Implications for Government policy
41. Having presented its evidence and outlined its
conclusions on the projected impacts of different scenarios of
climate change, and the overall cost-benefits of early and rapid
mitigation, the Stern Review then describes in detail three main
recommended policy responses for mitigation: imposing an extra
monetary charge on emissions; accelerating the development and
deployment of new technologies; and implementing various actions
to overcome structural and behavioural barriers to reducing emissions.
As it introduces these recommendations in summary:
The first essential element of climate change
policy is carbon pricing. Greenhouse gases are, in economic terms,
an externality: those who produce greenhouse gas do not face the
full consequences of the costs of their actions themselves. Putting
an appropriate price on carbon, through taxes, trading or regulation,
means that people pay the full social cost of their actions. This
will lead individuals and businesses to switch away from high-carbon
goods and services, and to invest in low-carbon alternatives.
But the presence of a range of other market failures
and barriers mean that carbon pricing alone is not sufficient.
Technology policy, the second element of a climate change strategy,
is vital to bring forward the range of low-carbon and high-efficiency
technologies that will be needed to make deep emissions cuts.
Research and development, demonstration, and market support policies
can all help to drive innovation, and motivate a response by the
private sector.
Policies to remove the barriers to behavioural
change are a third critical element. Opportunities for cost-effective
mitigation options are not always taken up, because of a lack
of information, the complexity of the choices available, or the
upfront cost. Policies on regulation, information and financing
are therefore important. And a shared understanding of the nature
of climate change and its consequences should be fostered through
evidence, education, persuasion and discussion.[54]
In addition the Review contains a cautionary note
to the effect that it may take some time for such policies to
become widely established and acted upon, and that in the meantime
it will be important to address the potential for public and private
investment decisions to take us further in the wrong direction
for years to come. As it puts it: "In the transitional period,
it is important for governments to consider how to avoid the risks
that long-lived investments may be made in high-carbon infrastructure."
[55]
42. We will use these main policy recommendations
of the Stern Review to help us assess the coherence and effectiveness
of the individual measures in Pre-Budget 2006 as we come to examine
PBR 2006 in the rest of this report; and will continue to refer
to Stern's recommendations in examining future PBRs and other
major announcements of Government policy. In this section, however,
we focus briefly on three particular implications of the Stern
Review which stood out for us in this inquiry.
43. The first of these is the profound scale and,
even more, urgency of the need to act as argued by Stern; and
the implication of this, that we would expect to see a very noticeable
increase in Government policies designed markedly to accelerate
the reduction in UK emissions. Pre-Budget 2006 assumes particular
importance here because it was one of the first major opportunities
for the Government to introduce or increase such policies following
publication of the Stern Review. In this it disappointed many
observers. For example, the Environment Agency observed to us:
The Pre-Budget Report (PBR) itself announced
little new environmental policy, somewhat surprisingly in the
context of the recent publication of the Stern Review. We look
forward to a credible response in the Budget 2007, Comprehensive
Spending Review and any other processes that will unfold through
2007.[56]
For their part, Friends of the Earth, told us:
Certainly the first response that the Government
had to Stern in policy terms was the Pre-Budget Report and there
was shockingly little in there about how to drive the UK to a
low carbon economy. To our view that was exceptionally disappointing
given the very strong statements that both Gordon Brown and Tony
Blair gave at the launch of the Stern Review saying: this is the
most important document to come out of Government in the last
ten years; it is the greatest challenge we face; and it can be
positive for the economy if we tackle this issue. Then to see
so very little in the Budget was immensely disappointing.[57]
The verdict of Green Alliance, meanwhile, was that:
"on the domestic front, there was some encouraging shifts
in the Pre-Budget Report but in overall terms we found it rather
disappointing as a follow-up to Stern."[58]
Discussing what was required in terms of a domestic response to
the Review, Green Alliance expanded:
At present the policy framework does not, in
any of the areas, have the ambition or the strength to drive us
to that kind of speed of emissions reduction. We think you need
changes across the board on trading, on tax, on spending and on
regulation. In spending terms, I think obviously there is a research
and development element to this but we do not see that as central.
It is more using the pricing framework, the tax framework and
the regulatory framework to drive investment in the private sector.
From our perspective there are a whole number of areas in which
there needs to be a step change.[59]
44. More widely, we heard the criticism that the
Government's approach to the Stern Review has been to focus far
more on using it to influence international opinion, rather than
implementing its conclusions in actual policies, especially domestic
policies. This, again, was certainly the view of Friends of the
Earth, who argued:
Firstly, it is very welcome that the Government
is using the Stern Review at an international level to drive progress
there, to get some of the more recalcitrant nations on board.
I think that is a very positive step. I think a problem so far
has been that Treasury ministers in particular have downplayed
the potential for UK action. They are all arguing that unilateral
action is where it is at; we do not need to do very much at the
national level because, again, the argument comes across that
it may damage UK competitiveness, and we should not really act
alone. I think that is a misreading of the Stern Report.
[60]
Green Alliance were somewhat less critical, but echoed
this essential point about the Government's international focus:
From our perspective we agree with the Government
that the primary target of the Stern report is the international
community. It is a global problem but clearly it has profound
implications, firstly, for the Government's domestic policy but,
secondly, also for the Government's international policy on climate
change and related issues.[61]
Elsewhere, Green Alliance have described the Review
as "a challenge not just to the international community,
but also to the UK government that commissioned it".[62]
45. We asked the Financial Secretary whether and
how the Treasury, in particular, was going to change its policies
as a result of the Stern Review. In reply, he suggested that there
would not necessarily be any radical changes in Treasury policy
as a result of the Review in itself:
Joan Walley: [
] Obviously the Stern
Review is at the top of our agenda and what we would like to do
is to ask you how has it changed your thinking?
John Healey: I think the significance
of Stern is less in the way that it has changed our thinking and
more in the way that it has confirmed some of the elements that
were beginning to emerge but perhaps had not been given a strong
enough emphasis within government nor a strong enough recognition
externally.[63]
We then asked him to point to the "specific
proposals in the Pre-Budget Report which are there directly because
of the work of Stern", to which he responded:
John Healey: I said at the very
outset that what Stern did was to not necessarily radically change
our view of what was required but confirm the emphasis and direction
we were giving and in a sense you would not expect a Pre-Budget
Report delivered a matter of a few weeks after the Stern Report
necessarily to be recast in the light of that. Nevertheless I
mentioned the three principal policy areas that Stern is concerned
to see and you can look in the Pre-Budget Report and see elements
or exemplifications of policy action in each of those areas.[64]
46. To a certain extent we agree with the Financial
Secretary: the Treasury can indeed point to already having
developed a number of policies which fall under Stern's three
main recommendations for government action. Indeed, in commissioning
and promoting the findings of the Stern Review around the world,
the Government is clearly playing a very important role in helping
to influence international opinion and rally support for concerted
and urgent action. But it must respond to Stern's conclusions
in its own domestic policies; the profound issue which remains
is the scale and urgency of its programme. The true test of its
policies is very simple: how fast the reduction in UK emissions
accelerates.
47. In this respect, we are very disappointed
by this Pre-Budget Report. This was the Treasury's first opportunity
to incorporate the findings of the Stern Review in a major policy
statement. It did not take it; we did not see any escalation of
the Treasury's climate change policies in this PBR.
48. A second individual point to focus on is Stern's
work on calculating a Social Cost of Carbon (SCC). As already
referred to, we and our predecessor Committee have previously
expressed our reservations regarding the use of an SCC in policy
appraisal decisionsi.e., to calculate the costs of the
extra carbon emissions which would result from a certain policy
if it were to be implemented, and thus help to inform decision-makers
as to whether it should go ahead or notnot least arguing
that such a figure cannot hope accurately to reflect the range
of possible impacts arising from certain rises in GHG concentrations.
Stern's discussion of SCCs is more complex than this, revolving
mainly around establishing an effective carbon price, through
taxation or emissions trading schemes, for a given emissions trajectory.[65]
However, what particularly interested us was that Stern recommends
a much higher SCC than that currently used by the Government.
49. The Government currently uses a figure of
£70 per tonne of carbon as its Social Cost of Carbon.[66]
The Stern Review suggests that the current SCC might be around
$85 per tonne of CO2 (in year 2000 prices). Elsewhere
the Review states the conversion rates it uses between: i) an
SCC in year 2000 US dollars and measured per tonne of CO2,
and ii) an SCC in year 2000 pounds sterling and measured per tonne
of carbon.[67] Friends
of the Earth brought this to our attention, using it to calculate
Stern's suggested SCC in the same terms as the figure currently
used by the Government: this produces the figure of £238
per tonne of carbon, or over three times the Government's SCC
value. Simon Bullock of Friends of the Earth expanded on the
implications of this to us:
Mr Bullock: Firstly, we do agree
with the Stern Report that there should be the higher cost of
carbon, both because the old figure is based on old analysis really,
a 2002 Treasury view of 2000 science; we have moved on seven years
so it is more up-to-date science which covers more impact and
uses a more ethically defensible discount rate, so treats future
generations more fairly. We strongly support what is effectively
a tripling of the Social Cost of Carbon. We think that is right,
although probably still is an under-estimate given that the science
gets stronger every year.
In policy terms, I think where it would have
the biggest effect is if it was reflected in the Government's
policy appraisal mechanisms. They currently use the £70 tonne
of carbon across Government and it affects lots and lots of different
things. In the last six months we have seen it heavily affect
the levels of recycling the Government is prepared to countenance
in its new waste strategy. If you triple the rate of the Social
Cost of Carbon that would mean, in the options you put across
and what recycling you go for, it would come out much higher than
incineration or other options. That is a practical example of
where it would be very different.
If it was applied to the Aviation White Paper,
again that would dramatically affect cost benefit calculations
the Government has there. Currently I think they use a figure
of aviation's climate costs of £2-4 billion. If you triple
that that then radically affects the net balance of net positives
or negatives for that expansion programme. It comes across in
lots of other ways as well. Building regulations is another recent
example. I think it was Yvette Cooper who considered standards
for building regulations being unnecessary gold plating. However,
if you use a higher figure for the Social Cost of Carbon then
they are absolutely justified.[68]
50. In discussing this point with us, the Financial
Secretary told us that the Government does not accept that Stern's
figure is applicable for Government decisions within the UK:
David Howarth: [
] It seems to me
the question for the Treasury and not just for each individual
department is whether the Stern figure will henceforth be incorporated
in policy evaluation across government because, if it is, it will
start to transform the policy choices of every department, not
just the ones that are obviously environmental.
John Healey: I suppose the short
answer to this is that Stern was trying to do an assessment of
the economics of climate change on a global basis so therefore
he was looking at elements and assumptions on a global basis,
including one that led him to take a view on calculating the social
cost of carbon on that basis which is not necessarily and is certainly
not directly applicable country-by-country. We are doing some
quite detailed technical work on this area within government.
It is obviously a complex and evolving science anyway. However,
at present the sort of assumptions and the purpose of the Stern
calculations, in our view do not directly translate to the UK
and do not lead us to the conclusion at this point that we need
to revise, for instance, the Green Book guidance, which is one
of the reference points for departments making the sort of calculations
to which you referred.
51. We find this argument hard to follow. After
all, the Government frequently makes the point that the global
warming impacts of a tonne of carbon do not differ depending on
where those emissions are made. The corollary of this should surely
be that the Social Cost of Carbon should be the same for any emissions,
no matter where they are made.
We made this point directly to the Financial Secretary:
David Howarth: But does the Secretary
of State for Environment, Food and Rural Affairs not make the
point constantly that a tonne of carbon somewhere else is the
same in its effects as a tonne of carbon here, so I cannot see
why it is the case that the British Government should adopt a
different social cost of carbon for its own activities from the
one that has been calculated to reflect the cost to the world
as a whole of emitting carbon?
John Healey: Because the modeling
that Stern used was global not UK in scope. It dealt with a range
of possible outcomes that may have been appropriate in other parts
of the world and not in the UK. It dealt with likelihoods of their
occurrence elsewhere and not in the UK, plus a number of other
assumptions which are not directly applicable to the UK, and it
is really for that reason that our preliminary conclusion is that
there is not that direct transferability of his global calculations
to what we should using in the UK. However, as I say, we are doing
some quite detailed internal technical work on that at the moment.[69]
We accept that Defra are currently reviewing the
UK's SCC, but we can see no convincing reason why the UK should
not adopt Stern's suggested SCC value for the current global emissions
trajectory. If the Government accepts the findings of the Stern
Review, it should surely accept its conclusions on the Social
Cost of Carbon.
52. Finally, but most importantly, the third implication
of the Stern Review which we focused on was the difference between
Stern's greenhouse gas targets for 2050 and the target used by
the Government. To be clear, Stern recommends a target range in
atmospheric concentrations of GHGs in 2050 of between 450 and
550ppm CO2 equivalent; which, in terms of CO2
alone equates in the main scenarios he uses to between around
400 and 490ppm CO2. (He also suggests the possibility
of a wider range of carbon dioxide concentrations, compatible
with his target range of 450-550ppm CO2e, of around
360-500ppm CO2.)[70]
The Government, meanwhile, has a target to reduce annual UK CO2
emissions by 60% from 1990 levels by 2050, with real progress
by 2020. This target was adapted from a recommendation made in
2000 by the Royal Commission on Environmental Pollution (RCEP),[71]
which was itself based on a target of stabilising global atmospheric
concentrations of carbon dioxide at 550ppm CO2 by 2050.
Clearly, then, the Government's 2050 target for reducing UK
CO2 emissions is out of step with the global targets
recommended by the Stern Review. Indeed, the global target limit
for atmospheric concentrations of CO2 which underlies
the UK's domestic target for 2050 is some 50-60ppm CO2,
or 10-12%, higher (that is, more lax) than Stern's upper
limit, the level of emissions which Stern makes clear would itself
be dangerous.
53. We put this point to the Financial Secretary,
who sent us a very interesting written answer:
Stabilisation goalsgreenhouse
gases compared to carbon dioxideinformation as provided
by Defra
The EU Council of Ministers has an objective
of limiting global average temperature increase to no more than
2ºC above pre-industrial levels, which it has associated
with limiting atmospheric greenhouse concentrations to well below
550ppm carbon dioxide equivalent (CO2e), necessitating
global emissions to peak and start to decline within 2 decades,
and global emission reductions of 15-50% by 2050. The UK
Government shares the EU's 2ºC objective. Officials are currently
exploring the linkages between this objective and a prospective
long-term stabilisation goal defined in terms of CO2e.
Carbon dioxide equivalent (CO2e) is
a measure of the total stock (or level) of all anthropogenic greenhouse
gases in the atmosphere. It represents the total warming effect
(or 'radiative forcing') of all greenhouse gases, expressed in
terms of an equivalent atmospheric concentration of carbon dioxide.
For example, the current concentration of carbon dioxide is 380ppm,
while the level of all greenhouse gases is equivalent to around
430ppm, i.e. other gases, mainly methane and nitrous oxide, have
a warming effect equivalent to 50ppm of carbon dioxide. A 550ppm
CO2e stabilisation goal, means a carbon dioxide concentration
of only around 450-500ppm.
The CO2e measure usually only includes the six Kyoto
gases: carbon dioxide, methane, nitrous oxide, SF6, HFCs and PFCs
(NB some definitions include other anthropogenic effects, such
as aerosols and CFCs).
A stabilisation goal defined in terms of CO2e
has the advantage of representing the full effect of anthropogenic
greenhouse gases on the atmosphere. It is a quantity that can
be linked directly to a probable temperature outcome and allows
flexibility to achieve least cost allocation of emissions reductions
between different gases.[72]
54. One point of interest in this response is the
information that: "Officials are currently exploring the
linkages between this objective and a prospective long-term stabilisation
goal defined in terms of CO2e." This suggests
that, whether agreed at an EU level or formulated by the UK alone,
the Government might at some point in the perhaps near future
adopt and promote a global stabilisation target for GHG concentrations.
This will presumablynot least because, as the response
says, the EU Council of Ministers has already indicated that this
stabilisation level should be "well below 550ppm carbon dioxide
equivalent" be lower than the underlying target behind
the Government's domestic target for 2050. Indeed, the Financial
Secretary intimated that the Government was already aware that
its 2050 carbon target might have to be made tougher:
John Healey: Our 2050 target is
for a 60 per cent cut in emissions, as you say. If we are looking,
as we believe, for global emissions by 2050 to be reduced by up
to 50 per cent, I think we have to accept following through the
logic of the position we are in [
] and then that really
implies for developed countries potential emissions reductions
of 60 per cent plus because in order to achieve what really ought
to be our global goal of a 50 per cent reduction then developed
countries are going to have to do more of the heavy lifting, so
I think we will need to consider this.[73]
55. This is of particular interest at this moment
because of the Government's plans to enshrine its current 2050
target in law, via the Climate Change Bill. The Government
has explained that even if its current domestic carbon reduction
target, included in the Climate Change Bill, becomes law, it may
still be altered and made tougher, should the science develop
and suggest the need for a lower limit to emissions. This is indeed
welcome. However, the science has already moved on since the UK's
domestic target for 2050 was first framed. The Government ought
to adopt a domestic target in line with Stern's target for global
greenhouse gases.
56. It is useful to go back to the original RCEP
report from which the Government's 2050 target was drawn. While
the report centrally suggested a global stabilisation target by
2050 of 550ppm CO2 and its associated target reduction
in annual UK CO2 emissions, it also offered other targets
for UK CO2 cuts, associated with other global stabilisation
targets, should policymakers decide a different global target
were needed. For a global 2050 target of 450ppm CO2
(roughly in the middle of Stern's 400-490ppm CO2 target
range), RCEP recommended that UK annual emissions ought to be
cut by 79% from 1997 levels by 2050.[74]
Putting this in the form in which the Government adopted RCEP's
550ppm target, this equates to around an 80% cut in UK annual
CO2 emissions from 1990 levels: a reduction from annual
emissions of 592.13MtCO2 in 1990 down to around 118.43MtCO2
in 2050.[75] To
illustrate what a difference this would make to the Government's
current domestic target, a 60% cut from 1990 levels would
result in annual emissions in 2050 of around 236.85MtCO2.
In other words, a new target for the UK, based on roughly the
mid-range of Stern's global targets, would mean that UK CO2
emissions in 2050 would have to be just half what they
would be under the Government's current target, the one that is
currently included in the Climate Change Bill (Figure 5).
We need hardly point out that the choice between such target values
must have the profoundest implications for the entire array of
public policy decisions, starting today.
57. This highlights the need for greater public
debate on what the UK's longer term emissions targets should be.
Even more, it highlights the need for much greater international
focus on a global target and a trajectory for getting there.
The Stern Review makes a powerful argument for an urgent new
international agreement on climate change, and for it to be framed
in terms of a target for the global stock of greenhouse gases
in the atmosphere in 2050; it is in these terms that Stern
has suggested his target range of 450-550ppm CO2e. A more specific
target within this range could be chosen by first deciding on
a level of temperature increase at which to seek to limit global
warming; then linking this, via the best scientific evidence on
the probability of certain temperature rises from different levels
of GHGs, to a definite target level of greenhouse gas concentrations.
Once such a global target were selected, it could be used to determine
the size of the national targets into which it was broken down.
The Government should work urgently to influence international
negotiations in this direction.
Figure 5 Implications of the Stern Review for
the UK's CO2 target for 2050
8