Select Committee on Environmental Audit Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 30-39)

MR SIMON BULLOCK AND MS SARAH-JAYNE CLIFTON

23 JANUARY 2007

  Q30 Chairman: Good morning and welcome. I guess you understand that your fellow colleague has been defeated by the transport system this morning. A warm welcome to the Committee. I think you probably know most of us from previous contacts. I wonder if you could start by giving a summary of your views about the Stern Report—its strengths and weaknesses as you see them.

  Mr Bullock: My name is Simon Bullock from Friends of the Earth and this is my colleague Sarah-Jayne Clifton who is a corporates campaigner. To our mind the Stern Report was a major turning point on carbon change. I think we would probably all agree that over the last five years or so the science has really hardened on climate change and things get stronger every year; but the major stumbling block and barrier to action has been this perception that tackling climate change would be bad for the economy; that is a very prevalent view—without a lot of evidence, I must argue. What the Stern Report does so very powerfully is turn that argument completely on its head and say that in fact it is far better for the economy if we act now rather than delay. To our mind, that is the central message from the Stern Report, that urgent, strong action is needed now. What would follow from that would be pretty much a new strategy on climate change from this Government. As we have seen over the last ten years, despite a lot of strong rhetoric, carbon emissions have not come down; and, despite a number of good measures, they are largely piecemeal and what we need is a strategy to drive carbon emissions down in a way that is good for the economy. Overall we strongly welcome the Stern Report, and we hope that it will lead to a major effect throughout Government. Would you like me to say what I think about the response to that so far?

  Q31  Chairman: Yes.

  Mr Bullock: Two things really. Firstly, it is very welcome that the Government is using the Stern Review at an international level to drive progress there, to get some of the more recalcitrant nations on board. I think that is a very positive step. I think a problem so far has been that Treasury ministers in particular have downplayed the potential for UK action. They are all arguing that unilateral action is where it is at; we do not need to do very much at the national level because, again, the argument comes across that it may damage UK competitiveness, and we should not really act alone. I think that is a misreading of the Stern Report. The Stern Report has two huge chapters, Chapters 11 and 12, which set out why action on climate change unilaterally is good for the economy, good for the UK's economy and how, if we do it properly, there are major economic benefits from innovation, new technologies and efficiencies throughout the economy. I think that is the message that the Government has missed—whether deliberately or not I do not know. Certainly the first response that the Government had to Stern in policy terms was the Pre-Budget Report and there was shockingly little in there about how to drive the UK to a low carbon economy. To our view that was exceptionally disappointing given the very strong statements that both Gordon Brown and Tony Blair gave at the launch of the Stern Review saying: this is the most important document to come out of Government in the last ten years; it is the greatest challenge we face; and it can be positive for the economy if we tackle this issue. Then to see so very little in the Budget was immensely disappointing.

  Q32  Chairman: That is very helpful. Stern's calculations produce a higher figure for the Social Cost of Carbon than the Government previously used hitherto. Could you illustrate what difference it would make to environmental taxes, spending and so on if that high Social Cost of Carbon was actually factored into the Government's own calculations?

  Mr Bullock: Firstly, we do agree with the Stern Report that there should be a higher social cost of carbon, both because the old figure is based on old analysis really, a 2002 Treasury view of 2000 science; we have moved on seven years so it is more up-to-date science which covers more impacts and uses a more ethically defensible discount rate, so treating future generations more fairly. We strongly support what is effectively a tripling of the Social Cost of Carbon. We think that is right, although probably still is an under-estimate given that the science gets stronger every year. In policy terms, I think where it would have the biggest effect is if it was reflected in the Government's policy appraisal mechanisms. They currently use the 70 pounds per tonne of carbon across Government and it affects lots and lots of different things. In the last six months we have seen it heavily affect the levels of recycling the Government is prepared to countenance in its new waste strategy. If you triple the rate of the Social Cost of Carbon that would mean, in the options you put across and what recycling you go for, it would come out much more favourable for recycling than incineration or other options. That is a practical example of where it would be very different. If it was applied to the Aviation White Paper, again that would dramatically affect cost benefit calculations the Government has there. Currently I think they use a figure of aviation's climate costs of £2-4 billion. If you triple that that then radically affects the net balance of net positives or negatives for that expansion programme. It comes across in lots of other ways as well. Building regulations is another recent example. I think it was Yvette Cooper who considered standards for building regulations being unnecessary gold plating. However, if you use a higher figure for the Social Cost of Carbon then they are absolutely justified. I do not think it is just an issue about green taxes; I think it runs right the way across Government. On green taxes themselves, I think what the figures do is show that taxes generally should be a lot higher if we are to stop climate change; but that the level of taxation should not be just to internalise the external cost; but it should be designed in policy packages across Government so that carbon emissions come down. That is the overall goal, to have a cap and stick to it. We hope the analysis behind the Social Cost of Carbon is that carbon damage is much greater than we had previously thought, and that is what should drive policy.

  Q33  Colin Challen: I am getting the impression that you feel the Treasury's economic strategy lacks coherence in its attempts to change people's behaviour and you have mentioned that taxes need to be a lot higher. Could you give a couple of concrete examples of where taxes and perhaps regulation should be stiffened up to change people's behaviour? Could you quantify the level of change you think that could bring about?

  Mr Bullock: Yes, I will give an aviation example to start with. The Government previously has ruled out increases in Air Passenger Duty; I think saying that, it was not really an environmental tax. However, in this Pre-Budget Report it has changed its focus and said it is well known that if you increase Air Passenger Duty it clearly would have an environmental effect, because it affects the level of growth you get in aviation emissions. It put up Air Passenger Duty, doubled it from five to ten for the cheapest flight; and, to our mind, it is a good thing they have recognised that Air Passenger Duty, in the absence of Fuel Duty and VAT on fuel, can have an effect on slowing the growth in aviation, but the level it put in place is just not sufficient. There is a report by the Environmental Change Unit, University of Oxford on aviation policy where they say that, if you wanted to slow the growth in aviation, not stop flying but slow the growth in aviation as predicted, the doubling or tripling, then you would need an Air Passenger Duty escalator every year going up by £10 or £15 a year depending on what type of ticket it is; obviously the higher rises for the longer haul flights. That is an example where the Government is saying, "Yes, it could have an effect", but it is not putting them in place in anything like the level needed to affect demand.

  Q34  Colin Challen: I think the real question is whether or not you have to raise the price of travel to such an extent that it actually puts people off. As we know, the cost of travel as a proportion of people's disposable income has gone down. Do you have any evidence that recent increases in fuel costs have deterred any motorists from making their usual number of journeys, because we have seen car travel, particularly, increasing year on year?

  Mr Bullock: Firstly, on the overall costs of different modes of travel, even though fuel price has gone up recently, it is still the long-run trend since 1970 that the costs of motoring have gone down whereas the costs of bus and rail have gone up. What we would like to see, we are not advocating heavily a tax on the motorist in any way. What we have got to do is have a system whereby gradually it becomes cheaper, easier and more convenient for people to use alternatives.

  Q35  Colin Challen: That will take a very long time. Why can you not just come along as a pressure group and say, "Right, fuel duty has to be doubled; £2 a litre is fairer than 86p a litre for the environment"; or is that too radical for you?

  Mr Bullock: Not at all but, firstly, I would say we are a sustainable development organisation. To our mind environmental and social objectives are equally important. Yes, we have to stop climate change but we cannot stop climate change in the way that desperately affects people who have no other option. It is currently the case that if you were to do something as immediate as you say, double fuel duty overnight, then what would happen to the people who rely upon the car to get them to work when there is no reasonable alternative to get there by any other means?

  Q36  Colin Challen: Ken Livingstone introduced the congestion charge overnight and saw a massive improvement in public transport almost overnight. That was a very quick change in emphasis.

  Mr Bullock: I think the congestion charge is a very strong example of how politicians with a clear idea of what we need to do can effect change much quicker than other politicians think is possible. What Ken Livingstone did was a great thing but London is a bit of a different example really, in that even before the congestion charge there were decent alternatives in most places; there is a decent bus service; there is a decent tube service. In lots of parts of the country, for example Manchester which does not have a decent bus service or a decent tram service, it would be much harder. What we would advocate is, yes, fuel. We certainly do advocate that fuel duty must go up; but we argue very strongly that it must go hand-in-hand with that money going directly to improving public transport; changes to the planning system so that people do not have to travel 20 miles to their work; making walking and cycling decent alternatives so people can feel, yes, they can let their children walk to school and not having to drive them. It is a mix of the two things. It is the same argument basically why we do not advocate at the moment increases in domestic energy prices; because although that would have an effect on climate change, it would have a desperate effect upon the millions of people who live in fuel poverty. That is why we argue that the first step should be a massive increase in the spending that Government puts into domestic energy programmes for energy efficiency and the like. We would argue that, for example, you could use the increased aviation taxation—they have just raised a billion pounds from Air Passenger Duty—and it would be far more politically palatable if the Government were to say, "We will invest that money into a major programme of energy efficiency grants for people across the country", particularly poor households, to have their homes decently insulated, with decent modern appliances, so they are not having to spend such a large proportion of their income on electricity.

  Q37  Colin Challen: How much needs to be spent, do you think, on creating a low carbon economy based on low carbon technologies? How quickly could you achieve that? What sorts of sums are required? Could you do it without making yourself electorally unpopular because surely these will mean greater costs on individual consumers?

  Mr Bullock: It is almost two or three orders of magnitude higher spending needed then current spending. You look at areas such as what the Government did in the Budget this year, the Pre-Budget Report on energy efficiency in the home—I think it put in place £7.5 million for better coordination of the Warm Front Programme; and, to our mind, what would be required is spending in the order of billions. There are 14 million people with a million households which have absolutely no basic energy efficiency measures. The Government should be putting in far greater sums of the order of £1-2 billion a year to provide grants, whether it is from council tax rebates or direct grants the details can be worked out and there are a number of different ways of doing it; but the issue is the scale of the change that is required. Rather than having little demonstration projects which, although they are worthy, they affect 5,000 or 10,000 homes, we need to be talking about millions of homes over the next three or four years. The Stern Report is correct and he is saying it is not just action some time in the future, it is action right now. You are right, there is potential for the green tax agenda to be politically unpopular; and that is why we think the spending agenda is such a critical part. It is very difficult for things to be politically acceptable if it is solely exhortation while, at the same time, the economic signals are all in the opposite direction. With bus and rail being more expensive, and planes and cars becoming cheaper then a political message where it days, "Don't use your car so much", is never going to be successful. That is why we would argue that the Treasury in particular needs to have an overall strategy; not just a green tax strategy but one that links tax and spending with regulation; so that it is cheaper and easier for people to go green. Currently if people who want to go green put a solar panel on their roof there are planning difficulties, it is expensive, there is low pay-back and they do not get the money when they export the electricity to the grid. There are all sorts of barriers to it which make it, frankly, a pain in the arse. If it was made cheaper and easier for people, and it is the Government who can do this, then that is what would drive the change we need to see so quickly.

  Q38  Joan Walley: There needs to be a radical agenda there. How do you get public acceptance of that?

  Mr Bullock: I think things have changed in the last five years. Five years ago on climate change people did not see it particularly as a big problem. It was something that would happen a long way away, or was not even very certain to happen. That has changed, that is one thing. Secondly, there was quite a bit of evidence polling that people would be prepared to countenance even things which directly affected them in a negative way if it could be seen that it would improve the environment in other ways. I cite as an example of that the MORI poll of last year which said that 60% of people would be prepared to take higher taxes on flights, and that rose to 73% if the money was then spent on improving the environment; that is largely an issue again of linking the tax and spend agenda together; but it does become very politically unpopular and difficult to sell it if green taxes are stigmatised as being stealth taxes. I can see entirely how people would think they are stealth taxes if, for example, Gordon Brown puts up Air Passenger Duty by £5, raises a billion pounds and there is nothing throughout the rest of his Budget on spending any money to improve the environment. It is seen as a stealth tax and it probably is a stealth tax; so the way you make it politically acceptable is by saying, "We will spend it on giving it back to you rather than keeping it for general Treasury spending".

  Q39  Joan Walley: Just going back to the Treasury and to Air Passenger Duty, why do you think the Treasury has changed its mind; why did the Chancellor change his mind on that? We have had a Financial Secretary before our Committee in the past saying that that was not really an option to increase it. Why do you think there has been a change of heart?

  Mr Bullock: Probably I think it is due to increasing political pressure on the Government to do something about climate change, and also the correct perception that aviation, compared with almost every other sector, does get away pretty scot-free with it tax exemption, and not being part of the Kyoto system as a whole. There was pressure from within the Government as well; the leaked letter from David Miliband to the Chancellor in October was saying basically, "Yes, the EU ETS system may be a good vehicle for bringing aviation emissions down in the long-term, but in the short-term we cannot let nothing happen on aviation in the next ten years, the next decade", the next five or six years I think he meant. There is an understanding that something needs to happen; but it was a bit of a strange decision because they did say that expressly we were going to use Air Passenger Duty as an environmental measure, but the level at which they brought it in was not sufficient to have anything like enough effect. If you look at the Aviation White Paper Review in December that was basically saying that even if you increase aviation alongside current policy initiatives, if you raise the cost of flying, it still will not do much to dent the increase in flying. To do that, as the Oxford University Report says, you do need to have high net raises in Air Passenger Duty. Maybe it is just a sign that they are hoping by showing they are doing something on aviation that that is better than nothing.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2007
Prepared 19 March 2007