Select Committee on Constitutional Affairs Written Evidence


Evidence submitted by Frank H Stephen, Professor of Regulation, School of Law, University of Manchester (LAR 228)

IMPACT OF FIXED PAYMENTS FOR LEGAL AID ON SOLICITOR BEHAVIOUR

  I have been invited to submit this memorandum of evidence to the Select Committee on Constitutional Affairs to aid it in its review of the Implementation of the Carter Review of Legal Aid in England and Wales. It has been suggested that research which I have carried out (with Cyrus Tata of Strathclyde University) on the impact of the introduction of fixed payments for certain categories of criminal legal aid services in Scotland provides insights on the likely behaviour of solicitors in England and Wales to the introduction of block contracts and fixed payment for legal aid in that jurisdiction which may be of interest to the Select Committee.

  Before turning to a discussion of this research I think it important to enter a number of caveats. All of the research which I have carried out on legal aid has been exclusively concerned with the legal aid system in Scotland. Members of the Committee will appreciate that legal aid in Scotland is governed by a separate set of regulations and administrative procedures from those in England and Wales. It is administered by the Scottish Legal Aid Board whose powers derive from separate legislation from that of England & Wales and since devolution legislative authority in this area lies with the Scottish Parliament. In addition, it should be remembered that Scotland has its own distinctive legal system and legal profession. Not only are there differences in law from England and Wales but the differences extend to: the court system; rules of criminal procedure; and the division between the two branches of the legal profession. Scottish solicitors have rights of audience before the courts that extend to a higher echelon of the court system than do their English counterparts. Consequently, the role of the bar (Faculty of Advocates) is less in Scotland than in England and Wales. All of this implies that one must be careful in drawing inferences about how reforms of the legal aid system of England and Wales will operate from experience north of the border. I would also like to make clear that the interpretations of our research which I express here are my own and are not necessarily shared by Cyrus Tata or those who commissioned our research (Scottish Executive Justice Department).

  As an economist one of my interests is the role which incentives play in the legal system. In particular, I am interested in how the legal profession responds to changes in incentives. The change in the nature of payments made to solicitors in Scotland introduced by the Criminal Legal Aid Fixed Payments (Scotland) Regulations 1999 as amended by the Criminal Aid (Fixed Payments) (Scotland) Amendment Regulations 2002 provide a natural experiment to examine responses of lawyers to a change in incentives. They were implemented from 1st April 1999. The proposals emanating from the Carter Review for contracts for the supply of legal aid services to be based on bids for blocks of cases is economically equivalent to the supply of services on a fixed fee basis. Thus the analysis of the Scottish switch to fixed payments for summary criminal legal aid may provide relevant insights.

  Two of the research projects which I have undertaken are concerned with the issue of fixed payments. The first was commissioned by the Law Society of Scotland during the period of consultation prior to the introduction of the legislation. It was an attempt to estimate the likely effects of fixed payments being introduced at the rates proposed. This work was later published as "Reform of Legal Aid in Scotland", Hume Papers on Public Policy, Vol 8, No 3, 2001, pp 23-31. Inter alia, simulations were carried out using unpublished official data on payments of summary legal aid to solicitors to estimate the effect of introducing fixed payments on solicitors carrying out different amounts of summary legal aid work. The effects of introducing fixed payments at both the, then, current average payment level and at the proposed level were estimated. This was done in order to distinguish between the effect of fixed payments per se and the effects of reducing the average payment per case. The estimated effects on the incomes of firms carrying out different amounts of summary legal aid varied greatly. Solicitors doing between 40 and 50 cases were subject to large variations on income from summary legal aid over a five year simulation period whilst those doing fewer than 10 cases were only subject to minor fluctuations in income. Solicitors undertaking more than 400 cases per year were subject to little variation in income from fixed fees per se because their income per case was close to the average income per case. However this group were hit the hardest by the proposed reduction in the level of payments.

  How suppliers would react to the introduction of fixed payments, it was suggested, would depend on their underlying motivations. If solicitors are motivated solely by the interests of their clients it was predicted that in the long run those suppliers who undertook a significant but small amount would move out of this area of work leaving it to larger suppliers who would provide a more routinised service. On the other hand, if the predominant motivation of solicitors is their own financial well being they would reduce their professional input to a level commensurate with the level of remuneration allowing them to devote their time to other more profitable areas of work or to increase the number of summary cases which they undertook. In either of the latter two cases the service provided to clients is likely to fall.

  The implications of this work for the analysis of the Carter proposals are two-fold. Since what is involved is essentially a fixed price contract, a firm's costs will fluctuate depending on the mix of straightforward and more complex cases if a small number of cases is contracted for. Only when the number of cases contracted for is sufficiently large to represent a random sample of all cases will there tend to be a cancelling out of simple and complex cases so that costs for the total number of cases is commensurate with the payments received. Thus it is in the interests of firms for the minimum contract size to be relatively large[134]. However, a second effect of the proposed scheme is likely to produce downward pressure on fees. To the extent that there is competitive bidding for contracts bid prices are likely to be pushed down. The literature on auctions and competitive bidding has identified a phenomenon known as the winner's curse ie the party winning an auction is likely to have overbid. This applies even to very sophisticated bidders (cf. bidding for UK 3rd generation mobile spectrum). The implication is that firms bidding for legal aid contracts are likely to bid low. This will exacerbate the problem of covering their costs. Thus the consequence is likely to be a reduced level of service for clients.

  The second project which I have undertaken (along with Cyrus Tata) was commissioned by the Scottish Executive Justice Department to examine the impact of the introduced of fixed payments from 1999. A summary of the findings of this research is available in Research Findings No 61/2006, Legal Studies Research Programme, Scottish Executive. The impact of fixed payments on case management is discussed in C Tata and F H Stephen, "`Swings and Roundabouts': Do Changes to the Structure of Legal Aid Remuneration Make a Real Difference to Criminal Case Management and Case Outcomes?", [2006] Criminal Law Review, 722-741. The full Report on this project is is awaiting publication by the Scottish Executive.

  This project uses both statistical analyses and interviews with defence lawyers and prosecutors to identify changes in the number of legally aided summary cases, the trajectory of cases through the court system, the incomes of firms from summary legal aid and the way solicitors manage summary cases. It is argued that these measurable changes are a consequence of changes in the behaviour of defence solicitors arising from the introduction of fixed payments. The use of a number of sources of evidence allows evidence from each source to be triangulated by the evidence from the other sources. We believe that the evidence from the different sources is consistent. In particular the interviews with solicitors and prosecutors confirm the inferences drawn from two separate statistical analyses.

  Certain characteristics of the Scottish legal aid system provide a means for measuring changes in solicitor behaviour. In particular, under the Scottish system criminal legal aid is only accessed where a "not guilty" plea is tendered. Accused persons pleading guilty are only entitled to Advice and Assistance and ABWOR. If a reduction in average payment per case (through the introduction of fixed payments) provides an incentive for solicitors to take on more legally-aided cases this might result in a higher proportion of accused persons pleading not guilty, ceteris paribus. Under Scottish criminal procedure there is no prior disclosure of Crown evidence in criminal trials. This has resulted in the defence arranging to have precognitions taken from Crown witnesses. Under the time-and-line system the cost of taking precognitions was treated as an expense claimable from the Legal Aid Board whilst under fixed payments such expenses have to be covered from the fixed payment. Changes in the use of precognitions would then be an indicator of the influence of fixed payments on how cases are handled.

  Our statistical analysis of data supplied by the Crown Office on the proportion of cases terminating at each of four key stages in the criminal prosecution process in summary cases in all Sheriff Courts in Scotland suggested that the proportion of cases terminating at the pleading diet (initial hearing) fell after the introduction of fixed payments. This is consistent with an increase in the proportion of not guilty pleas. However, there was also an increase in the proportion of cases terminating at the Intermediate Diet (pre-trial hearing) and on the day of the trial without evidence being led. Consequently the proportion of cases going to full trial fell. Thus although the proportion of cases with a plea of not guilty rose (and thus the proportion of accused eligible for summary legal aid) that plea was changed to guilty before any trial could take place. Data supplied by the Scottish Legal Aid Board on all legal aided summary cases in the Sheriff Courts for two years prior to and three years after the introduction of fixed payments revealed a consistent pattern of an increase in the proportion of cases being legally aided after the introduction of fixed payments. These two sets of data suggest that the introduction of fixed payments (at a rate below the previous average payment) resulted in more legally aided cases being taken up by solicitors. Our interview data confirmed that such behaviour was being observed by lawyers and prosecutors.

  Further analysis of the legal aid data revealed that firms which were heavily involved in summary legal aid work had dramatically increased the number of cases which they undertook. They also became more assiduous in claiming payments under Advice and Assistance. As a consequence, by the third year after the introduction of fixed payments the income of these firms from Summary Criminal Legal Aid and Advice and Assistance was on average above that prior to the introduction of fixed payments. All of these data suggest that the introduction of fixed payments led to specialist legal aid firms increasing the number of cases undertaken.

  Surveys of defence lawyers and subsequent interviews with them revealed a dramatic fall in the use of precognitions. Interviews with lawyers and prosecutors also suggested a reduction in the preparation of the defence. Again this is consistent with defence lawyers reducing their input to cases following the reduction in fee rates which accompanied the introduction of fixed payments.

  The evidence we have assembled on the consequences of the introduction of fixed payments in summary legal aid in Scotland is consistent with defence lawyers reacting in an economically rational manner to the reduced income per case which fixed fees entailed. Those highly involved in summary legal aid work appear to have reacted by reducing their professional input to cases and producing a more routinised service. The particularities of the Scottish Legal Aid system and Scottish criminal procedure allowed us to pick up indicators of these changes in behaviour which were confirmed in our interview data. I have no reason to believe that the ethical constraints on English solicitors are greater than those on Scottish solicitors. Consequently I would expect that the introduction of bidding for contracts for blocks of work (which is likely to result in a reduction in fees per case) will result in a similar change in behaviour of English legal aid specialists.

  I would like to stress that none of the work I have undertaken allows any inference to be drawn on whether the work done by solicitors either before or after the introduction of fixed fees in Scotland was adequate, excessive or inadequate. All the research allows us to infer is that the level of lawyer input into cases is likely to have reduced as a consequence of fixed fees.

February 2007






134   This is in addition to any reduction in average cost due to economies of scale. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2007
Prepared 1 May 2007