Select Committee on Education and Skills Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 20-39)

PROFESSOR EWART KEEP, PROFESSOR LORNA UNWIN, AND MR ALAN WELLS OBE

21 FEBRUARY 2007

  Q20  Mr Marsden: Alan, can I ask you about other things which Leitch touches on but maybe does not focus on to a great degree. One of the issues, which has been raised by a large number of people, for example, City and Guilds, and various others as well, is obviously the demographic changes which are going to take place over the next few years. Does Leitch give enough attention to the issues of training and retraining and skilling of an older workforce?

  Mr Wells: I do not think so. One of the problems is, if you look at all of the statistics on literacy and numeracy, in fact, more people who are older have problems than younger. There are, I think, technical reasons for this, in the way the testing is done, to be absolutely frank. I think testing is often not of literacy and numeracy skills but of short-term memory, and, frankly, most of us who have got older have worse short-term memories, and I think that is an international problem in the way that the testing is done. There does not seem to be much incentive built into the systems suggested in Leitch for people who are perhaps out of the workforce, not likely to be back in the workforce, particularly people who are "early retired", ie are not looking for jobs, who may have worked for a long while, or cannot get jobs, frankly. Again, Leitch tends to look quite like a report written in the South East of England and in London, which is rather different from parts of the North East of England, as you well know. Because it is, and I can understand this, very economically-driven, with work, really, fundamentally, as its rationale, then it is weak on what you are doing for both older workers who are reaching towards the end perhaps of their career, or are hoping to, or people who are not in the workforce but may have a significant role to play in the skills of the next generation of people coming up. We know the link between parenting and grandparenting and the skills of the younger generation, not least their aspiration, and it seems to me to be extremely weak on that; it is a model driven largely by the interests of a youngish workforce.

  Q21  Mr Marsden: On that particular issue, enabling skills, soft skills, call them what you will, the sorts of things which enable people potentially to get back into the workforce, is Leitch valuing those enough; does the current Government strategy value those enough?

  Mr Wells: No. I do not think it does. I think the strategy is so top-driven, basically, and so narrowly economically-focused, in that sense, I think one economic focus, that it does not value those other skills enough, and it does not, I think, therefore relate to the lives of lots of older workers, in or out of work, basically, probably not living in the South East of England. It seems to me to lack enough vision in that area.

  Q22  Chairman: Professor Keep, you are nodding energetically there?

  Professor Keep: I am sorry. I tend to do that, when I agree.

  Q23  Chairman: Is there anything you want to add; you must agree with that?

  Professor Keep: The one thing I would agree with, it was emphasised, is that one of the other ways in which Leitch, yet again, takes us somewhat backwards from where once we thought we were heading is the way in which everything is about skills which are economically useful, and it is a very narrow, utilitarian definition of economically useful. There are huge rafts of evidence, yet again, that there are many economic benefits from people learning things which are nothing to do with their work; things to do with parenting, things to do with hobbies, voluntary activities, citizenship activities and duties, cultural activities. I fear that we are moving towards a vision of adult learning, adult education, that is based so narrowly on the economy, the workplace and utilitarian values that we are in awful danger of throwing out a very large baby with the bathwater, and I think that would be a huge loss.

  Chairman: Let us move on and we want to go back to productivity.

  Q24  Mr Chaytor: If I can pick up the point which Ewart made earlier, about the higher proportion of people with Level 3 qualifications in Germany; is not that why BMW took over Rover and not the other way round?

  Professor Keep: It is; but you have got to remember that licence to practise runs right across the German economy, so you need to have done an appropriate apprenticeship to become a sales assistant in a retail store. It runs right across the economy. It is a form of labour market regulation which is more common than people think. It exists in the Australian States, not across all occupations but across many more than is the case here. It exists in America, but again on an individual State basis, rather than a federal basis. Quite a lot of countries have far more extensive licence to practise than we have; we do not have it, on the whole, except for a few, very safety-critical and professional occupations, and I think it does help skew the level of qualification when you tot up the totals. Your point though about Germany having a more skilled workforce in manufacturing certainly is true; but, again, we have some studies which suggest that the reason for it is because the German organisations are producing high quality goods in a different market niche from our own. Many of our producers produce things which require lower levels of skill to produce them, because they are further down the value chain. Changing the skills of the workforce may not change the product market strategy of the organisation, on its own.

  Q25  Mr Chaytor: In the long term, is not the German approach to these things more likely to deliver prosperity over a long period of time, because they have got a bigger share of high value manufactured goods?

  Professor Keep: That certainly is true, and Germany has a massively better balance of payments than we have and a massively greater, certainly physical, exporting record than we have. The catch is that, as Leitch suggests, simply supplying more skills, of itself, will not help us. We can have a German-level qualified workforce and many British employers would not know what to do with it; it would not give us a German economy. Their economy now is so different from ours, structurally, in terms of its continuing dependence on high skill, high value added manufacturing; our economy is dependent upon other things. We have to be cautious about saying simply "If we had as many as Germany, we would be like Germany." There are a lot of other things which make Germany different from us.

  Q26  Mr Chaytor: It is the relationship between cause and effect which you are questioning?

  Professor Keep: Yes.

  Q27  Mr Chaytor: Can I come back to the other point you made about the organisation of work; you made the point that maybe other countries are better at organising the level of skills they have, whatever that level is, but surely is not that a critique of management skills? Are you saying that really the British disease is paying insufficient attention to the quality of management and training of people for management in organisational ways?

  Professor Keep: Certainly in part it is a critique of British management, but you could argue that the problems go beyond that, because very often British managers know what they should be doing but then choose not to do it. I think that a lot of the things British managers do, in actual fact, are a rational response to the economic incentive structures which, as managers, they face, at a personal level, in terms of what they will get rewarded with through their pay packet, what the stock market will reward their company for doing, and so on. It is a mixture of both. Yes, sometimes our managers do not have the right skills, but also they have in their heads, sometimes for a very good reason, a different model of what a well-functioning organisation should look like. I think one of the most interesting developments of the last 20 years is the way in which, just as the production line, routine jobs have declined in manufacturing, they have expanded in the service sector, so you go into cheque-clearing factories, you go into call centres, you go into large retail organisations, where the organisation tries to script the interaction between a sales assistant and the customer. If you upskilled massively the people doing those jobs, they could not use the extra level of skill, unless the job changed. It is getting the job to change which is so hard.

  Q28  Mr Chaytor: In our evidence session on Monday of this week, we had some documentation which suggested that the productivity gap between Britain and France, Germany, the USA, was in the order of 15%, but that Britain was about 6% more productive than Japan. I think the score for Britain was 100. Japan was 94, as I recall it. How do you explain that, given that half the goods in our shops are Japanese?

  Professor Keep: First of all, the Japanese service sector is monumentally heavily staffed; it has staffing levels which just make your jaw drop. Secondly, you have got to remember that there are lots and lots of different measures of productivity, and this is one of the huge confusions. There is productivity per hour worked, which is the one that a lot of labour economists think is the best measure, but there are lots of other, different measures and, depending on which measure you choose, the number of hours people work can skew them enormously. If you take just output per worker and you do not compensate for the number of hours they work then countries zoom up and down the league table. Japan is a story of two halves: massively efficient, lean manufacturing organisations, and then still, though it is less the case than it used to be, service sector organisations, like retail and catering, which have levels of staffing at which UK employers would go green with terror when they saw them. In that sense, it is explicable.

  Q29  Mr Chaytor: The productivity indicator is not necessarily an accurate guide to the overall health of the economy or the sense of well-being of a nation; is that what you are saying?

  Professor Keep: It is one indicator, but there are lots of different ways you can measure productivity, and different economies, particularly because the amount of hours that people work in different countries varies enormously; unless you compensate for that you get a very skewed picture. The best measure of productivity, because it is regarded as the most accurate, is the one which compensates for hours worked, so that you get the genuine product. In any given hour, a British worker will produce X, a French worker will produce Y, and because they have got a short working week in France they use their people very productively in the short working week they have got. Labour market regulation comes back in there again. Productivity is only one measure. Balance of payments, which when I was growing up used to be something which was on the news every time it was announced, now no-one seems to care that we have a huge current account deficit, which I find intriguing. There are lots of different measures of well-being, and, again, last week, or was it this week, it blurs, the UNICEF league table on the well-being of children suggests another way in which you can view the well-being of society, and one which might be quite important.

  Q30  Mr Chaytor: Would the introduction of a French-style, 35-hour working week immediately increase Britain's productivity indices?

  Professor Keep: No; because British employers would not know how to cope.

  Q31  Mr Chaytor: It is the skills gap of British employers which is the problem?

  Professor Keep: It would be a real shock. That would be a very interesting experiment, but I think a rather dangerous one; the French moved there in steps. Certainly there is some evidence that if you cap the working week it is one way, one incentive structure, which then forces managers to say, "Okay, if X can work only 40 hours this week, max, then, my goodness, I've got to make sure they work productively." If you think, "Right; well we can force them to do as much unpaid overtime as we like until they drop," then you will not worry too much about whether they are very efficient in any given hour. There are lots of different ways in which you can change productivity but it is best to think about doing it gradually.

  Q32  Chairman: Before Ewart moves away from the UNICEF analysis, there have been some severe criticisms of that thought, in terms of the age of its data and the accuracy of its measurement?

  Professor Keep: It is like everything, it is a dip-stick.

  Q33  Mr Chaytor: Back to skills and productivity; what is your view then? You are saying, first of all, skills are related only remotely to productivity; secondly, productivity itself is a pretty nebulous concept because there are different ways of measuring it; and, thirdly, productivity itself is not related directly to the health of the economy or the welfare of the nation. What is your recommendation as to the way forward, in the context of Leitch and the Government's intentions: do nothing, or are there certain areas of skills that we do need to invest in more?

  Professor Keep: Skills are important but they are, as Leitch admits and as the PIU report suggested, a derived demand; so, in a sense, they are dependent on other first order decisions. If enough of our employers decide to move up market to produce goods and services which require high levels of skill and simultaneously we supply that skill then we have a recipe for economic growth and success. My fear about Leitch is that Leitch says basically that skills is the, as he put it, in capital letters, THE main lever we can pull. I do not think it is. It is one of a number of levers which we have to pull simultaneously and pull in quite crafty and complex ways. Simply pumping more people with paper qualifications into the economy, of itself, will not be enough. Therefore, I think we need to be very cautious about chasing blanket targets for qualification levels, unless we are clear what economic development strategies we have in place to ensure that those skills get used once they are created.

  Q34  Mr Chaytor: Accepting your point about the economic development strategy being the prime driver, is there not a value to the nation and to the individual and to the wider community in generally raising the level of skills, in the same way there is in generally increasing the number of graduates?

  Professor Keep: Yes, there is, but again then you might beg the question, if it is general benefit, in terms of the well-being of society, you might not obsess quite so much as Leitch does about economically valuable skills as the sole arbiter; because it is very difficult to judge what is economically beneficial. Many high-end employers say that what they value is creativity and they are not the least concerned about what degree people did; they want someone who happens to have a creative turn of mind and who has been educated in a way which stimulates that creativity. I think a very narrow definition can lead you down something of a blind alley and we need to be slightly more liberal in thinking about what might be economically and societally beneficial. I am not against increasing levels of learning, I am not against increasing levels of education, but I worry about the simplistic assumptions about increasing the levels of skill.

  Q35  Chairman: Do you agree with the drift of that, Alan?

  Mr Wells: Yes, I think I do. I think the problem will be, if we are not careful, that we will have very, very well-educated people in very, very tedious, low-skill jobs; very highly skilled but actually frustrated by that. There is a danger with that. I have always felt that the overall health of our nation, in a sense, is much more complex than just a narrow skills-driven agenda. I am in favour of more education and people being educated better, because I think things like citizenship, and good citizenship, and all of those things, are just as important as the economic drivers. If you look at, and it is not very well explored, the number of young men in prison who cannot read and write or use numbers properly, and it is a very difficult area and it is a chicken and egg area, you have a good reason for thinking that maybe education has a part to play in stopping young men going into prison. Generally I do agree that there is a danger of giving people the idea that more and more skills, more and more certificates, basically, will mean that somehow or another they are going to be in better, more interesting jobs and better off; because unless we can guarantee that then people are going to be in for a sad shock.

  Q36  Mr Chaytor: Let me pursue that point. Your scenario of increasing numbers of people being over-qualified for the jobs they are doing, is not that a very effective way of (a) ensuring either they get out of that job and get a better one quickly, or (b) they bring something to that job and their employer which increases the overall level of the operation, and it moves the employer up the value chain, which was what Ewart was arguing earlier?

  Mr Wells: I think that is right, in theory, but the practice of it is that I think quite often people look at, the quite short term, what is going to be the benefit for them, if the benefit for them is that they are better qualified—and there is a difference, I think, and Ewart has made this point, between skills and qualifications—but they end up still being in a job which does not need those qualifications. I remember, years and years ago, I advertised for somebody who basically was in charge of a stock cupboard; everybody who applied was a graduate. Therefore, did I make the job more interesting by developing more stock cupboards? No, I did not. What I tried to deal with was a whole load of people who were frustrated because they were in a job which did not need the kind of educational background that they had. I am in favour of aspiration, there is no doubt about that, and I am always conscious of the vocational/academic divide, because I want people from working-class communities, who have not had the great advantages, to become doctors and lawyers. I think there is a danger in promising and then not delivering, and then thinking that somehow or other it is down to the individual to demonstrate their wonderful creativity which suddenly will see them promoted up in organisations. Ewart made the point, and I always think, when you are talking about skills, about the person working in the local café, where there are only three employees, and whether they are going to be able to show their creativity in order to be promoted in the business or go into another business. I think it is just a bit more complex perhaps than thinking that, somehow or other, higher skills will drive it in such a way that everybody will move up to jobs which are eminently satisfying for them.

  Q37  Chairman: Surely, if you stretch people, in terms of their skills and training, it gives them more opportunity; they do not have to stay in the same job, in the same occupation? One of the things that I have seen in my own part of Yorkshire is that my population, compared with perhaps Barnsley, or Jeff Ennis', is much more mobile and willing to switch jobs and move quite regularly in order to seek and find a better job. Surely, increasing skills gives the possibility of mobility?

  Mr Wells: To an extent, of course, it does give the possibility of mobility, but the idea that, somehow or other, we are all a mobile population, or that high mobility in jobs is a good thing, is not my experience. As a former employer, I wanted a few people who might stay in the job for a while, because the idea of mobility was costly and disruption. In times of high employment people came into jobs and they were looking at the paper for the next job directly they came. To an extent, of course mobility is a good thing, but we cannot have a whole population of people moving from job to job; lots of people do stay in jobs for a rather long period of time. I am not against ensuring they have the education to make absolutely the most contribution they can in that job, but making the best contribution they can to the life of their community as well is just as important to me.

  Q38  Stephen Williams: Chairman, just to stick to this comparison we have had, between this country and Germany and other countries, about our productivity gap and our skills gap, if you look at what this country is good at, say, the City of London, if you compare it with Frankfurt or Paris, or whatever, everyone working in the City of London, or in Edinburgh or Bristol, in corporate and financial services will have at least Level 4 and more likely Level 5 qualifications and we beat all of our competitors hands down in that area. If you look at manufacturing, is not that where our skills gap is, as well as our productivity gap, so does not that imply that we need more skills in the manufacturing area? What I am trying to say is where we have got high-level skills we do extraordinarily well; where we have not, that is where our productivity gap is?

  Professor Keep: One half is right and one half is wrong, I suppose would be my response. Certainly the economy is quite efficient at allocating the most talented; and you could say that, because of the kinds of salaries that the City and allied business services firms are willing to pay, they take their pick of the brightest graduates. You could say, given that is now one of our major export sectors, the driving force of large chunks of our economy, that is a very efficient allocation of talent. Those manufacturing firms which we have, which have survived this long, on the whole are actually quite productive, it is just that we do not have quite so many of them as we used to have. The biggest productivity problems, and they vary enormously by sector, a lot of them are in the service sector but they are in the bits of the service sector which you might guess have got problems, things like hotels, catering, parts of the transport industry, wholesaling, and so on. Those also tend to be the parts of the economy where the qualifications demanded by employers of large chunks of their workforce are the lowest, often zero, in the sense that employers simply do not use qualifications very much in the recruitment and selection process. It is not clear that simply supplying more skills will change the way those employers conceive of those jobs, or that necessarily it will impact significantly on their productivity, unless they make other changes as well. That is not to say that probably we should not be trying to force those employers in those industries to think harder about skill creation and utilisation, and that is what the Sector Skills Councils are there for, but on its own it may not be enough.

  Q39  Stephen Williams: To quote from the Leitch report: "qualifications are the most common measures of skills." I would guess, from earlier answers, from Mr Wells and Professor Keep, that you are rather sceptical about it. I wonder if Professor Unwin could say whether she is sceptical about that as well?

  Professor Unwin: I am not sure that "sceptical" is the right word. I think qualifications are a measure of skills, to some extent, yes. As Ewart pointed out before, what they do not capture though are large numbers of skills, including soft skills, which people use and develop in the workplace. I would raise though a different issue about qualifications, which I do not think we have touched on yet, and that is, there is a big assumption in Leitch, and in most Government policy, that our qualifications system is sound. We have a very complex qualifications system, particularly on the vocational side, and the key qualification which is used in Government targets is the National Vocational Qualification, the competence-based qualification, which was introduced in the late 1980s. One of the issues which I think is of great concern is the quality of that qualification and the fact that it differs so considerably between sectors, between occupational areas, so we have a notional system of levels, and Leitch uses the notion of the Level 2 as being the key target. The problem with our system of levels is that it varies so enormously from sector to sector, so a Level 2 in parts of the service sector can be achieved very quickly and often through accreditation of existing skills, whereas a Level 2 in areas like engineering, for example, demands a much higher level of general education and takes much longer to acquire. Obviously, qualifications need to be fit for purpose and skills in, say, retailing differ from skills in engineering, but I think we need to have a serious look at whether, in a lot of our occupational areas, the use of Level 2 qualification, and Level 3, in some instances, the notion of this level actually measures what we presume is the quality of skills.

  Mr Wells: Can I make a point, just to clarify. I am certainly not against qualifications, because I think generally people who are against qualifications are people who have got lots of them and I think most people recognise that getting qualifications is important. The point I was making, similar to Ewart, was that qualifications do not capture absolutely everything about knowledge and skills. What I think is important is that the qualifications are real and meaningful. One of my concerns has been the drawing of equivalence between, for instance, Level 2 qualifications and GCSE qualifications. By the nature of it, that is an incredibly crude measure; yet it has now become accepted. These qualification are assessed in entirely different ways. A GCSE in English is totally different, in the way that it is assessed, from a Level 2 qualification through the national test in literacy, and I suspect that no employer will think that they are the same as each other, that their worth has the same value. I think it is quite important that we encourage people to get qualifications but that those qualifications do not turn out to be a con, in the end, that they are worthless, but that they are meaningful. Personally I think that there needs to be a look at the way that equivalence has been drawn between qualifications for adults and what are effectively qualifications at the end of a compulsory schooling period.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2007
Prepared 14 August 2007