Select Committee on Environmental Audit Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 1 - 19)

TUESDAY 20 FEBRUARY 2007

MS RUTH DAVIS, MR JOHN LANCHBERY, MR BRIAN SAMUEL AND MS BROOKE FLANAGAN


  Q1  Chairman: Good morning, welcome and thank you very much for coming in. Thank you for your written submissions as well. Can I start off on a general basis and ask you to say what you think is the role the voluntary offset market should play, and in the light of that whether you think it is something that should be actively promoted? I would like to hear both of you on this.

  Mr Samuel: From the Energy Saving Trust perspective my first point would be that what we actually require is for individuals to take action and save carbon rather than to rely on other methods to do so. So it is important for individual actions. That said, once people have taken those actions open to them there may be a role to play for offsetting those emissions that they cannot do by other means. So we believe that once action has been taken there is a potential role for offsetting.

  Ms Davis: If I can pick up on behalf of the RSPB, two or three things really. I think our major scepticism about the role that voluntary offsets play is the overall message that is associated with those going out to the consumers of those offsets, and with the best will in the world it is very hard to convey to people when they are buying an offset that they are not actually neutralising their impact on the global environment; they, I think, quite understandably, think that what they are doing is buying something which means that they are relieved from the responsibility of taking further action. And the science is telling us that we cannot have an either/or solution; we cannot have action somewhere else in the developing world and no action in the developed world—we have to have both. The voluntary market does not give that very, very important message to its customers.

  Q2  Chairman: Are you saying that it is actually harmful thing in that case?

  Ms Davis: In terms of its overall messaging, yes, I think it can be, and I think if you look at the way in which it is used by particular sectors in their conversations with their customers that will give you an indication of how it is harmful. So if you have an airline selling an offset alongside a flight I really do think that that is a proposition being put to those customers to say, "It is okay, you can carry on doing this and you can still rescue us from the current crisis."

  Q3  Chairman: If you have an airline passenger who is genuinely concerned about climate change and recognises that it will be at least five years before aviation is inside the EST in any kind of meaningful or effective way, is it not better that those people should be facilitated, the opportunity for those people to buy an offset rather than just do nothing? You are not going to stop people flying; in the real world we are going to go on flying. Parliament has just been to America to discuss climate change and we flew there. Is it not better to promote offsets in those circumstances?

  Ms Davis: I think it would be better to give people an opportunity to make a contribution to projects which will help manage climate change either here or abroad, but the messaging that goes with the concept of offsetting and the idea of carbon neutrality does specifically convey the idea that you can neutralise the environmental impacts of your activity by paying for somebody else to take responsibility for that.

  Mr Lanchbery: Could I just add a bit there? There are other actions you can take at home, as EST has just said. What people do not tend to do is think, "I really do need to fly to there so I ought to take some compensatory action in another sphere in which I operate at home," using the car less or something, and offsetting provides them with an excuse for not taking those compensatory actions elsewhere. That is our concern. If people wanted to buy a whole load of emission reduction credits of some sort from the vendors of these products, then, fine, it is just the way they use them to specifically offset particular activities that is troublesome. It is the concept of carbon neutrality: that in some way you can take action and then be excused for taking it. Because you do not reduce emissions overall what you use offsets for is to keep emissions the same—you do not actually use them to reduce anything. So we are very keen to encourage people to take action at home, which is ultimately the only solution. Your question obviously is a very good one; people will continue to fly, but if they do continue to fly then they should think what they can do somewhere else.

  Q4  Chairman: This is rather the WWF view, that if you are going to have offset it is at the bottom and there are other things you should be doing first.

  Mr Lanchbery: Yes.

  Q5  Colin Challen: In the light of that, can I ask whether either of your organisations have made a policy decision not to use offsets yourselves?

  Ms Davis: Yes.

  Mr Lanchbery: Yes.

  Mr Samuel: No. What we have tried to do is to try and end up with a zero carbon footprint for all our operations. At the moment we have not been able to achieve that and so, in the meantime, whilst we continue to try and work towards that goal of being a zero carbon organisation we are considering offsetting with one of the schemes that the government has recommended in its consultation. In the meantime we will still try to get down to zero carbon for our organisation.

  Ms Davis: We have decided that we do not want to go down the route of offsetting in order to be able to take the money that we would in offsetting and reinvest it in reducing our emissions at home. So we have a commitment to try to match our own target within the NGO community of a three% annual reduction per person per year within the business, and we expect to do that by absolute emission reductions and not through offsetting.

  Q6  Chairman: I fully understand your arguments but, notwithstanding, offsetting does seem to be a growing activity. Why do you think that is?

  Mr Lanchbery: There are two reasons. Firstly, there are people who are pretty green and feel that they ought to do something and they feel that offsetting in some way empowers them to do something. Then there is the business case where businesses, either through moral principles or just for publicity purposes, want to look good and will offset their emissions. So there are two main types. It is ironic, though, that in the case of personal offsetting the offsetting tends to be done very much by the green community—although it is growing it is growing really within a green community, which is interesting given the controversy around the subject. So there are two main thoughts—business and personl.

  Mr Samuel: If I could add to John's comments? We are also finding that within individual consumers there is also another category, those who are able to pay and therefore appear keen to buy their way out of their personal responsibility. That said, if there is a consumer demand then businesses will develop products for that consumer demand and with the focus on aviation emissions and the fact that there are not any aviation emission reduction policies, or major ones in place at the moment, therefore businesses will develop products—and we have seen that, there are now over 60 companies offering products in the market place for individuals and businesses. So I think there will be offsetting because people are demanding it.

  Q7  Mr Chaytor: If there are over 60 companies now offering offset schemes, how do you envisage that it will develop over the next five years, the next 10 years? Do you expect continuous growth? How do you see the voluntary market developing?

  Ms Flanagan: I think it will continue to grow at the moment. Over the last three years we have seen in the offsetting schemes a 60% growth per annum in those which are available, which is quite substantial, and it seems to be that that will continue on for some time. Whether it continues to grow beyond that will depend on whether there is some sort of accreditation scheme put in place.

  Mr Lanchbery: It looks as though it will continue to grow. Whether it will continue to grow indefinitely is another matter. As more Kyoto credits come on to the market I suspect that they will tend to be used anyway, whether or not there is an accreditation scheme, because they have more credibility in many ways. They are inadequate in some ways but at least they abide by a set of internationally agreed rules that are drawn up by the entire world and experts around the world, so people tend to prefer those, I think, given the choice. I am sure you will come on to this, but there is really no way of choosing between credits on the voluntary market; it is very difficult to get accurate information about precisely what carbon value and other co-benefits in terms of social development and biodiversity they might bring. So it is a terrible market. We have been looking at the market for ages now and we, frankly, would not be able to draw up a list of which ones were best. So it does need regulation.

  Ms Davis: I think there is also a question as to the growth in the market partly depends on credits being a lot cheaper than the activity they are offsetting. At the moment we are in a situation where it is possible to buy an offset for a price which is a tiny fraction of what Nicholas Stern believes to be the price of carbon, for example. In a regulated market with a cap on it you would expect at some point that that would change, and we would hope it would change. As that becomes the case more and more people would probably find themselves in a position where financially they may choose to forego the activity rather than buy the offset, but that really is contingent on actually having a market which reflects the value of its major product—it does not at the moment.

  Q8  Mr Chaytor: Just to pursue that point a moment. If both of your organisations feel that growth is inevitable, although not infinite, what is the likely pattern? John, you said that at the moment this is an activity entirely within the affluent green community. If Ruth's point is the case that sooner or later the cost of offsets will need to rise towards the government's view of the real cost of carbon then it is likely to stay within the green affluent community. The prospect of the voluntary offset market extending out to millions of ordinary people is constrained by the price of purchasing the offsets, which are going to increase.

  Mr Lanchbery: Probably, yes. The value of Certified Emission Reductions and the Clean Development Mechanism will almost certainly increase once the global trading market opens in 2008. It is difficult to see how they will not, and they will probably increase over that period as the end of the first Kyoto commitment period looms and states will need credits in order to come into compliance. So I suspect the price will go up, yes. The price is an interesting thing because the whole point of an offset in the voluntary market is to keep it as cheap as possible. A chap called Brendan Sewell, an ex civil servant and now an NGO, did a series of sums and worked out that if you paid the equivalent of the taxes on a motor car for a flight to Australia you would be paying about £750 to pay the equivalent taxes for going by road. So that is perhaps indicative of the sort of value that an offset to Australia ought to be, just about £700 to £800.

  Mr Samuel: I think I would agree with the fact that prices will increase if this scheme is robust. I think the problem is that if you have lots of entrants in a scheme where there are not any rules, then who knows what would happen? At the moment you have a massive divergence of prices—€3 to €30. You have a massive difference in the carbon calculations behind the whole offsetting process as well. So there is a lot of uncertainty. The risk is that you can have even worse products and projects than there are now on the market to try and keep the price as low as possible for others to participate. From our perspective what we would be keen to encourage is that with Defra planning to launch a carbon calculator, we would look to encourage every single household in the country to take advantage of that tool and then to implement the mechanisms required to reduce their own carbon footprint. Hopefully that may then drive them to look at what else they can do, and that may or may not include offsetting if it is a robust scheme.

  Q9  Mr Chaytor: The market is going to grow and therefore the regulation is crucial?

  Mr Samuel: Regulation is crucial.

  Ms Davis: I think also there is a very important point about the difference between a functioning cap and trade scheme, and what we have here, which is a voluntary market, is that there is no cap. The point about a cap and trade scheme is specifically that it sets an environmental limit on emissions and then you trade within that context. We all know that we are not there with the Kyoto Mechanism yet because we do not have the right level of participation, the right number of sectors, even the right cap operating, but the principle behind that is that we do have an environmental limit. No environmental limit exists in the voluntary market, and in essence that creates a situation where you are really not trading to reduce, which is the point that John was making. If we were to get into a situation, for example, where we did have personal carbon calculators, and perhaps a suggestion from government, if not a regulation from government—I cannot see us going down that route yet—of, say, a limit, a five tonne personal allowance for carbon, if we were to take the same approach that we have taken in, for example, the EST, then we should be saying to people, "You can only meet a small proportion of your carbon requirements through offsetting." In the EST we set a limit on the number of credits that can be used and traded from CDM mechanisms for precisely the reason that we know it is necessary to achieve reductions within the European Union, rather than simply trade across global power blocks. The same would need to apply to a personal carbon allowance for this to have any real environmental benefit. We have to remember all the time that the point of this market is to achieve benefits for the climate, and we will not get those without a cap.

  Chairman: Graham Stuart.

  Q10  Mr Stuart: There have been reports in the Press about projects not being truly additional, of double-counting, of leakage, and I wondered how serious and widespread you thought these problems were in the market, or is it just a small number of bad apples giving the rest a bad name?

  Ms Flanagan: I think without an accreditation regulation or regulatory scheme in place it is really hard to know. It is widely variable.

  Mr Lanchbery: We would agree with that but there have been some real horror stories. Some of the projects have actually been approved by—not the CDM—but the World Bank have run into big trouble, especially the big Plantar project, for example, in Brazil, about which many horror stories are told. So there are a lot of projects that have gone wrong; but, as you say, it is very difficult to quantify them because there is no regulation, so it is just what people can find out or happen to find out. The Defra project is way behind time, of course; it has not gone wrong, as such, but Defra are still flying around whilst not actually offsetting that much in their project in South Africa.

  Mr Samuel: One of my major concerns as well is how much of the financial contribution is actually going to go to projects, even the good ones. So the margins that have been extracted by the market by some of the suppliers of the offsetting projects are very high. So that is another concern.

  Q11  Mr Stuart: Before we move on to talk about validation I want to ask you about who is best to regulate the market, or indeed to provide the accreditation that is felt to be necessary, because you both agree that some form of accreditation should be mandatory. Could the industry, rather than the government, run such a mandatory scheme, perhaps with government support and with outside independent regulation and verification?

  Ms Flanagan: I think if you are looking for a consumer based programme it needs to be a very trusted, transparent and robust system that is put in place, and I think that needs to be run by an organisation that is seen to be trusted by consumers. I am not sure that necessarily they would see the industry self-regulating as meeting those requirements.

  Ms Davis: There is also an issue about the fact that many charities, environmental charities, development groups and others have seen the voluntary market as a means of attracting funding in a very difficult funding environment, which means that you have a plethora of different kinds of projects in the voluntary market. I think it would be very difficult to get those very different groups to agree to a single accreditation system; they would all fight for their specific projects, and we know this very clearly because within the conservation community there are many people who see this as a means of accessing funds and will argue for maintaining all kinds of land use projects in a context where many others might actually see those as not being appropriate or valid. So I think it might be very hard to achieve commonality.

  Mr Lanchbery: I think you do need an independent verifier. Like the EST has done that on renewables projects in the UK at one time, and did it very well. The CDM executive board does sort of fulfil that function—it is composed of experts appointed by governments but acting in their own capacity, scrutinising projects, and most of them are very good, very expert experts. It may be a bit clunky in the way it operates—it is rather cumbersome—but they are very expert and very independent. They are almost bound to be because of the diversity of countries and the different states of development that they come from. So they do give pretty unbiased judgments, even if people sometimes do not like them.

  Q12  Mr Stuart: Is it not possible though that as the market develops the market is going to suffer because of the bad Press stories we have already mentioned, and often markets do seem extremely diverse and unable to come to any common standards together, but actually market pressures themselves bring them together until you develop a stamp of approval, without which you do not really have market credibility. Is it not possible that that could develop, given time, rather than some central regulatory regime?

  Mr Samuel: I think it could possibly develop given time, but how long and what damage is done in the meantime and how long would it take to recover, I think it is far too risky an approach to let the market manage itself.

  Ms Davis: I do think as well in a context where you are not talking about firms necessarily adapting their existing business to meet regulatory standards, but changing fundamentally their whole business. So, for example, if we had a context where we said that actually the regulation suggests that forest projects in temperate regions are inappropriate, you have whole businesses whose entire offsetting practice is around temperate forests and they cannot adapt because they are doing something completely outside of what would then be the regulated market, which means that they will fight tooth and nail against that kind of regulatory proposition. I do not think they can be expected to self-regulate in that context.

  Q13  Mr Stuart: Again, market pressure might mean market knowledge develops and they are simply—

  Ms Davis: Wiped out.

  Q14  Mr Stuart: They either move to other areas or go out of business. What makes offsets different from "buy-a-goat" or "water-a-farm" projects undertaken by overseas aid and development charities that do not, at least for now, require accreditation? Is it just that you do not think the offset industry is to be trusted?

  Mr Lanchbery: It is probably the fact that they do purport to deliver a certain amount of carbon saving which has a specific value, and in the voluntary market they do not have a highly specific market value. But that is what is valued, and it has led, as Ruth implied just now, a lot of companies to set up offset marketing exercises for reasons other than climate because they see this as one way of getting money for environmental or developmental goods. So, a lot of the projects they run are actually very good in terms of biodiversity or social development—the wood burning stoves projects, for example, in India and Nepal that are Practical Action run. They are excellent projects but they are not primarily designed as carbon projects. Because they are designed for something else—many of the offsets, anyway—this tends to distort how they function. So you can have a perfectly good biodiversity project, say, from Conservation International, and they will have worked out the biodiversity aspect brilliantly, but not necessarily the carbon aspects. I think that is what makes it so difficult; there are lots of different types of projects that bring about social or environmental good in some way, and they are piggy-backing on the top of the carbon market, and for carbon markets you really want something different.

  Mr Samuel: I would perhaps turn the question around and liken the carbon market to perhaps a financial market. We have seen quite a lot of instances of mis-selling of financial products, even within the FSA framework, so I would turn it around and say it is more similar to a financials market.

  Q15  Colin Challen: Mis-selling is perhaps a good word for me to come in on because the CDM has been criticised by a number of our contributors to this inquiry on the grounds that it is inflexible, delivers projects which are very large-scale and, as we saw recently in a report about China, does not even necessarily deliver what we really want; it does not look at the social and other developmental aspects and so on. So would it be the best thing to lock ourselves into that kind of system which effectively locks out, as we have seen with the CDM, many African countries—only South Africa seems to be getting anything from the CDM. What are your views on that?

  Mr Lanchbery: The CDM market being part of the Kyoto cap and trade market again delivers carbon benefits and inevitably it was designed in that way: to deliver carbon benefits and absolutely nothing else. It is meant to deliver sustainable development benefits but in practice it does not—sustainability is assessed solely by the host country of the project because that is the only way to do it in an international regime. So you are right, it is a clunky mechanism, like many international mechanisms, and it is designed solely to deliver carbon benefit. So if you are an investor it has always been recognised that the CDM was likely to become the Chinese development mechanism because China is a big country, it has infrastructure, you are going to invest in it, or you are going to invest in India; but you are probably not going to invest in small countries. Also, the transaction costs are quite high, it costs $50,000 to $100,000 to go through the compliance procedures, so that tends to mitigate against small projects in developing countries. There was an attempt to fast track such projects, to have some sort of streamlining, but it fell by the wayside. Yes, it certainly has a large number of flaws, but it is hard to see how to get around that. There is a lot of biodiversity stuff written into the agreements on afforestation and reforestation but it is not binding—only the carbon bits are binding.

  Q16  Colin Challen: If you have VERs operating who can deal with the smaller projects and also take into account other social developmental aspects, provided that was properly regulated, surely that would fill that gap?

  Mr Lanchbery: That could be a valuable function, yes.

  Ms Davis: I think that is a very good point because the danger of regulating so that you limit the choice to Kyoto projects is that you do exclude things which are socially very important, you exclude poor countries and you exclude stuff which is very close to our hearts as a conservation organisation, which is managing impacts of deforestation. I am not sure, though, that in deciding because the CDM mechanism does not work in the way that we want it to that the right approach is then to decide that the responsibility for dealing with those issues and for providing that funding should fall to the voluntary market. I think we would probably take the view that over time we have to try to make carbon savings within the context of a cap and trade scheme. That means really doing everything we can to improve what is still a very new international process. We have never had a market in environmental goods before; we cannot really expect it to operate immediately in the most perfect way. But I would have said from our point of view that most of our time and investment will probably go into trying to do the best we can to improve both the CDM mechanism itself and also improve wider provisions around Kyoto and post-Kyoto to be able to take into account some of the things that are currently neglected through that process. That is in the end because we have to keep concentrating on the fact that the purpose of the carbon market is to allow us to cap carbon emissions, and we should bring everything we can within the context of that cap and not manage outside the cap scheme.

  Q17  Colin Challen: From that would the most important thing in your view be to remove doubts about VERs if they were somehow included in a robust cap and trade system, but still allowed themselves the flexibilities that the CDM does not offer?

  Ms Davis: I think that is one way of looking at it; I think that is an interesting question. What government is trying to do, very intelligently, is to make sure that what cap and trade schemes exist actually have a relationship with each other so that they sit within an overall framework. That is why the EST is essentially embedded inside the Kyoto process and why any trading schemes that we develop further down the chain should have that relationship. That may be quite problematic if you have a context in which you are trading with VERs in a situation where you also want to have a relationship with other trading schemes further up the system. The preference has to remain, difficult though it is, to try and create a context in which the international agreement under which we are operating allows flows of capital to developing countries to manage their emissions through whatever route, and recognises the value of standing forest, through whatever is an appropriate route. Relying on the voluntary market to do that is not, in the end, going to solve the problem; it is not a long-term solution to the problem.

  Q18  Colin Challen: Do the EST share those views?

  Mr Samuel: I fully agree with the fact that where we should end up is a cap and trade system. However, I am not convinced that a personal carbon allowance scheme of caps on individuals is going to happen very quickly. I would like to think that progress towards that goal would be taken. Therefore, I think there probably is a role for a mandatory regulated market for smaller projects that are more difficult to deliver under the CDM mechanism. And within that you could have product differentiation where you would have the products within the market, such as an African offset fund, you could have an Asian offset fund, a fuel poverty offset fund, technology transfer offset fund, for instance, which is more difficult to be achieved under CDM. The point is, though, that you do need to have regulations in order to make that happen. I do not know if those regulations can be developed to be sufficiently robust to guarantee and deliver sufficient carbon savings, but I think that it is something probably worthwhile exploring. Going back to my earlier point, if consumers demand offsetting then companies will develop schemes anyway.

  Q19  Colin Challen: Can I ask a broader question about the issue of equity because, as we have heard, Africa is generally excluded from the CDM so clearly the CDM, which is about trying to reduce carbon emissions, only focuses on those people who have the infrastructure to release carbon and, since most African countries do not, do you think that that should be an issue discussed in any form of the CDM?

  Mr Lanchbery: Yes. It has been discussed in the context of avoided deforestation that Ruth mentioned. There is a proposal from Papua New Guinea and Costa Rica to limit emissions from deforestation where they would take on what is known as sectoral commitment to limit their rate of deforestation, preferably to zero, and they would gain credit from anything in excess of that. The trouble with that is that for countries in Africa, particularly the Congo Basin people, they are not actually deforesting much at the moment and so they cannot really deforest any less, and yet they need the funding to preserve their forests and prevent emissions from deforestation. You have another problem, in addition, which is basically a capacity problem. We had quite a good meeting with the Congo Basin Group—which is the Congo, Cameroon and neighbouring countries—and they pointed out that what they really need at the moment is some sort of capacity building programme that would enable them to take on this sort of commitment and do projects on avoided deforestation, and I know it is a very common difficulty in Africa. South Africa can do these projects but in many other countries it is probable initially, that some sort of form of overseas aid is needed from DFID to enable people to development such projects.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2007
Prepared 23 July 2007