by increasing volumes and realising economies of scale. In the short term the rationale for offering cheaper fares through the internet, therefore, is to drive volume and achieve economies of scale. In the longer term, if the cost of sale is reduced, lower fares via the internet would reflect the fact that this is a lower cost distribution channel for train companies. We would like to see changes to the current regulatory framework that would allow train companies to exploit the internet more effectively.

  It is worth noting that there are other advantages associated with internet retailing:

    —  part of the market now expects to buy online and if this facility was not offered, some sales would be lost and revenue reduced; and

    —  web sales allow, with the customer's permission, detailed data on customers to be collected, facilitating communication of future fares' offers and promotions.

4.  OPEN TICKETS

Question F.   To what extent do people who "turn up and go" represent a "captive market", that is people who have little or no choice but to travel by train using open tickets?

  Turn up and go customers are likely to be less flexible in their travel plans but it is incorrect to say that those customers are forced to buy Open tickets. Walk-up Saver fares and Cheap Day Returns are available on all longer and shorter distance routes respectively at off peak times. On some routes, walk-up Travelcards, SuperSavers, Network Awaybreaks, Cheap Day Singles and other route specific walk-up fares are available for off-peak travel. Railcard holders are also able to obtain reductions on both Open and discounted walk-up fares.

  A breakdown of walk-up sales for each of the major fare types in 2004-05 has been summarised overleaf showing that around 70% of "turn up and go" customers benefit from some kind of discounted fare:


Fare Type
    Revenue and Volume 2004-05 Revenue
(£m)Volume
(m journeys)
Percentage of
Total Volume




Open and Day Single/Return
99417130%
Open and Day Single/Return—Railcard Discount 74 173%
Saver/Supersaver/Network Away break816 7714%
Cheap Day Single/Return/Travelcards639 29553%
Total2,522560 100%


Source: Rail industry systems (Lennon). Note that for shorter distance journeys, the full price Day Single/Return is offered instead of the Open Single/Return. The data in this table includes both these products.

  It is also worth noting that most longer distance train companies now offer discounted advance purchase single fares. For many journeys, therefore, customers that have completely inflexible outward travel arrangements and need to travel during a peak period may be able to purchase a standard single for their outward journey and a discounted advance purchase single for their return journey.

  Finally, we should re-emphasise that Virgin Trains, GNER and Midland Mainline have all simplified their advance purchase fares and now allow these fares to be bought up to the day before travel, providing the greatest possible opportunity for customers to buy in advance.

5.  SAVER AND ADVANCE-PURCHASE FARES

Question G.   Will Saver tickets not suffer the same fate as the SuperSaver and effectively disappear if they are de-regulated?

  As we have already highlighted, train companies maximise revenue by offering a range of fares targeted at different market segments. There is always likely to be an element of the longer distance leisure market that wishes to turn up and travel.

  Train companies will wish to cater for this market and thus discounted walk-up fares will continue to be offered even if Savers are deregulated. However, train companies wish to be able to have the freedom to integrate these fares fully into their fare's structures, allowing their yield management systems to be used to as efficiently as possible.

  It is this context that we have argued the case for deregulation of Saver fares. It is also worth emphasising that in the very competitive markets that longer distance train companies operate in, rail's relatively low market shares do not provide any economic justification for regulation.

Question H.   The allocation of advance purchase tickets in unclear. How can passengers make informed choices if the details of quotas are not publicly available?

  Yield management systems operate on the basis that the number of seats available at any particular price level is constantly varied before departure, in order to maximise the number of seats sold, whilst ensuring that enough seats are always available for higher yield, walk-up passengers and customers purchasing more flexible, higher priced tickets.

  In such an environment there may be 100 seats available at a particular price level on day one, 50 available on day five and 150 available on day 10. In these circumstances it is impossible to state the absolute number of seats available at a particular price point on a specific train service, as this will vary over time. Availability on a specific day could be provided but given the dynamic nature of seat availability, as described above, this could end up being highly misleading.

  Conventional airlines and low cost airlines have been using yield management systems for many years and do not show availabilities on their internet sites or other sales channels. Nevertheless, consumers understand the general principle that the earlier you book the better chance you have of a very cheap fare. The enormous success of the low cost carriers illustrates how powerful yield management can be in increasing volumes, load factors and revenue yields.

6.  RAILCARDS

Question I.   Would a National Railcard scheme not be the best way to expand the market for rail travel in the UK?

  We do not believe that a National Railcard scheme would be the best way of expanding the market for rail in the UK commercially and would very probably require a higher level of subsidy to support the industry.

  Train companies currently offer a range of Railcards targeted at specific market segments, which research has indicated to be more price elastic than the market in general. The Railcards are designed to generate additional, off peak leisure travel, in particular with a low risk of use for business travel. There are currently around 2.2 million Railcards in use (Young Persons, Senior, Family, Disabled, HM Forces and Network) and they account for around £400 million of revenue per year. ATOC estimates that around £60 million of this revenue is generated solely because of the existence of the Railcards. Railcards are well supported by train companies with around £2.5 million per year spent on managing and promoting them.

  Although targeted Railcards have been very successful, we believe that a universally available National Railcard is likely to lead to reduction in industry revenue. This is because a National Railcard will provide discounts to all segments of the market, including those that are relatively price inelastic.

  Overall, we believe that a National Railcard is likely to lead to a decrease in industry revenue with a concomitant increase in the level of subsidy required.

  We understand that the DfT, and the SRA before them, have been considering this issue and that the SRA undertook market research. Although we have not seen the detailed results of this research, we understand that it generally supports our belief that a National Railcard would be loss making.

7.  EFFECT OF TIMETABLING ON THE AVAILABILITY OF CHEAPER FARES

Question J.   Last year there were significant problems for passengers in making cheap advance bookings for the Christmas period. How do you think advance bookings are progressing for Christmas this year?

Question K.   Is the process of Network Rail uploading timetables and engineering works data to the national database at T-12 now functioning satisfactorily?

  As they are so closely related, we will answer questions 7(J) and 7(K) together. There has been very significant progress since last year in improving the availability of timetable information to meet the T-12 and T-9 deadlines. Prior to this year's peak Christmas and New Year period, all reserving train companies were able to offer reservations, as required, at T-9 except Virgin Trains and Hull Trains. Virgin Trains were able to offer reservations at T-7 and Hull Trains at T-5. All reserving train operators now have reservations open for the Christmas and New Year period.

  Currently all reserving train operators are open for T-9 bookings after Christmas except Virgin West Coast (T-6), Midland Mainline (T-8) and Hull Trains (T-6).

  Train companies are generally pleased with the progress made by Network Rail in ensuring that timetable data is available to meet these required deadlines. However, it is important that all parties continue to remain focused on consolidating the improvements made to date and making further progress towards compliance with the T-9 and T-12 deadlines, although short term engineering work is always likely to make full compliance on all routes very difficult to achieve. Nevertheless, we are confident that all parties are now fully committed and that improvement will continue to be made.

8.  BOOKING SYSTEMS

Question L.   How widespread is it for train operating companies to offer special assistance for business travellers helping them to identify of the best fares and making reservations?

  As we have emphasised previously, all rail customers have access to a wide range of channels for obtaining information about rail fares and purchasing them.

  A number of train companies operate specialist business travel units to provide specialist services to corporate customers. These are, in effect, in house travel agencies that make bookings and provide tickets to these customers. Tickets are generally delivered to meet the customer's specific needs and in addition account management services are provided. These include the provision of regular statements that give a breakdown of employee travel, central invoicing of the customer and the provision of credit facilities. Some train companies charge corporate customers fees for the provision of these services.

  These services are valued by corporate customers principally because they provide additional management information, allow greater control over travel by employees and facilitate ticket dispatch and collection. Whilst corporate customers will be advised on fares, as part of the service provided, this is not the primary purpose of these units.

  Very similar services are offered by travel agents who specialise in the corporate travel market. Rail sales through these travel agents amount to roundly £200 million per year.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2006
Prepared 19 May 2006