Select Committee on Treasury Written Evidence


Memorandum submitted by The Standard Life Assurance Company

    —  The Pensions Commission assumes that charges under a NPSS should be around 0.3%, as this is the expected long-term level of charge for the Swedish funded defined contribution (FDC) scheme. This assumption is flawed. Some functions of the Swedish FDC scheme are heavily subsidised by the Swedish taxpayer and, therefore, are not covered by the 0.3% charge.

    —  Using the Pensions Commission's own figures, a flat single annual management charge of 0.3% requires whoever runs the NPSS to accumulate losses for the first 30 years, with debts peaking at over £3.5 billion. If the government run the NPSS then MPs need to be aware of this long-term funding commitment. If the private sector puts up this capital then it may need to make significant additional interest charges to reflect the risks inherent in this project and, in particular, the long payback period.

    —  The Regulatory Update 64 rule should be dropped. There is no need to replace this with a similar rule in the run-up to a NPSS taking effect.

    —  Providers are unlikely to want to serve a large part of the employer pension market over the next four years (until the introduction of a NPSS). The current distribution model requires payments to be made to intermediaries to establish and develop new pension schemes. These costs are unlikely to be recouped if charges fall to 0.3% in four year's time.

    —  NPSS should be bought by savers without regard to the current Conduct of Business rules. However, advisers should take account of the existence of a NPSS in making recommendations.

    —  The NPSS should fit within the new simplified tax regime, due to take effect on 6 April 2006.

INTRODUCTION

  1.  Standard Life is the market leading provider of group money purchase pension schemes in the UK. Due to the overlapping nature of the current private pension system and proposals made by the Pensions Commission, we are keen to participate in the debate into the possible introduction of a National Pension Savings Scheme (NPSS).

  2.  We note that the Committee is not seeking submissions which are circulated elsewhere. However, bearing in mind the parallel inquiry that the Work and Pensions Select Committee is conducting, there are areas of overlap which means that some of the content of this response is duplicated in our response to the other inquiry.

  3.  There are a number of factors that will affect the operational cost of a NPSS. The main factors are:

    —  The shape and level of charges levied against savers' accounts (this is a determinant of the amount of debt that the system would build up in the early years, the cost of this debt being an operational expense).

    —  Take-up rates (a higher number of joiners will help defray fixed costs).

    —  How quickly wages, and therefore, contributions rise (again this is a determinant of debt levels in the early years).

    —  How many people leave the system each year (paid-up accounts).

    —  Any costs associated with enrolling people into the scheme, and the extent to which information and advice is required.

    —  The level of service provided to savers (regular communications, access to telephone and internet help, and so on).

    —  The regulatory regime imposed by government and the Financial Services Authority.

  4.  A main topic of your inquiry concerns the regulatory and distribution issues connected with the introduction of a NPSS. In addition, you also ask how government can avoid the difficulties encountered by Stakeholder Pensions. However, we note your interest in the operational costs of a NPSS and we therefore begin our response there.

THE NATIONAL PENSIONS SAVINGS SCHEME

  5.  We have several comments to make about the Pensions Commission's recommendation to establish a NPSS. The first of these concerns the level of charges.

NPSS CHARGE LEVELS

  6.  The target level of charge set by the Pensions Commission is 0.3%. The Commission bases this expectation upon the long-term cost of the Swedish funded defined contribution scheme.

  7.  However, in Sweden's funded defined contribution scheme (premium pension), the average charge is currently 0.64%, despite having now received ten year's worth of contributions. The charge on the default fund is 0.37%—still above the Commission's target (1). The Swedes do not expect average charges to fall to 0.3% until 2020 (by which time, 25 years worth of contributions will have been invested).

  8.  Another important fact ignored by the Pensions Commission is that the account charge in Sweden only covers part of the cost. The government agency that operates the premium pension (the Premium Pension Authority or PPM) has a large part of its expenses met by central government. Specifically, the PPM shares the cost of collecting contributions with the income pension (Sweden's main state pension scheme). It also shares the cost of communicating with savers—including the Swede's famous "orange envelope" that is sent out annually.

  9.  The cost of these shared services amounted to as much as SEK 426 million in 2005 (1). But to date, the PPM has paid nothing towards these shared services. That means the PPM's costs have been directly subsidised by the Swedish taxpayer for the last 10 years. If the PPM were to share these costs equally with the income pension then the PPM's share of these shared costs could be as much as SEK 213 million a year in 2005 terms.

  10.  If shared costs in previous years were of a similar size (for example, SEK 454 total in 2004), the Swedish taxpayer has already provided subsidies to the PPM of over SEK 2 billion in 2005 terms. Actual declared debts of the PPM amount to SEK 1.86 billion (1). Had these shared expenses been borne by PPM in previous years, then outstanding debts would more than double the declared level. Historic interest costs on this debt would also have been much higher, adding to the accumulated deficit.

  11.  To put the extra ongoing cost in perspective, the declared operating costs of the PPM (the amount on which account charges is based) were only SEK 220 million in 2004 (1). This means that the PPM's costs would almost double if it were to pay a half share of shared expenses.

  12.  Yet even when the PPM starts paying a share in 2005, it will only pay a share in proportion to the size of the contributions collected relative to the whole. As the income pension has compulsory contributions of 16% and the premium pension just 2.5%, the proportion of shared costs it will meet will only be 2.5/18.5ths.

  13.  If such a system were put in place in the UK (the Pension Commission's proposed NPSS is very similar to the Swedish premium pension), it is far from clear whether it would be able to share the costs of collecting premiums with the basic state pension. Her Majesty's Revenue and Customs has reportedly ruled out this option because the IT infrastructure would not be able to cope.

  14.  In that case, a UK version of the premium pension would have to pay for the full costs of collecting contributions, unless our government chose to subsidise the account charges with taxpayers' money.

  15.  If, in Swedish PPM terms, operating expenses of SEK 220 million are equivalent to a target charge 0.3% (after 25 years of operation), then the target charge in 2020 would have to be significantly higher if annual operating expense were instead SEK 646 million in 2005 terms (SEK 220 million plus SEK 426 million).

  16.  The Pensions Commission's assumption that 0.3% is an achievable 25-year target based upon the experience of the Swedish funded defined contribution system is seriously flawed for the reasons given above.

  17.  If the Government is to proceed with its own scheme then taxpayers ought to be aware of the likely costs of such a scheme and that taxes will be used to subsidise the annual management charges as happens in Sweden.

  18.  We recommend that the Committee carry out its own investigation to establish the facts. Specifically, whether and when an annual management charge of 0.3% is attainable.

NPSS CHARGE STRUCTURE

  19.  Flat annual management charges such as those proposed by the Pensions Commission do not cover the substantial investment required in the early years of any new system. Investment is required to establish the IT and other administrative infrastructure. However, the major capital requirement comes from subsidising charges in the early years.

  20.  Standard Life has calculated that, based upon the Pensions Commission's own cost and coverage estimates, the NPSS would not reach break-even until its 30th year. This analysis makes the following assumptions:

    —  That six million people save via the NPSS (Pensions Commission estimate).

    —  Charges of 0.3% (Pensions Commission estimate).

    —  IT and administrative systems establishment £500 million (Pensions Commission estimate).

    —  Account set-up expense £90 per member (Pensions Commission estimate).

    —  Account maintenance cost £25 per annum (Pensions Commission estimate).

    —  Paid-up account maintenance cost £19.50 (Pensions Commission estimate).

    —  Average annual amount of saving per member £1,000 (Pensions Commission estimate).

    —  People retire from the NPSS based upon a 40-year cycle, ie at the rate of 150,000 per annum (Standard Life estimate).

    —  Termination expenses are the same as account set-up charges of £90 per retiring member (Standard Life estimate).

    —  Members retiring from the NPSS take their funds with them (for example, they buy annuities) and the 0.3% charge on these funds stops.

    —  People join the NPSS (eg school/university leavers, immigrants) at the rate of 150,000 per annum.

    —  Interest on NPSS debts is charged at a rate of 4% (Standard Life assumption based upon long-term gilt redemption yields).

    —  Funds grow at a nominal rate of 6% per annum, before charges (Standard Life estimate).

    —  200,000 people (3.3% of members) per annum leave the NPSS before retirement and their account becomes paid-up. For example, they emigrate or join a better quality scheme that has opted-out of the NPSS (Standard Life estimate).

  21.  On the basis of this analysis, the NPSS will run up debts of £3.5 billion by year 18 (assuming cost and contribution inflation of 4% a year) or £3.1 billion in year 16 (assuming cost and contribution inflation of 2.5% a year). See Appendix 1 which illustrates the net capital requirements under each of these projections.

  22.  This raises two important financial questions for members of parliament, if they are asked to support plans for a government-run NPSS. Firstly, are they prepared to sanction a new national savings scheme that will require the country to borrow to subsidise charges on what are effectively private pension savings? Note that the bulk of this borrowing could not be regarded as an investment in the infrastructure of the UK. Secondly, are MPs prepared to sanction a NPSS that will not break even until 2035 on optimistic assumptions? MPs need to make a judgement whether this policy will endure long enough to break even.

  23.  If government decides that an NPSS-style savings scheme is desirable, then the only other alternative would be to ask the private sector to run the scheme instead.

  24.  However, the economic and structural costs of an NPSS-style alternative, at a flat annual management charge of 0.3% per annum, are little different for the financial services industry than they are for government. The estimated costs of running such a scheme, and laid out in Appendix F of the Pensions Commission's Second Report, were derived from discussions that the Pensions Commission had with the industry.

  25.  Indeed, the cost of running the scheme (before any profit margin is taken into account) is likely to be higher for the private sector than it would be for government. There are two reasons for this:

    i.  In addition to supplying capital to finance start-up costs and subsidise charges until break-even point, the industry must also hold capital reserves (solvency margin capital).

    ii.  The cost of capital to the financial services industry is higher than the cost of capital for government. If financial services companies raise equity from their shareholders, those shareholders will typically be expecting a gross return on that capital of between 10% and 15%; substantially higher than the rate the government can borrow money at. In the case of this particular project, shareholders are likely to demand an even higher return, due to the added risk of a long payback period and the fact that no previous pension reform has lasted much beyond 10 years.

  26.  Alternative charging structures would reduce this capital strain. One example would be a mixture of a regular monthly administration fee of £2 per month and an annual management charge of 0.3%.

  27.  Based upon this charging structure, the projected net capital requirement is set out in Appendix 2. This reduces the peak capital requirement to just over £1.1 billion in year four, with break-even reached in year 14.

  28.  The effect of this style of charging structure on the saver is minimal. Appendix 3 shows that the net loss of retirement savings is 6.63% of a hypothetical charge-free fund for a typical NPSS saver (2) at a flat charge of 0.3%.

  29.  However, when a £2 monthly administration fee is added, the net loss increases to only 8.87% of a hypothetical charge-free fund.

  30.  To put this into perspective, the net loss of fund resulting from current stakeholder charges (1.5% for the first 10 years and 1% thereafter) is 20.76% of a hypothetical charge-free fund.

  31.  Appendix 3 also shows the net loss of charge-free fund for other selected charging structures.

  32.  In cash terms, the fund value at retirement (in today's money and assuming future price inflation of 2.5%) for a typical NPSS saver (2) is £98,654 with a £2 per month administration fee added, as against £101,088 with the only charge being a 0.3% annual management charge. The hypothetical charge-free fund is £108,261.

  33.  Based upon current stakeholder charges, the today's money value of estimated retirement savings is only £85,791. Note that although stakeholder charges are higher than the charging structures mentioned above (and those laid out in Appendix 3), these new structures are only made possible by changes to state pension policy and changes to the regulatory and legislative environment.

  34.  At current annuity rates, these funds would generate monthly incomes of:

    —  £528 (0.3% annual management charge only throughout);

    —  £515 (0.3% annual management charge throughout plus a £2 per month administration charge); and

    —  £448 per month (current stakeholder charges).

  35.  If the government does want the financial services industry to run an NPSS-style scheme, then industry and government must be willing partners. The industry is not seeking to make excessive profits from running such a scheme and has suggested that this is overseen by an independent regulator.

  36.  We recommend that the Committee explore alternative charging structures to that proposed and the suggestion of an independent regulator whose job, amongst other things, would be to ensure that savers get a fair deal.

NPSS ALTERNATIVEWHO SHOULD RUN IT?

  37.  In the insurance industry's favour is the fact that much of the initial capital cost required to pay for IT and other administrative infrastructure has already been incurred. The incremental cost to tailor administrative systems to the needs of an NPSS-style alternative would, therefore, be relatively light.

  38.  Other considerations are that the insurance industry has the experience necessary to administer a national scheme, for example, we have the systems and processes necessary to:

    —  communicate effectively with scheme members (via telephone, internet and post);

    —  collect contributions from employers and reconcile the amount of those contributions;

    —  report contribution discrepancies to The Pensions Regulator;

    —  keep records; and

    —  account for investments.

  39.  Importantly, the insurance industry has the capacity to handle the expected volumes.

  40.  We recommend that the Committee explore these issues with each of the parties that has tabled a bid to run an alternative to the NPSS.

REGULATION—ADVICE

  41.  At the level of charge required by the Pensions Commission, NPSS pensions will be bought (by default) rather than sold. There is simply no margin available to pay for any distribution cost, whether that is persuasion or full regulated advice.

  42.  Advisers do need to be aware of a NPSS and any recommendations they give should take into account its existence. To this extent, the FSA should recognise NPSS in its Conduct of Business rules.

  43.  However, the FSA need not continue with the Regulatory Update 64 (RU64) rule that required the recommendation of non-stakeholder pensions to be justified as to their superiority over stakeholder pensions. Nor should they extend this rule to cover a NPSS.

  44.  There are two reasons for this. First, a clear division is now apparent between non-stakeholder and stakeholder products. This was not the case when RU64 was first introduced. However, since then, the design of stakeholder pensions has largely stood still, constrained by their charge cap. On the other hand, personal pensions and group personal pensions have changed markedly, such that they now offer a much wider range of funds and other options than stakeholder pensions.

  45.  The second reason is that the Pensions Commission imposes its own quality condition on schemes that opt-out of the NPSS. These must (in charges and contributions terms at least) be equivalent to or better than a NPSS.

  46.  In the interim—between now and the advent of NPSS—we are unlikely to see any rush to sell the current higher charge (relative to NPSS) products. In particular, any schemes which fail to meet the opt-out conditions will necessarily convert to the NPSS.

  47.  So, rather than there being a last minute rush to sell new pension schemes, the opposite is likely to be true. Providers are unlikely to want new schemes today that fail to meet the standards set by a NPSS, or schemes where there was a likelihood on the part of the employer to "level down" to NPSS in 2010.

  48.  The Committee should be aware of this issue and should consider the impact on employees and employers if the financial services market finds it impossible to serve any but the best quality group pension schemes over the next four years.

REGULATION—PRUDENTIAL

  49.  We would expect the FSA to maintain its current role in overseeing providers' financial soundness, risks inherent in strategy, control mechanisms, corporate governance and so on.

THE ROLE OF THE TREASURY

  50.  The Treasury's involvement in pensions is largely related to setting the tax laws within which pensions operate. In examining how the NPSS fits in, the Treasury should pay close consideration to the new simplified tax regime that is to take effect on 6 April 2006.

  51.  There will be a temptation to regard a NPSS as being outside of the new tax regime. However, if such a path is followed, numerous difficulties will arise in the inter-relationship of two tax regimes. Any new NPSS should, therefore, be part of the new tax regime that takes effect on 6 April 2006.

  52.  One potential side effect of the combination of the new tax regime and a NPSS is that savings (if these are all the private savings one has) can be "trivially commuted" up to a value of 1% of the lifetime allowance (£18,000 in 2010-11 terms).

  53.  Given that a fair proportion of NPSS savers will be first time retirement savers, it is likely that these people will be able to commute their NPSS savings at retirement, rather than buy a pension.

  54.  If they then spend their commuted fund values, these people will fall back on the state for support. This will have an impact on the Pensions Commission's projections that indicated that the number of people on means-tested benefits would fall.

  55.  Assuming that the lifetime allowance increases in line with price inflation, it is unlikely that anyone earning less than £20,000 in today's terms, and with no pension savings other than those from a NPSS, will exceed 1% of the lifetime allowance before 2020 (the first 10 years of the NPSS).

LESSONS FROM STAKEHOLDER

  56.  The key lesson learned from stakeholder for providers is that single charge products introduce an enormous business risk, particularly if savings are switched to another provider before costs can be recouped.

  57.  The consumer is also badly served by the design of stakeholder. The level of the charge cap allowed some inducements to be paid to intermediaries, but not enough such that full advice could be given.

  58.  Providers rationally offered intermediaries as much commission as they could afford within the confines of the charge cap. However, in doing so, they made optimistic assumptions about how long that business would remain on their books to justify these payments. Therefore, instead of charging consumers more for the significant risks being run in selling stakeholder pensions, providers sold business on uneconomic terms. It is unlikely such a situation will persist or be repeated. (3)

  59.  The design of the NPSS should be such that it encourages providers to compete for savers' attention by either providing exceptional service/flexible products/strong investment returns and/or competes for the saver's attention by offering the lowest charges.

  60.  Single charge products produce a cross-subsidy from long-term savers to short-term savers. And, as noted earlier, borrowing to subsidise charges may not present those consumers with the best deal if interest on that borrowing has to be paid back to shareholders at rates of between 10% and 15%. Therefore, different charge designs, other than a flat annual management charge, should be considered (see earlier discussion in paragraphs 26-36).

REFERENCES

   (1)   Private discussion with PPM officials in February 2006 and PPM Annual Report 2004

   (2)   Typical saver based upon saving £1,000 per annum as per Pensions Commission estimates. Fund growth 6% per annum nominal. Charges and contribution inflation 4% per annum. Figures quoted are based upon saving £1,000 per annum over 40 years. Net present values arrived at using 2.5% future price inflation assumption. Source of annuity rates is FSA comparative tables, highest quote available on 27 March 2006.

   (3)   E.g. see "Polly put the kettle on", Ned Cazalet, January 2006.

March 2006








 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2006
Prepared 24 May 2006