Select Committee on Treasury Written Evidence


Memorandum submitted by Fidelity International

SUMMARY

  1.  Fidelity International believes that a National Pension Savings Scheme (NPSS), as proposed by the Pensions Commission, would have the potential to provide cost-effective, meaningful retirement provision for its target population, ie those who do not have access to a good work-based alternative.

  2.  The Commission acknowledged that there is a great deal of good quality private-sector pension provision already in existence but that it is increasingly under pressure. Unless the NPSS is implemented and managed carefully its introduction could threaten this existing provision still further.

  3.  If an NPSS is to be introduced broadly along the lines envisaged in the Pensions Commission's report there are certain features that would be key to the success both of the NPSS itself as well as to existing work-based pensions:

    —  automatic enrolment through the workplace together with an employer contribution;

    —  a clear distinction between the NPSS and employer-sponsored arrangements;

    —  flexibility on the "target" costs for running NPSS;

    —  limiting the contributions that can be made to NPSS;

    —  simplified processes to enable easier transfer from one defined contribution scheme to another.

POTENTIAL BENEFITS OF AN NPSS

  4.  As a low-cost retirement savings vehicle with centralised contribution collection, the NPSS would have the potential, if properly managed, to meet the needs of those individuals who currently have no access to a good work-based pension scheme—something that Stakeholder failed to do. Automatic enrolment through the workplace would ensure that inertia helped build up retirement savings. And with default enrolment, there would be no need for advice or marketing, thus keeping costs down. Limiting employer contributions to 3% of "relevant earnings" would help employers manage the costs, especially if the NPPS introduction were phased.

  5.  A cap on contributions to NPSS and suitable banding for relevant earnings would be essential to help mitigate the risk of adversely affecting current work-based schemes.

  6.  Limited, or even zero, investment choice will keep costs low and help differentiate NPSS from good work-based schemes. However, if the Government failed to strike the right balance between the NPSS and the interests of workplace pension schemes, it would risk harming the overall level of pension provision making the NPSS merely an adjunct of the State pension system. State pension provision would be the sole source of retirement income for all but the wealthiest.

EMPLOYERS' WORK-BASED SCHEMES

  7.  Existing work-based arrangements are already providing excellent pensions for millions of people. It would be essential that the eventual implementation of an NPSS did nothing to weaken the incentive for employers to continue making such provision available. For example, existing schemes can more accurately cater for different workforce structures, eg through tiered and matching contribution designs. The all-or-nothing opt out from NPSS could facilitate entry to employer schemes at a lower cost than proposed for NPSS, although controls would be necessary to avoid abuse.

  8.  It is also in the Government's interest to have good workplace schemes. If the NPSS were to crowd out private schemes, it would in effect become a nationalised pension scheme and an adjunct to state pension provision. With employers simply collecting contributions and passing them on, NPSS could come to be viewed as just another form of national insurance contributions. Crucially, this could also lead to lower overall levels of individual retirement saving.

OPTIMUM FRAMEWORK

  9.  If the goal is greater provision for all, it may seem counter-intuitive to argue that a new NPSS be kept clearly separate from existing arrangements. But, in Fidelity's view, this would be essential to ensure that the NPSS served its purpose of providing a minimum adequate level of pension support for those who need it, when they need it while still encouraging existing schemes to grow. Proper separation will mitigate the risk of employers levelling down (although this will undoubtedly happen to some degree—as some employers would have a fixed budget for pension costs and if spread wider, would result in the available budget being spread more thinly).

  10.  Where the employer's scheme meets the conditions necessary to be deemed a "good" scheme, employees should be automatically enrolled. Any employee who decided not to join that scheme, however, could opt out. If they did so the employer should be under no obligation to enrol them into the NPSS as this would incur additional expenditure that would undermine the viability of the employer's existing arrangements. With the new three-month vesting provision for trust-based schemes (and immediate vesting for contract-based schemes) there would be no fear that individuals with short tenure of service would lose out. Employees who joined their employer's scheme should not be able to make additional contributions to the NPSS, or if they were permitted to do so, this should be outside the employer's payroll system.

  11.  The advantages of this would be that:

    —  it would produce benefits greater than those available through NPSS for most employees, including valuable death in service and ill-health benefits;

    —  it would keep down administration costs for employers as they would only have to operate one payroll deduction system;

    —  there would likely be less loss of assets, as those employees who wanted to make additional voluntary contributions (AVCs) would be likely to do so under these arrangements. Hence, there would be greater mitigation of per capita cost increases resulting from loss of scale;

    —  employees who did not want, or could not afford to make any pension provision could opt out altogether;

    —  there would be no issues of advice.

  12.  The disadvantage would be that people who opted out would be likely to have no pension coverage at all. But this could also arise under other arrangements between the NPSS and workplace schemes envisaged by the Pensions Commission. Allowing concurrency of active membership would create greater administrative burdens and lead to greater erosion of good work-based schemes.

IMPLEMENTATION AND INTEGRATION

  13.  Employer schemes should be judged against the NPSS by a simple one-off test. Defined contribution schemes would have to ensure that their design incorporated contribution levels equal to or higher than those payable to NPSS. Contrary to the Pensions Commission's proposals, however, this should not be net of charges as this additional level of compliance would render the test far more expensive to apply—particularly as there would likely be variance of NPSS costs over time. Defined benefit schemes could be subject to a one-off test of equivalence (or better) similar to that currently applicable for contracting out on the reference scheme basis—with actuarial consideration of continuing ability to meet that test when scheme rules are amended.

  14.  It should not be possible to have concurrent membership of NPSS and workplace schemes as to do so would exacerbate the risks of levelling down or forcing the closure of employer-run schemes. Concurrent membership would also increase employer costs by doubling payroll deduction costs and reducing the assets available for employer schemes and thus increasing costs. It would also lead to a "choice" for employees and thus the need for advice—this would increase the costs and risks for all concerned. Employer schemes could, in effect, be reduced to becoming a form of Additional Voluntary Contribution (AVC) scheme—but with greater costs and potentially lower returns. The situation could also arise where individuals on similar conditions, working side-by-side, would have very different retirement outcomes dependent on the decisions they had made. Comparatively poor outcomes from being in NPSS compared to a workplace scheme could also lead to feelings of injustice and claims of mis-selling. Tax relief provisions should also be the same between NPSS and workplace schemes in order to avoid one undermining the other and exacerbating the advice issues.

INVESTMENT ASPECTS

  15.  In order to keep down costs and maximise benefits, the NPSS should offer a relatively limited range of funds options. This would also ensure ease of understanding for consumers. Good work-based schemes will be able to offer a wider range of investment choices. This would help differentiate work-based schemes from the NPSS.

COSTS

  16.  A 0.30% limit on costs might be achievable over the longer term. However, if this limit were imposed inflexibly, it could have adverse consequences for workplace schemes and the overall level of pension provision. Asset levels, and thus, revenue would be low at the outset and if the cost limit were set rigidly at 0.30%, this might require higher contribution levels or widened "relevant earnings" levels in order to come within the limit. This could have the perverse effect of drawing assets away from workplace schemes which would increase their costs and lower returns. Ultimately, it could lead to the NPSS displacing good workplace schemes or a levelling down of benefits. This, in turn, could result in the NPSS being seen as a third tier state pension and lead to lower retirement provision overall.

FRAGMENTATION

  17.  The current legislative framework for allowing transfers of pensions is complex and requires simplification to enable employees to transfer more easily from one defined contribution pension scheme to another. A simplified process would be required if providers were actively to promote transfers as a means of consolidating funds. In principle, transfers between defined contribution arrangements, particularly those meeting the conditions necessary to qualify as a Stakeholder scheme, should be fast-tracked with no need for the usual lengthy compliance requirements imposed by the Financial Services Authority (FSA)—such an approach would appear to be in line with the Government's desire to see light-touch and proportionate regulation.

INFORMATION

  18.  All UK citizens should be given a centralised combined pension forecast, although it is likely that the State would need to obtain the necessary data from private pension providers in order to do so. The information should be shown as a single projected pension figure based on the individual's pension entitlement from all sources including, as appropriate, the State pension scheme and the NPSS. This should be the only information provided on this statement although further detailed information should be available on request.

  19.  Much of the Government's recent research on communicating pension messages indicates that simplicity is the key. It is well known that the morass of well-intentioned disclosure material turns off all but a few pension scheme members and hence detracts from the central message. A single, bold projected pension figure (expressed in today's terms, but without copious, qualifying footnotes explaining how this is derived) would be simple for everyone. There is ample evidence that sophisticated additional communication material and modellers are useful, but only to those inclined to use them. Most individuals are put off if deluged with such information at outset with the result that rather than being able to make an informed decision they will choose to do nothing.

CONCLUSION

  20.  Fidelity has made this submission as a contribution to the debate on the assumption that an NPSS is to be implemented. Although we believe that an NPSS would have the potential to make a positive contribution to the broader pension landscape, it would be important for the initial level of contribution to be set high enough to achieve the objective of lifting contributors out of means-tested benefits, whilst not undermining good corporate schemes. If the Government were to get the balance wrong, it would risk employers moving en masse to NPSS leading to the effective nationalisation of corporate pensions and the perverse outcome of a reduction of overall pension provision.

March 2006





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2006
Prepared 24 May 2006