Select Committee on Trade and Industry Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 262-279)

DR DIETER HELM

13 JUNE 2006

  Q262 Chairman: Dr Helm, welcome to this evidence session in which we are gathering evidence particularly on the nuclear new build question but, of course, it is important to emphasise the evidence you have given us would relate to any part of the energy review and not just the nuclear question. Before we begin questioning, can I ask you to introduce yourself for the record, as I always do?

  Dr Helm: My name is Dieter Helm and I am a Fellow of New College Oxford.

  Q263 Chairman: A very, very brief introduction, thank you. What you have written about the Government's energy policy has consistently highlighted the fact that the electricity market is not meeting the challenges of climate change and security of supply. Do you think the Government chose the right time to conduct an energy review then, three years after the last one?

  Dr Helm: The answer to that question depends on what you think about the 2003 White Paper and whether you think it is an enduring basis on which to construct energy policy. My own view is that it does not provide such a base. It does not provide such a base even to address the short-term problems which were witnessed last winter and arise especially with respect to the gas market. More generally, it has not provided incentives to ensure sufficient investment in the energy sector to meet the security of supply objective. On climate change, I think it is already patently obvious that the strategy that is set out in the 2003 White Paper, while making a contribution to dealing with emissions, is a long way adrift from either the domestic targets of 2010 or, more seriously, the longer-term targets.

  Chairman: Thank you very much indeed. We are now going to pick up the points that you made in your written submission to us.

  Q264  Mrs Curtis-Thomas: Last week we took evidence from two major generators—E.ON and EDF—likely to be involved in any potential nuclear build. Do you think that, with six main energy firms in the UK, we have market players capable of the competitive delivery of new nuclear build?

  Dr Helm: It depends on the structure of a nuclear project. You can imagine consortia being put together which might comprise any of the players in the UK market. In terms of companies with large balance sheets and the capacity to run a nuclear programme and to carry through most of the main components of a nuclear project then I think we are quite limited to the big three European players.

  Q265  Mrs Curtis-Thomas: Just to summarise what you have said: we have got six major players but they would only take a small role in the consortia. What role do you think they might take and is it a significant role with the rest of it being parcelled out to our European colleagues on the Continent?

  Dr Helm: If you think about how a nuclear project is put together, first of all there are the sites, and British Energy and the remnants of BNFL own all of those, so that is part and parcel. There is the question of off-take contracts and if anyone commits to a fixed price contract to buy the power effectively they are taking some of the risk of the project and any of the players might want to take some of their capacity in that form. Then there is the issue of the bidding and construction costs of the plant and it is none of the UK players as currently constructed, it is the French nuclear reactor developers and the Americans. I think the idea of seeing this as a company building a nuclear power station is to misconstrue the way in which the risks of these pan out and the way in which consortia may well be formed.

  Q266  Mrs Curtis-Thomas: The construction and build is not ours, that is for others, but service and contract provision is ours.

  Dr Helm: In the end somebody has to buy the power and it might be that large suppliers take a chunk of that, but it might also be that financial institutions do. For example, in the Finnish case it is a nuclear power project and large industrial customers. A financial intermediary might buy the contract, break it up into all sorts of small bits and you might personally like to take a little bit of your power on a guaranteed price, but not all of it. I think we need to move forward into a world in which contracting is a much more diffuse and potentially diverse type of activity than simply some lump sum big contracts, but there might be such contracts.

  Q267  Mark Hunter: Dr Helm, can I ask you how important you think is the need for political consensus on any final decision on nuclear. Do you think the Government is going about achieving this in the right way?

  Dr Helm: I think it is very important to have political consensus about the climate change targets, the climate change instruments, the structure of the electricity market and particularly the security of supply incentives. I think that requires an overarching framework which has to look beyond the natural life of one party's period in government. We need to get political consensus around that. So far, although it seems to me most political parties take the issue pretty seriously, as yet there is not much evidence that people are going to sit down and hammer out an all-party enduring agreement. By the way, that is one of the reasons why I think some institutions are needed behind this to provide that. A separate question is whether there needs to be political consensus on nuclear power. The strong difference between the really very, very poor record of nuclear development in the UK and the much more successful development in France is clearly political commitment in France across the spectrum and not in the UK. If you are going to engage in a large lumpy capital project, or series of capital projects, the chances that a government might subsequently change the rules increases the risk of that project, raises the cost of capital, and in a large capital-intensive industry it is the cost of capital that really matters. The answer is if there is not cross-party support for a nuclear programme, or at least the framework within which one might be constructed, then it is going to be very expensive.

  Q268  Mark Hunter: The second part of the question was do you think the Government is currently going about achieving this in the right way?

  Dr Helm: No. I have argued all along that these long-term energy questions should be taken, to an extent, outside the party process. That does not mean in the end it should not be political, it has to be political in a democracy, and when one is talking about industry with long-term waste the politics of handling that is paramount. We need to find a framework within which the parties can sign up to such a framework without it being the initiative of one or the other. In the past there were mechanisms for doing these things, things like Royal Commissions and things of that ilk, but I am not sure that is appropriate in this context. I urged at the beginning of this current energy review that it should be cross-party and it is not, it is a governmental review, and I think that is a mistake.

  Q269  Mr Bone: From your comments, and there clearly is not cross-party consensus on this, and you quite rightly have said the Government has not encouraged any cross-party discussion by doing it as a single issue for themselves, can I conclude that because it is going to be very expensive you would be against a nuclear option?

  Dr Helm: I am neither for nor against. It is utterly critical to my arguments about energy policy that I am in favour of setting a level playing field in which carbon and security of supply are properly placed in the market. In that context I hear from the nuclear industry that they think they are the cheapest way of achieving low cost emissions and security of supply. If that is true then if the playing field is level there will be nuclear build, but I do not know. I am highly sceptical, having studied energy policy for 20 years plus and watched the numbers the Government produced about the costs of different technology, about any point estimates of the costs of different technologies. I think the market will out who is bluffing, who is not, and what those prices are. Additionally, the nuclear side—this is where you fray the edges of the playing field—has some issues which require solutions which go across political parties. One of the reasons I propose carbon contracts is that a carbon contract is a contract which will have to be honoured, so it is important to recognise that the carbon approach is a cross-party commitment because somebody has underwritten a contract. It is not enough to simply say, "We are going to have a carbon price in the future" or there will be some sort of floor that we will deal with, that is open to political movement. What is not open to political movement is offering a contract, signing a contract and then delivering on that component. Commitment is part and parcel of the way I have thought about designing a carbon framework. I am sorry if that is a little convoluted.

  Chairman: We will come back to the carbon framework later, I know it is one of your principal points.

  Q270  Mr Weir: I was interested in what you were saying about markets deciding. Given that evidence we have had, not only from nuclear but from some energy providers, is they are looking for long-term guarantees, and perhaps some guarantee on long-term pricing, is it truly the market deciding on that basis or are we looking at a skewed market to deliver energy for the future?

  Dr Helm: I think you have to be very careful of the word "guarantee". In a market you can get contracts. Contracts establish a fixed price for certain activities and those contracts are enforceable. A guaranteed price by government is quite a different thing. For example, mechanisms like the Renewables Obligation or—I am not in favour of this—a nuclear obligation effectively guarantees that costs will be passed through in one form or another. That is not a very good incentive mechanism and can produce all sorts of outcomes.

  Q271  Mr Weir: Is it your feeling that government should not be involved in effectively setting a base price for any form of energy?

  Dr Helm: Absolutely. Why should it, and how would it know? If you had a benign planner who had perfect information about everything and could perceive the future, was immune to lobby groups and interest groups, fine. I think what government should do is sort out what its objectives are here. It is for government to sort out what carbon policy it wants, ie what targets, and it is for government to sort out what level of security of supply it wants and is prepared to take a risk on. Given that framework, what we want to find is the cheapest way of achieving that outcome. If it is a sharp and sustained reduction in CO2 emissions then the question is how we can do that as cheaply as possible. For the government to go in and say, "We know that the answer to that is wind" or "We know the answer to that is a nuclear power station" assumes a level of information and understanding and an immunity to lobbying which has never been witnessed before in an energy policy. The history of energy policy and governments picking technologies has been at times quite close to disastrous, particularly in the nuclear sector.

  Chairman: I think we are getting into the danger of stealing some of the territory Mark Hunter wants to ask about.

  Q272  Mark Hunter: Before I come on to my next question can I take you back to your answer to my previous question. If I heard you correctly I think you were implying that it would help, if that is the right term, if this decision about nuclear were taken outside the party political process. Could you extrapolate briefly on that given the fact you are talking to an audience of people very much involved inside the party political process. I am intrigued to know what your ideas might be in that area.

  Dr Helm: The political process is involved in setting the carbon targets and the security of supply requirements, fuel poverty and other objectives. (On the objectives setting on the carbon side, I propose that there is an auction of long-term contracts.) Somebody has to run those auctions and I propose that there is an energy agency which has the job of delivering the objectives which Government has set. The auctions are one form of that. Similarly, on the security of supply, the capacity market has to function in a context in which a view has been taken about that security of supply and, again, in my world that would be delegated to an agency. I strongly distinguish between the setting of objectives as a political activity and the delivery of those objectives which I delegate to an agency in my proposed framework.

  Q273  Chairman: The challenge to the political process is for us to agree a consensus on supply and carbon emissions, is that right?

  Dr Helm: It is. It has proved very difficult. This is not about aspirations. We can aspire to reduce CO2 emissions by 20% by 2010 but, to be blunt, it never was going to happen and it has no credibility. On the other hand, you can auction contracts for carbon and they have credibility by definition because they are contracts. You can tie yourself to an EU emissions trading national allocation plan and that is it. So far the politics has not gone so far as to even have agreement about what those carbon targets are before we get into all the detail about how they might be delivered.

  Q274  Mark Hunter: On the last scenario you advocate I am sure you would accept there are some fairly basic issues about accountability that would need to be overcome, but that is perhaps best left for another day. I am keen to make progress, if I might move on to my next question. You have also suggested the possibility of a single agency for the implementation of energy policy which would encompass the work of Ofgem, the Carbon Trust, the Energy Saving Trust and parts of the DTI. Could you elaborate on how you might see this working and how feasible you think that would be? Perhaps, how would it differ from a Department of Energy?

  Dr Helm: In my framework the government sets its targets on climate change on security of supply. It delegates those targets to an agency to deliver and that agency reports publicly on progress with respect to those targets and publicly alerts ministers to any substantive problems that arise. It is somewhat modelled on the Monetary Policy Committee of the Bank of England. It has both security of supply and climate change together because trying to solve them separately creates enormous inefficiency and, indeed, that is reflected at both the government level and the structure we have at the moment between Defra and DTI and between the energy regulator and environmental interests. It is less bureaucratic than we have at the moment. We have spawned a very large number of organisations across the energy sector solving problems on a piecemeal ad hoc basis. I would bring together the expertise of the Carbon Trust, the Energy Saving Trust and Ofgem in particular within that body, it would have a core modelling skill and we would have people with substantive expertise in that body who would be there full-time and we would build up a level of knowledge which we clearly do not have in Government at the moment to address these issues. It is a delivery body with two objectives, publicly accountable and it is a reduction in bureaucracy from what we have at the moment.

  Q275  Mark Hunter: I am interested in the accountability factor, as I mentioned before. You just said it would be publicly accountable.

  Dr Helm: Absolutely.

  Q276  Mark Hunter: If it is responsible for delivery how is it going to be publicly accountable if we do not have the situation of the minister being able to account for progress, or lack of, in front of Parliament?

  Dr Helm: We have that problem across all aspects of delivery of government policy, so there is nothing new, whether it be in the health service, education or elsewhere. In my view, the agency status would not be the same as the Ofgem status. We have thought through, perhaps well or badly, the relationship between Defra and the Environment Agency and the Environment Agency's accountability in that framework. I envisage the normal mechanism for doing that might include guidance, it will include select committees, it will include the normal ministerial relationships with agencies, but there is one separation in that ministers cannot say, "This is our carbon target but, by the way, it looks like it is much more expensive than we thought it was. We charged you with delivering it but now we do not like how you are delivering it, could you change it a bit without undermining the targets?" The crucial thing here is how ministers make it credible that they are going to stick to their targets and take the consequences for prices that follow from those targets. It is better to be honest and say, "We are not going to have these targets" if you cannot do that, but if you are going to do it I do not think we want to continue, if we take climate change very seriously, with the current world where nobody really knows what the 20% 2010 target means. That is the difficulty. If you want credibility it is expensive, that is what it is like in monetary policy. We have learned there is a massive pay-off in monetary policy from having clarity, of the inflation objective being the Chancellor's and the delivery of that objective being the Bank of England's.

  Q277  Mark Hunter: That is interesting, thank you. You have talked this morning about the importance of establishing a level playing field, as you put it, on which all technologies can compete. To what extent do you think the current market provides such a level playing field?

  Dr Helm: It is certainly not a level playing field. We have a whole host of different kinds of interventions and they are for different time horizons and they treat different technologies differently. I am in favour of a technology-neutral policy. For example, the Renewables Obligation is largely a wind obligation, it excludes nuclear power, although nuclear power is apparently low carbon. The Climate Change Levy is not a proper carbon tax. There are a host of other interventions in support of particular options within the marketplace. No, it is not, but more fundamentally it misses out long-term signals for the two things that you want this level playing field to take into account. There are no serious incentives in the market to provide excess capacity, which is what you need for security of supply. No rational capitalists worth their salt would deliberately engineer excess supply unless they were paid to do it, and clearly they are not paid to do it. On the carbon side, we have no idea what the carbon regime is beyond 2012 and we do not yet know what the Emissions Trading Scheme looks like from 2008-12. I cannot think of any serious technology on the carbon front which is interested very much in what happens before 2012 other than very established technologies. The two key elements to energy policy are outside the market and, therefore, not part of that level playing field. This market, whatever it does do, cannot possibly provide a secure, climate change friendly energy outcome.

  Chairman: Let us move on to the specifics of the carbon contract now.

  Q278  Roger Berry: Dr Helm, you make a powerful case for using market-based mechanisms for dealing with CO2 emissions, the two obvious mechanisms being carbon contracts and a long-term carbon tax. Could you comment on the relative advantages of the two mechanisms?

  Dr Helm: In theory, and forgive me I am an academic—

  Q279  Roger Berry: I understand, I used to be one.

  Dr Helm: My condolences! In theory there is much to recommend a straight carbon tax over permits, however international agreements are much easier struck in quantities rather than prices, ie permit trading rather than taxes, and Kyoto in itself is fixed in quantities. There are reasons for thinking that if you want to approach this problem internationally you have got to go down the permits route. Then there is the industrial lobby which would much prefer permits than taxes because taxes provide revenue for Treasury, permits tend to get grandfathered and not have the income effect on industry. We have the European Emissions Trading Scheme, it is probably the only main game in town, and the scheme that I propose with regard to carbon contracts is designed exclusively with a view to reinforcing that regime and providing a bridge to the longer term for that regime and also fitting in with a framework for thinking about more international agreement about carbon. The carbon contract proposal I have is essentially an elongation of the Emissions Trading Scheme and has the nice feature that if it comes into form it gives politicians an extraordinarily strong interest in making sure the European Emissions Trading Scheme goes forward because they need that to offload the contracts on subsequently.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2006
Prepared 6 September 2006