Select Committee on Treasury Written Evidence


Memorandum submitted by the PEPs and ISAs Managers' Association (PIMA)

Introduction

  PIMA the leading trade body for tax incentivised savings providers, on behalf of over 110 members and the millions of consumers who hold tax-preferred savings schemes, would like to recognise the importance of the efforts by the Treasury Select Committee to better understand stakeholders' views regarding pensions reform and specifically the costs and role of regulation arising from the proposals for the National Pensions Savings Scheme (NPSS). PIMA believes that successful pensions reform will be best achieved through a collaborative process with industry, consumer groups, independent bodies and other stakeholders.

  PIMA applauds the work of the Pensions Commission. The Commissioners and their team have produced an excellent report that presents an exhaustive account of the state of long-term savings in Britain. The detail and thinking around past experience, current policy and likely trends give fresh life to the policy debate around pensions reform and broader issues about long-term savings and retirement.

  PIMA is well-placed to make a serious contribution to this debate. PIMA's members represent a diverse cross-section of the retail financial services industry from banks and friendly societies to asset managers to stockbrokers to insurance companies and services providers. PIMA represents its members, and through them, the millions of investors in tax-preferred schemes.

  PIMA works with a wide range of Government departments, the FSA, and private sector stakeholders to ensure that consumers have the widest range of choices in their tax-preferred investment vehicles. PIMA works on behalf of members and consumers to make regulation of the UK's "flagship" savings schemes effective, properly balancing protection and market efficiency.

  At the behest of the Committee, PIMA would like to offers its views on regulation and cost of NPSS. PIMA's members have immense experience in managing thousands of savings schemes and investment products. PIMA members are able and willing to make available to the committee their first-hand knowledge of operational issues and feasibility of implementing any new scheme. Broadly speaking, PIMA is ambivalent about the creation of a new NPSS scheme. In truth, much more thinking needs to be done. However, as a general principle, PIMA believes that the wealth of experience in the financial services sector in the UK can and should provide the solution to long-term savings in the UK. Recreating that through a Government scheme may only add further complexity to savings.

Cost

  First it is worth noting that while cost is an important factor in the accumulation of long-term savings, to date it has had a tendency to play too large a role in the debate. The real question is cost for what? Cost can only be compared if the other factors are equal. If costs are really cheap, but returns are lacklustre is the investor really better off? If costs are high, but returns are spectacular, then does it matter that costs were higher? This is a crucial question of the debate that has been inadequately articulated in the wider dialogue on pensions reform, the real issue is much more about risk versus reward, the risk appetite and its understanding or comprehension by the consumers.

  However, PIMA does admit that cost is one important consideration. Based on the conceptual shell provided in the Pensions Commission's second report, PIMA believes that there is potential for significant up-front costs in creating and implementing the NPSS model. Obviously, there are a lot of details still yet to be known about the NPSS and how it would function. As such, we are hesitant to offer concrete figures to this end. There are three important "costs" to contemplate as the debate goes forward. Firstly, there is the cost of creation and implementation of any Government-led NPSS solution. This cost of installing the infrastructure by the Government would presumably be funded by tax receipts. Secondly, there is the cost to the consumer, the collector and the contributor of transactions related to any scheme. Finally, there is the cost of advice which should be a consideration to any scheme created.

  As to cost of creation and implementation for the Government, PIMA has little expertise in this area. However, based on our experience, the expected cost of publicity, information technology systems, and maintenance for a universal scheme would be substantial—probably running into the tens or hundreds of millions.

  Related to this is the cost of transactions for ongoing contributions. The feedback received from members who currently conduct business in occupational pension schemes suggests that the cost of collection from employers is significant for the collector. Systems must be created, learnt and manned. In addition, with any new scheme there will also be some (perhaps even significant) business cost to employers to make such contributions to any scheme, especially if it is compulsory. Again, this will involve man-hours, expenditure on systems and significant internal resource.

  Finally, the cost of advice is nearly universally recognised as one of the most costly parts of providing long-term savings products. PIMA recognises that advice is not always required—in there is a great diversity in how consumers buy ISAs and CTFs. Some consumers feel comfortable with choosing their own investments and purchasing them directly from a distributor or product provider. These are generally the most financially savvy and financially capable. However others seek, and quite frankly need, advice in their long-term financial planning. PIMA is not satisfied that the issues around cost of provision of advice have been adequately addressed by the Pensions Commission or National Pensions Debate. The Pensions Commission was half right—properly addressing the issue entails "un-bundling" the cost of advice from the costs associated with managing the underlying investment. However, it does not solve the problem that many people need and want advice on such important decisions with such significant long-term implications. As such, offering a universal figure of 0.3% for everyone would seem to oversimplify what is a much more complex problem.

  PIMA sees the workplace as an important component in encouraging long-term savings. However, many years of experience and common sense lead it to believe that obligatory participation by employers and employees may not actually result in a net gain for Britons. Clearly, the employer contribution will not simply appear from nowhere. As much as the Government and society at large may wish otherwise, the implementation of an obligatory scheme will lead some employers to simply offset contributions to the NPSS against future earnings or benefits.

  PIMA believes that the workplace of the future will be one in which flexible benefits thrive. In order to stay competitive, employers of all type will be required to give employees the choice in how they are remunerated. That might be through contributions to a savings vehicle such as an ISA or pension. It might be through protection policies or employee share schemes. Or it might be through additional salary or holidays. This will allow individuals to meet their own needs as they see fit.

NPSS and Regulation

  The issue of regulation of any pension scheme offered by the Government is extremely complex. First it is worth noting that current Government-sponsored investment products are not regulated by the FSA. One can buy a cash ISA or bonds from NS&I, while not being afforded the protection of FSA regulation. Instead they are "backed by HM Treasury". In contrast, many other investment products are regulated by the FSA. This is worth noting not because of any suggestion on PIMA's part that NS&I be regulated, rather because of the precedent it sets for any NPSS scheme.

  Based on the responses to the recent HM Treasury consultation on eligibility to establish pension schemes and the Government response, it seems likely that pensions will be regulated by the FSA from April 2007. PIMA has been supportive of this move on both philosophical and practical grounds. It believes that this will greatly benefit the consumer by promoting greater competition through enabling a wider number of market participants to offer pension schemes. PIMA believes that this could include the Government via NPSS should it choose to compete in the marketplace. However, in the interest of a level playing field and fair competition, that marketplace must be equitable to all players. As such, NPSS should also be required to meet the same regulatory requirements as other firms offering pension schemes. Only when all firms are subject to the same standards can the consumer really make an informed choice in a competitive market. To create a scheme where one player enjoys different rules can only lead to market distortion and confusion by those it is designed to benefit most—the consumer. If the ideas underpinning NPSS are truly superior, let the market make it a success.

  Again, advice is a key issue. If NPSS is allowed to operate on a different plane than the private sector, there could be profound consequences. Compulsory pension contributions may not always be the most financially sensible. Take one issue which is very relevant to contemporary personal finance in Britain—debt. In modern Britain, people have a vast array of financial predicaments. Some have no savings and only debt, of the consumer and mortgage varieties. Others have no debt and significant equity/sums saved in ISAs, pensions or housing stock. However, most people have a combination of both. In the case of those who have only debt and no savings, compulsion to save for the long-term, instead of near-term priority on repayment of debt may constitute mis-selling and is almost certainly not financially sensible. Here is where the stark inequity of different regulatory approaches becomes apparent. Competent financial advisers selling private sector savings would not and should not advise savings where guaranteed returns would not outstrip the cost of servicing debts.

  In summation, PIMA feels that it is broadly in the interest of the consumer to have a single, overarching regulatory framework for the conduct of business relating to and promotion of all pension arrangements—including NPSS.

Building on Success

  PIMA believes that there is a much simpler way to promote long-term savings in the UK. The answer lies in simply building upon what already exists, what is proven as successful and what consumers like and use—the tax preferred wrapper.

  Tax-preferred schemes are exceptionally popular with the public. For example, over 55% of the working population owns an ISA. Why? Mainly, because the concept is exceptionally simple and it is clear that this is very attractive to the consumer. Investments of a wide variety sit within a "wrapper" which shields them from tax on capital gains and interest received.

  In only six years after the introduction of the ISA, nearly £190 billion has been invested. [34]In addition PEPs still have £71 billion held in them. We can expect the figures from the Child Trust Fund, which is based on ISA philosophy, to reveal many billion more invested when figures are published this summer.

ISAs vs. Pensions?

  When thinking about ISAs in comparison to pensions, it is useful to consider total funds invested to each. While there is a much larger aggregate total subscribed to pensions, the statistics show that in the past five years the ISA has been a much more successful consumer savings product.

  Compare the five years of contributions between 2000-05. According to the HMRC statistics, the aggregate total of ISA subscriptions between tax years 2000-01 and 2004-05 is roughly £141 billion. [35]That compares with £282 billion paid into pensions (including funded occupational, unfunded occupational and personal pensions savings) in the calendar years between 2000-05. [36]However, of that £282 billion, £184 billion are employer contributions. As such, one may deduce that individuals' subscriptions to ISAs were over 43% greater than contributions to pensions of all types made by individuals/employees (employers cannot make direct contributions to ISAs per HMRC regulations).

  Thus, in like for like terms, contributions to ISAs by individuals have been significantly greater than those made into pensions regardless of type. However, comparing ISAs to all types of pensions is a skewed comparison because of the scale, complexity and variety of occupational pension provision in Britain. Thus, it is perhaps more accurate in terms of perspective to compare yearly ISA contributions to those made by individuals into personal pensions schemes. Year-on-year, ISA subscriptions are roughly double those made into private personal pensions schemes by employers and individuals. Further when comparing like for like—individuals' contributions to ISAs and private personal pensions, contributions to ISAs are roughly 335% of those made to private personal pension schemes. [37]

  Additionally, all ISA contributions have been taxed. This compares with pensions contributions which have tax relief added to them at the marginal rate. Additionally, ISAs have a maximum subscription per calendar year that is a fraction of that which may be invested into a pension. Thus it is logical to conclude that if ISA savers had the opportunity to gain tax relief and had a significantly higher subscription limit; the investment in ISAs would outstrip pension contributions by an exponentially greater figure than is already the case.

  It is therefore logical to conclude that ISA-style schemes are much more attractive to the general public than pensions. This is evidenced by consumers' own demand for them despite their lack of tax incentives like those afforded to pensions.

A Gap in the Thinking

  PIMA and its members were disappointed that more attention wasn't paid to savings in ISAs and other tax-preferred wrappers in the Pensions Commission's overall analysis. While ISA savings were considered in the first Pensions Commission Report (Challenges and Choices), they were not fully considered in the Second Report (A New Pension Settlement for the Twenty-First Century) nor were they offered as part of the solutions package for reform.

  However, PIMA supports reform on pensions because it agrees with the broad conclusions of the Pensions Commission's Challenges and Choices report about the state of pensions savings in the UK. Millions of Britons are not saving enough for their future to provide for themselves adequately in retirement. If no further provision is made, many people will face their retirement living on only the State Pension and other associated state benefits. However, there is a great deal of evidence to suggest that better can be done.

  To that end, it is necessary to make long-term and retirement savings better fit the lives people lead. The current system is woefully outmoded by changes in lifestyle, career patterns, life expectancy, and technology. In the words of the New Pension Settlement for the Twenty-First Century the current pensions arrangements and choices are simply "not fit for purpose". Those who are not in regular work or have multiple jobs often fall through the cracks. Those who shift from one employer to another are often burdened with many pensions with small amounts of contributions.

  Pensions reform should ensure access to modern, flexible, transparent, portable, and a cost-efficient means of saving. Much of the debate recently has centred on cost. PIMA and its members believe that an ISA-style retirement account offers many additional attractions that make it suitable for today and into the future.

Building on the ISA Success—The Savings and Retirement Account (SaRA)

  For the past two years, PIMA has advocated the introduction of a retirement-specific savings wrapper entitled the Savings and Retirement Account (SaRA). The SaRA would build upon the success of the ISA. It would be a long-term account in which funds accumulate towards retirement income provision. Like the ISA and the Child Trust Fund (CTF), this scheme would be defined as a wrapper and would hold funds of varying types chosen by the investor. Permissible investments would be any FSA-qualifying investment. Employers could pay funds into a SaRA, just like existing pension arrangements.

  The rules and regulations would be very similar to those of the Child Trust Fund, but access to the funds would be restricted until retirement and the scheme would operate under pensions legislation and attract pension tax relief. The key differences to most current pensions is that they would have the option of operating without trustees but could rely on the use of nominees to restrict the underlying beneficiaries access to the funds—this will come into force on A day; the scheme will be regulated by the FSA—they have stated that they will regulate personal pensions from April 2007, and the pension provider rules should be widened to increase competition—this has been the subject of a recent consultation by the Treasury and will hopefully be in place by or before April 2007.

  Thus hopefully the legal framework for the SaRA should be in place before 2007.

Why SaRA?

  Funds would be portable—assigned to people, not "employees". Thus if a person moves jobs, they would keep the same SaRA account whether they have only one or fifty jobs over the course of their life. This would prevent proliferation of many small pension pots which is recognised to be a very serious problem with the current system.

  The SaRA is transparent. Investments can be valued at any time.

  The SaRA is simple. Just as over 16 million people understand the ISA, the SaRA would be immediately comprehendible by most prospective savers. Saving with the SaRA isn't hard. Get the SaRA wrapper. Pay money in. Attract tax relief. Make choices (advised or unadvised) on your investments.

  Greater coverage for lower earners could easily be achieved. The SaRA is ideal for those not well-served by the classically defined "pensions industry" or through ever-dwindling occupational pensions schemes. A single, simple product means lower and middle earners would be equally well-placed for saving. Additionally, since they have traditionally not saved in pension products, there may be added incentives to add smaller amounts and attract tax relief.

  The SaRA empowers the consumer to make choices about their investments and how to best achieve growth. They can choose to amass greater funds through minimising cost of investment, which was a major emphasis in the second Pensions Commission Report and ultimately led to their recommendation of an NPSS. However, other investors may choose to pay a higher price for what they deem to be potentially better performing investments. The consumer is empowered with the SaRA model in a way that they are not with the NPSS model.

  Flexibility is a necessity of modern life. The SaRA would allow inflow of funds to stop and start at the will of the account holder. Thus if funds need to be diverted elsewhere for other needs, the integrity of the SaRA remains. It doesn't lapse. It doesn't expire. Since the SaRA is not tied to the workplace, career breaks for carers and parents have no effect either.

  Costs are an important issue, because as has been demonstrated in the Pensions Commissions' findings, higher fees and charges can have both a detrimental effect on the decision to save and can result in significantly less accumulation of funds. The SaRA wrapper would ideally be available at no direct cost, as are many ISAs.

  The nature of the qualifying investments for the SaRA would retard excessive charges. There has been much attention paid to the annual management charges (AMC). There is every reason to believe that the wide range of qualifying investments and providers would create a competitive marketplace where charges would be kept low. This is an issue that would need to be further explored with individual providers, but on the surface, there isn't any reason why providers could not provide special "SaRA-friendly" AMCs. It is also anticipated that investment options would include low risk "Stakeholder"-style funds as used in Child Trust Funds and bond and money market funds.

Why is SaRA a favoured alternative to NPSS?

  The SaRA is a market-based solution that would allow consumers to choose from amongst many different providers for their investments. That compares with the proposed NPSS whose gatekeeper (HM Government) contracts mass volumes of funds to wholesale markets. In this scenario, it is unlikely that market providers would ever come into contact with the saver or know his/her needs.

  SaRA would undoubtedly give the consumer more choice of investments while allowing greater accommodation of different risk tolerances amongst investors than the NPSS scheme.

  A market-based solution would allow innovation and competition to thrive in the marketplace.

  The SaRA builds on an existing context that 16 million Britons already have—the "ISA Experience". There is no reason to "re-invent the wheel" when evidence strongly suggests that there is already a solution people understand and like.

  The SaRA would enhance the financial capability and education of savers. In contrast, the NPSS simply channels the money through Government or some centralised clearing mechanism that then passes it on to highly sophisticated institutional asset managers.

  Savers could easily know the value of their investments. How would one value his/her NPSS savings?

Is the SaRA mutually exclusive with NPSS?

  No. Given the open architecture design of the SaRA, there is no reason why a person's NPSS account could not be held within a SaRA, allowing them to hold other investments as well. For instance, they may seek to invest via NPSS as they look for savings accumulation through lower cost. In other investments, they may be willing to pay higher costs because they think that returns on investment represent good value for money paid.

  The SaRA and NPSS, as it is proposed in the Second Pensions Commission Report, have some important features like flexibility and portability in common. The most redeeming overall feature of the SaRA is its open architecture design—thus there is no reason why they should be incompatible.

The Way Forward

  The opportunity embodied in the SaRA concept represents a quantum leap forward in thinking around long-term/pensions savings. Throughout the first part of 2006, providers in many different disciplines (including life companies, financial advisers, fund supermarkets, fund managers, etc.) will be coming together in a working group hosted by PIMA to scope the specific details of products operating under this proposed scheme. We would warmly welcome all, including representatives from the Department for Work and Pensions, HM Treasury, and HM Revenue & Customs to be participants in this process.

  It is PIMA's view that for a number of reasons, principally to do with benefits and taxation, pensions are not the best solution for all consumers. PIMA has been working with its members to design a tax incentivised savings scheme based on the ISA philosophy with ISA tax rules which may be more appropriate for this segment of society. In outline this scheme would be very similar to the CTF, would start at age 18, the monies in the scheme could only be accessed at age 55 when the scheme would convert into one looking very similar to the existing ISA. This would enable participants to withdraw funds post age 55, when required and with no tax liability.

  Further, in forthcoming pension reform legislation, we encourage the Government to put savers first by allowing them to save for retirement as many already do successfully in ISAs. This can be best achieved through the introduction and promotion of the SaRA by HM Government and the savings industry in mutual cooperation.

March 2006






34   Projected figure based on past years' amounts invested in Individual Savings Accounts, HMRC table 9.4. Back

35   2005 Budget Report. HM Treasury, p. 111. Back

36   "Private pensions contributions: updated estimates, 1996-2004." Economic Trends 622. Office of National Statistics. September 2005, p. 31. This is based on the NQ5. Back

37   Extrapolated from Economic Trends 622 and the HMRC Table 9.4. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2006
Prepared 24 May 2006