Contracted-out rebates
330. One possible source of additional revenue for
the Government is from the abolition of contracted out rebates.
Removing the contracted-out rebates would increase receipts of
National Insurance contributions. It would also increase future
state spending on the State Second Pension, since those brought
back into the state scheme would accrue greater rights. The White
Paper sets out both the increase in revenue, and the increase
in state spending, as a result of abolishing contracting out for
Defined Contribution pensions. This is shown in Table 5.
Table 5: State Second Pension and rebate savings
due to the abolition of contracting out for Defined Contribution
schemes, £ billion 2006-07 prices
| 2012
| 2015 | 2020
| 2030 | 2040
| 2050 |
State Second Pension (£ billion) | +0.0
| +0.0 | +0.1
| +1.3 | +3.8
| +5.4 |
Rebates (£ billion) | -4.0
| -4.2 | -4.3
| -4.3 | -4.3
| -5.1 |
Source: Figure 3.viii of White Paper, Volume 2.
331. There were differing views over the appropriate use of the
increase in Government revenues that would arise from the change.
Howard Reed, director of research at the IPPR, and Alison O'Connell,
Director of the Pensions Policy Institute, both argued in favour
of an increase in state support for current pensioners.[421]
In contrast other witnesses, such as Adrian Waddingham (Association
of Consulting Actuaries), Deborah Cooper (Actuarial Profession)
and Professor David Miles (Managing Director and Chief UK Economist
at Morgan Stanley and visiting Professor of Financial Economics,
Imperial College, University of London) argued that it did not
really free up new resources because of the increased liability
arising in the future and stated that the most appropriate use
of the additional revenue would be to run down Government debt.
[422]
332. In its report on The Future of UK Pensions
the then House of Commons Work and Pensions Committee stated that
"Abolition of the contracting-out NI rebates [for both Defined
Contribution and Defined Benefit schemes] would provide an immediate
increase in NI revenue of around £10 billion (1.0% of GDP).
But this would be at a cost of a near equivalent increase in the
state pension bill for future generations of pensioners who would
otherwise have contracted out and so cannot really be regarded
as a method of financing an increase in state pension rights.
The case for and against contracting-out needs to be considered
separately from options for financing an increase in state pension
rights".[423]
333. It is clear that it is not possible to spend
the same resources twice: increased tax revenues from the abolition
of NI rebates cannot be used to both increase state pensions of
today's pensioners and finance the implied increase in future
rights to the state second pension. However, as pointed out by
Alison O'Connell, Director of the Pensions Policy Institute, "in
all the projections of future state pension cost it has been taken
into account that S2P will be run down, or whatever is happening
to S2P, but nowhere is the fact that there is this short-term
change in the contracted-out rebates taken into account."[424]
334. As a result some of the increase in state spending
on pensioner benefits that was presented in Figure 2 will be due
to the abolition of contracting out for Defined Contribution pension
arrangements. This part of the increase in state spending could
be financed from using the increased receipts of NI contributions
(as suggested by Professor David Miles).
335. Figure 2 suggests that state spending on pensioner
benefits would increase by 1.5% of national income between 2008-09
and 2050-51. Of this increase £5.4 billion (in 2006-07 prices
from Table 5) is directly due to the abolition of contracting
out for Defined Contribution schemes. This is equivalent to just
under 0.2% of national income in 2050-51, which suggests that
the remainder - 1.3% of national income - would need to be financed
from increased borrowing, increased taxation or cuts in spending
elsewhere.
336. The Committee believes that the Government
should be explicit about how it intends to use the increased revenue
arising from the abolition of contracting out for Defined Contribution
schemes. In particular, if the revenue is not being used to reduce
Government debt in order to part-finance the resources needed
to implement the White Paper proposals over the longer-term then
the Government should explain why it has deemed this course of
action to be appropriate.
Tax relief
337. The Pensions Commission's Second Report stated
that "Pension tax relief is costly, poorly focussed and not
well understood".[425]
Much of the evidence received by the Committee supported this
view, and argued that reform of tax relief would be desirable.[426]
338. The net cost of tax relief is estimated by the
HM Revenue and Customs as being £12.3 billion per year, with
a further £6.8 billion from employer relief on National Insurance
Contributions.[427]
The Pensions Commission also argued that "the calculation
is complex and it is possible to argue that the figure is an overstatement
since it fails to reflect fully the timing differences between
tax relief given (on contributions) and tax imposed (on benefits).
But it is clear that the cost is significant, as it must be since
many people benefit."[428]
339. The evidence to the Committee suggested that
there were two components of tax relief on pensions that could
be better targeted: the tax-free lump sum and the relief given
to individuals who are higher-rate taxpayers when they are making
pension contributions and not higher-rate taxpayers when they
receive their pension income.[429]
340. The Rt Hon Frank Field MP, Chairman of the Pensions
Reform Group, argued: "I would also hope it would be something
the Committee might consider in that if one looks at the tax concessions
to pension savings, which overwhelmingly benefit the richest -
we have something like 5% of the population gaining over half
of all the tax revenue lost through tax concessions on pension
savings - to allow all of that at the standard rate again would
give us very substantial sums of money to play with."[430]
341. Philip Davis, Professor of Finance and Economics,
Brunel Business School, said that in his view "I think the
tax-free lump sum is an anomaly and I do not really think it is
appropriate. In a sense, it is the Exchequer giving away money;
it will otherwise get the tax back on the pension, instead it
just gives it away. Furthermore, further to my earlier point,
we are [not] annuitising the asset, so it is not being used for
retirement income. I do not think, if we were inventing a pension
system, we would invent a tax-free lump sum, at least not against
the background of the argument that annuitisation is appropriate."[431]
342. The overwhelming consensus, and the view of
the Pensions Commission, appeared to be that the resources currently
allocated to tax-relief could be focussed better. Indeed, were
additional resources required to finance the White Paper proposals
(for example over the period beyond 2020-21) one possible source
could be through reductions in the generosity of tax-relief for
private pension saving.
343. We recommend that the Government responds
to the Pensions Commission view that "pensions tax relief
is costly, poorly focussed and not well understood", highlights
whether it believes the relief could be targeted better, and whether
some of the resources devoted to tax relief might be used to finance
the increases in state spending on pensioner benefits.
412 Ev 370 Back
413
Q 358 Back
414
Q 5 Back
415
Pensions Commission, Final Report, April 2006, p 15 Back
416
Pensions Commission, Final Report, April 2006, p 16 Back
417
Ev 369, para 30 Back
418
White Paper, Annex D, para D.31 Back
419
Q 5 Back
420
White Paper, para 3.35 Back
421
Q 139 [Howard Reed] and Q 30 [Alison O'Connell] Back
422
Q 184 [Adrian Waddingham and Deborah Cooper] and Q 31 [Professor
Miles] Back
423
Work and Pensions Committee, Third Report of Session 2002-03,
The Future of UK Pensions, HC 92, para 156 Back
424
Q 32 Back
425
Pensions Commission, Second Report, November 2005, p 312 Back
426
See, for example: Ev 164, para 3.3; Ev 284; Ev 323, para 14; Ev
398, para 61 Back
427
Figures for 2004-05. Source: Table 7.9 of HM Revenue and Customs
Statistics (http://www.hmrc.gov.uk/stats/pensions/7_9_sep05.pdf).
Back
428
Pensions Commission, Second Report, November 2005, p 312 Back
429
Q 56 [Alison O'Connell] Back
430
Q 138 Back
431
Q 90 Back