Select Committee on Environmental Audit Written Evidence


Memorandum submitted by Carbon Offsets Ltd

  Carbon Offsets Ltd was set up in 2006 to help people reduce their climate change impact through:

    —  direct action to reduce their own emissions; and

    —  offsetting those that they are not able to avoid.

  Carbon Offsets Ltd supplies carbon offsets in an ethical, efficient and economic way.

  We are a young, dynamic, value-driven organisation, with an established record in: carbon offsets, environmental management, the aviation industry, commodity trading and business start-ups. Based in the UK close to London, we have wide international experience.

SUMMARY

    —  The emissions reduction/carbon offset market needs to be well controlled, but that does not mean one size fits all.

    —  Some emissions reduction projects are small, community based schemes with a high level of associated sustainable development benefits. Such schemes cannot realistically bear the cost and time delay of full CDM certification.

    —  The current two tier system (compliance- based and voluntary) should be maintained. However, agreed standards should be developed and the voluntary market should be subject to more regulation to ensure that its greater freedom is not abused.

    —  There is a risk of missing the opportunity to engage the public in climate change action by offering emissions reduction projects with which they can easily relate.

    —  Whatever process is used, additionality will be key—and problematical.

    —  Carbon Offsets Ltd would be happy to participate in a Working Group to develop appropriate standards.

1.  Background

  The basic argument for carbon offsetting/carbon emissions reduction projects is that the cost/price of bringing about a reduction in carbon emissions varies widely. The cost of reducing carbon emissions is lower for society as a whole if the emission reductions (eg in terms of energy efficiency improvements or the development of renewable energy) are carried out in areas where the emission reduction cost is relatively low, and then, through trading, offset against emissions for which the direct reduction might be, or be perceived to be, relatively high.

  Originally the market place was entirely voluntary—but small. This changed, however, with the development of the EU-ETS and decision that the Kyoto CDM and JI mechanism units (CERs and ERUs respectively) should be fungible with the EU-ETS unit, the EUA. The concept of offsetting was extended to the compliance market—not only to trading within the EU-ETS itself but also with Kyoto signatories from the developing world and economies in transition.

  This led initially to two parallel markets, the compliance market (with EUAs, ERUs, and EUAs) and the voluntary market with its Verified Emissions Reductions (VERs).

Some concerns have been expressed however as to the reliability of the VER market, including, in particular in relation to the quality of the projects supported (eg additionality and actual performance), the avoidance of double selling and the clarity of information in the market place. As a result, DEFRA has decided to promote the use of compliance based instruments to meet the needs of some, or all the voluntary (non-compliance) requirements.

2.  What is the role of the Voluntary market?

  Demand:

  Voluntary demand for carbon offsets arises when the concern regarding the climate change impact in a certain field is not being sufficiently satisfied by compliance based action. In this case either individuals, through their own concern for the environment, or businesses, driven by their own desire to be seen to be acting responsibly, will seek opportunities to offset their carbon emissions.

  There is a danger that such action can foster a sense of business as usual in terms of the level of emissions generated. Such offsetting always needs to be seen and promoted as part of a solution, alongside active steps to reduce emissions directly. At the same time, the offsetting activity can foster greater carbon emission awareness. On balance, this voluntary demand for carbon offsetting is desirable, providing a funding stream that can be deployed to reduce carbon emissions.

  Being voluntary, the demand is affected not only by price, but by other more subjective factors in terms of whether the project is "attractive".

  Supply:  The prime aim of the market is to supply carbon emission reduction projects that meet the additionality test, are quantifiable, have been measured and externally verified—and sold only once.

  Initially, until the CDM and JI processes were established, all projects were VERs. Since the emergence of the Kyoto processes, the majority of emissions reduction tonnage has shifted to the compliance market.

  The CDM project development and approval process has been developed with the aim of addressing the above objectives. This is the process that the world has accepted for Kyoto based projects—and it can be argued that such a process provides the most reliable assurance available that the project satisfies the necessary criteria. This process comes however at a cost—estimated at between 50 and 250 thousand dollars (Krolik, T. (2006) "The Argentine Carbon Fund Helps Developers Dance the Dance", The Ecosystem Marketplace, www.ecosystemmarketplace.com/ )

  There are two main sources of VERs, namely:

    1.  Small projects, for which the CDM process cannot be justified. Such projects are often community based, and bring with them wider sustainable development benefits. As such, they tend to prove more attractive to individuals who are voluntarily deciding to offset their emissions.

    2.  Projects/parts of projects that were originally intended for the CDM process. Such projects can give rise to VERs in a number of ways, eg:

    —  A methodology may not be approved, even though the project has serious merit.

    —  The country concerned may not have ratified Kyoto (eg Turkey).

    —  There could be "pre registration credits" eg if a scheme does not meet the Prompt Start deadline.

    —  A project developer may not be prepared to wait for the year or so to get the CDM approval.

  Whilst elements of category 2 above can be debated, the merits of category 1 are difficult to dispute. It is important to ensure that such projects can be encouraged and fostered. The Voluntary/VER market is one which should be encouraged—but it would benefit from standards and an appropriate framework within which to operate.

3.  What impact will the voluntary carbon offset market have on the compliance market if the former continues to grow as steadily as it has done over the last few years?

  The Voluntary Market has been growing steadily in recent years because a significant and growing proportion of society finds that Government (in the UK and elsewhere) has not taken sufficiently robust and timely action to address climate change.

  To date the bulk of the offsetting by individuals (and to a lesser extent companies) has been in relation to aviation. It has recently been decided to bring aviation within the EU ETS from 2011. This will help to reduce the pressure for voluntary action—but only so long as a hard line is taken by European Governments in reducing the cap. If that hard line is taken, then voluntary action in relation to aviation is likely to reduce, whilst voluntary action in relation to some other sources of carbon emissions is likely to increase if there are people who are dissatisfied with the rate of Government action in relation to those sources.

4.  Ought there to be a compulsory UK or European accreditation scheme for carbon offset projects or companies? If so, how should this operate?

  One approach to providing assurance regarding good projects that are too small to support the CDM/JI certification process is to adopt an accreditation scheme at the level of the vendor company, rather than the project. Standards need to be established for projects—but in a way that caters for small projects. For such projects, the customer can be assured partly through the application of those standards, but also through the knowledge that the carbon offset provider is a member of the accredited scheme.

  The objective, we believe, should be to achieve the greatest environmental benefit at least cost. The imposition of costly process on small projects will inevitably make them less attractive to consumers. This could affect the level of public support for offsetting and would consequently reduce the impact of such projects in other relevant areas of sustainable development.

5.  Whether there is enough clarity within the offset market to allow customers to make informed choices based upon robust information about different schemes at different prices?

  The use of a price per tonne of carbon emissions reduction is widely used—but is not ubiquitous. The use of such a measure could be part of the regulation of carbon offset providers. If there are other sustainable development benefits associated with a project, then these can be clearly listed, justifying a higher price in the eyes of some customers.

6.  Whether there is sufficient data available to guarantee accurate amounts of carbon or other GHG mitigation in the sorts of schemes which offset projects finance?

  The word guarantee is a legalistic view which tends to override materiality. Normal auditing techniques such as sampling should be permissible. The market would benefit from clear standards in relation to verification, though there are risks in delivery of carbon dioxide reductions even in the best CER projects.

  In conclusion, we believe that the government should not only act to regulate the market in CERs but it should protect the responsible market in VERs through appropriate steps such as a code of practice and kite mark.

  Carbon Offsets Ltd would be happy to participate in any Working Group established to develop such a code of practice and kite mark.

January 2007





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2007
Prepared 23 July 2007