Select Committee on Environmental Audit Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 267 - 279)

TUESDAY 13 MARCH 2007

MR MARK KENBER

  Q267  Chairman: Good morning. Welcome to the Committee. Thank you very much for coming in. You and I have already discussed some of these issues but you are now able to discuss it with the Committee as a whole. Could I kick off on a general point: the Voluntary Carbon Standard which you are promoting is one of several emerging standards in the voluntary offset market. What is going to happen? Is there room for more than one standard? Is one going to emerge, as the Co-Operative Group suggest, that will be the cream?

  Mr Kenber: I would start by saying I am not absolutely convinced there are lots and lots of standards emerging in the voluntary carbon market though it is often suggested. I know of one that already exists, which is the Gold Standard which has been applied to the voluntary carbon market and the work we are doing on the Voluntary Carbon Standard. Then there are some proprietary standards that certain offset providers or certain schemes have, but they have no ambition to go beyond the remit or the scope of their own schemes. Then there are standards which are being developed in certain sub-national regulatory schemes, for example, in California or in the north eastern states of the United States. But I do not see a plethora of Voluntary Carbon Standards. Turning to the question, I think there is probably scope for more than one but what we are trying to do with the Voluntary Carbon Standard is have the base standard, and when I say more than one, I want to explain why. The basic standard, the Voluntary Carbon Standard, tries to say it is what it says on the tin. This is a certificate that represents 1 tonne of CO2 equivalent reduction and that is what you are getting. It is real, it has been measured, it has been independently verified, it is additional and it is permanent. It does not say anything about the sustainable development benefits, the social attributes, the environmental attributes; it is just a guarantee that what you are paying for, if you are buying a tonne of carbon dioxide reduction, that is what you are getting. That is where the other standards may be useful. For example, the Gold Standard focuses specifically on renewable energy and end-use energy efficiency, the idea being that is one area that people would like to channel investment into. There are others who are looking at the forestry attributes. Having spoken to the Gold Standard and also to the people working with the Climate, Community & Biodiversity Alliance, who are developing standards for forestry projects[2], their aim is very much to have players theirs as Voluntary Carbon Standard Plus. I think you will find that not only in standards across the board but companies themselves, buyers themselves, have their own requirements. One company may say, "We want to use the Voluntary Carbon Standard but only credits from Latin America or only credits from poverty alleviation projects in Africa" or whatever it may be. People will have extra standards that they will put on top but I do not think there are going to be many that try and do the same thing, which is to say it is what it says on the tin.


  Q268  Chairman: Do you think people are nevertheless rather confused by all this? The voluntary offset market is itself pretty confusing, even to people who try and take an intelligent interest in it. Do you think that people who purchase an offset which meets the Voluntary Carbon Standard are clear that they have something distinctive and they understand what it is?

  Mr Kenber: On a business to business level, absolutely. I think it is worth distinguishing that what we are trying to do is probably aimed more at the business to business market, the wholesale level. Were we to talk about going back to the question about other standards, I think there is some need for both education and protection of retail customers, you and I as individuals buying, because we do not know much about offsetting, or the average member of the public does not know much about offsetting and probably does not know how it fits into climate mitigation and emissions reductions more generally, and some sense of guarantee that they are getting what they are paying for. We would hope that the Voluntary Carbon Standard would be part of that in saying "This certificate represents a tonne of emission reduction" but, rather like the code of conduct that has been developed here and a standard that has been developed by an organisation in the United States, which does not look at the offset per se but if you go to a retail provider and you want to buy a tonne of emission reduction from wind farm X in India, you are actually getting a tonne from that wind farm and not from another project somewhere else because there are not enough left, a guarantee that they are being retired when they have been used, consumer protection rather than looking at the offset quality per se. There is certainly a need for education, there is probably a need for some sort of protection at the retail end, but I think the offset quality itself is being dealt with quite adequately in the regulatory market by the CDM rules and, with luck, in the voluntary market by the Voluntary Carbon Standard.

  Q269  Chairman: If offsetting became mandatory for flying, for example, the need for a voluntary code would be eliminated, would it, or would it still be desirable?

  Mr Kenber: If offsetting was mandatory for everything across the board, which I think is very unlikely, then yes. I often say, with the Voluntary Carbon Standard, if regulation and international negotiation is successful and we end up having a much more comprehensive legislative framework, then the need for the voluntary carbon market will be diminished. I would be surprised if it disappears altogether. It is unlikely we are going to regulate every sector and every facet of the economy and there will still be people who want to go beyond regulation, but at the moment, in a way, it fills a gap in regulation.

  Q270  Colin Challen: You did not comment directly in your memorandum on the Government's proposals. What do you think of them?

  Mr Kenber: I think it starts from a useful premise that there is a lot of confusion, as we were discussing before, in the market about what people are buying and how it fits into general emissions reduction and climate strategies. There are a number of questions about it that I would have. I am not sure why the Government has decided that it needs to intervene in this. It is a voluntary code of conduct. If it is a voluntary code of conduct in an environmental or social space, there are plenty of very functional examples of where industry and the non-government movement have worked together to develop standards, for example, the Forest Stewardship Council, the Marine Stewardship Council, organic certification, Fair Trade and so on and so forth, without the need of direct government intervention. If government feels that that sort of approach is not sufficient, then regulate. You can only have it one way or the other. I think there are enough non-governmental actors both from the private sector and the non-profit sector who know about this, who have worked on this for a long time, to be able to develop a code of conduct if such a thing is necessary. Secondly, I am not convinced about the way that the consultation process has been carried out. I think there is a lot of confusion. To give you an example, some of the work The Climate Group does is with banks, helping them develop their climate strategies going forward. One bank we were working with three weeks ago said, "We are going to buy our offsets to go carbon neutral from this company because it has government approval." We said, "Government approval of what?" "It was mentioned in the press release on the consultation," and of course, the Government would say "We have not approved anybody because it is still out for consultation." There is clearly confusion being sown in people's minds about who has been approved and who has not been approved. I think it would have made sense to have some pre-consultation with all those who are working in this space already, because it seems some of the consultation reflects some understanding of some of the issues but not all of them. I think it has been handled in a fairly heavy-handed way. I think it was acknowledged that the consultation this Committee was carrying out was going on in parallel and that seems to have been fairly poorly thought through as well. In terms of the standard itself, I think it is a fairly heavy-handed way of dealing with the problem of offset quality. Some of the up-front reasons for having a code that covers offset quality itself was because there are a lot of cheap tonnes that are available which are undermining the environmental quality but restricting it to the CDM and Joint Implementation, for example, does not solve that problem. There are plenty of industrial gas problems in the CDM and Joint Implementation. We could argue whether that is a good or a bad thing but if one of the objectives is to not have the public buying credits from industrial gas projects, doing it with the CDM does not solve that problem; all it does is make it more expensive for everybody, because the public who want to voluntarily offset are competing with businesses who are capped under the Emissions Trading Scheme or countries that have Kyoto caps. It seems a blunt instrument for one, assuring the public of the quality and two, of channelling investments into new projects while just artificially raising the price. As mentioned in our submission, our main concern, apart from the process, which we felt, as I say, was poorly handled, was the artificial restriction of credits to only credits from the CDM, EU trading system and Joint Implementation.

  Q271  Colin Challen: In that respect, do you think they are just being a bit heavy-handed and perhaps lacking in imagination because they do not understand the voluntary market so they say "Well, we have got the CDM style and that approach to doing things so we will just lob you all in there and have done with it"?

  Mr Kenber: I think that is correct. If government is going to offset its own emissions, then I think it is perfectly reasonable for it to do it using the Clean Development Mechanism as it is a signatory of the Kyoto Protocol as a national government and there is no reason why it should not do that. In the voluntary market, as Mr Yeo was suggesting at the beginning, the Government believes there are lots of standards and therefore has said, "We are not going to look at all of the standards. It is too much time, too much like hard work. We do not know enough about it. They are emerging all the time"—that is what Defra has said which, as I say, I disagree with—"and therefore it is easier to go for something we know." What is true is that the CDM at the moment in particular does have an approval system, it has independent verification and it has a registry associated with it, so it has some advantages over other global systems, hence the reason why we are developing the Voluntary Carbon Standard, which will have independent verification by accredited verifiers, both CDM verifiers and others accredited under ISO standards. It will have a single registry where you will be able to track credits to make sure there is not double counting and so on and so forth. It was interesting that, given that this has been in the public domain, or early versions of the Voluntary Carbon Standard have been in the public domain for over a year now and that the Carbon Trust[3] in its own report on offsetting carbon dioxide, said, "Here are five principles for what an offsetting standard should look like and here are two or three standards that meet them, including the Voluntary Carbon Standard," they seem to have ignored that bit of advice from their own subsidiary, so to speak. What they have missed by ruling out the voluntary market is a number of benefits that other projects outside the CDM can have. One is scope for innovation, which I think is very important. One of the reasons there has been a lot of support for the Voluntary Carbon Standard is that people recognize that changing the rules of the CDM, perhaps rightly, is a slow process. There are lots of different countries that have to be involved in the decision-making process. It is not easy but there are lots of projects and new technologies are being developed, new approaches, that need trying out, may subsequently become part of the CDM, perhaps post 2012, and the voluntary market, provided it is within a robust framework, is a good place to innovate and try those out, both in terms of project types and methodologies but also the procedures, asking questions like: where is it possible to maintain environmental integrity while cutting costs or streamlining the timing involved? That is one reason to put some faith in the voluntary market, provided it is well managed, and that is what we hope to achieve. There are project types, as I have just mentioned, that do not go into the CDM. I am sure you have heard from other people and other submissions that, for example, project types that would substitute fuel wood use or innovative community reforestation projects that would not make it through the CDM just because in political negotiations at the outset they were not included. Then there is a question of timing and cost. Putting a project through the CDM is time-consuming, upwards of 200 days to get initial approval. It is costly if you have to use one of the large verification companies and that rules out a lot of smaller projects that are worthy of carbon financing but would not get it through the CDM just because they cannot afford the time or the delay. There are project developers who are not interested—well, of course they are interested in higher prices for their carbon but more of a concern is having liquidity, having cash flow, generating projects, having them certified to a decent standard and then reinvesting in new projects, and that is difficult under the CDM given the time process. This is not meant to be a criticism per se of the CDM, because it is evident that it is working quite well and there are a billion tonnes or so worth of projects already in the CDM pipeline and that is anticipated to grow quickly but it is true that for a lot of projects that do not fit into it, it does not work, it is time-consuming and there is a whole lot of demand out there. I was at a conference in the United States last week which estimated that the voluntary carbon market just in the United States could reach somewhere between 150-300 million tonnes a year within three years, and that chimes with a report you may have seen by ICF Consulting that suggests it might get to somewhere between 400 million and 1 billion tonnes globally in three to four years. Who knows whether those estimates are right but that is a sizeable amount of money wanting to be invested in emissions reductions projects that will be choked to a certain extent if they were required to go through the CDM.


  Q272  Colin Challen: If you want to buy your offsets and you have a choice between the compliance model which has a government stamp of approval on it and something which is voluntarily regulated, as it were, are people going to say, "We'll have to go with the government approved scheme"? That is implicit, and what impact will that have on the voluntary market?

  Mr Kenber: One, it depends on the elasticity of the demand for offsets but immediately you are pushing up the price of an offset. Two tonnes of emissions reduction coming from the same project can be sold at very different prices. The price through the CDM market will be much higher largely because of the competition with companies that have to have compliance with the regulations under the Emissions Trading Scheme in Europe or other countries. That does not say anything about the quality of the offset; it is just how the demand is being driven in that market. I think there will be some who balk at paying up to four or five times as much for the same tonne of carbon and there will be project developers who will wait to see what happens in the post 2012 framework, in terms of whether there is going to be some certainty after they have been through the CDM system. It will not choke the market off altogether but I think it will reduce the size of the market and it will restrict to a certain extent the interplay between the US and Europe and other markets. There has been some suggestion that the reason for restricting it to the CDM is not to reward countries like the US for not having joined up to Kyoto, and therefore people can buy credits cheaper that are generated in the US and that would be unfair on those of us who have made some sort of sacrifice under Kyoto. I think there is a very small amount of merit in that argument. The situation now, in 2007, is that we are not going to change decisions made by the US Government six or seven years ago. Getting them involved in carbon markets—and there is a lot of appetite for it at the moment—is a way of demonstrating that the arguments about the costs of compliance and the costs of reducing emissions are largely spurious, at least in the short term, and therefore having a thriving voluntary carbon market is a way of moving policy forward rather than impeding it.

  Q273  Dr Turner: There are a lot of schemes out there now and clearly there comes an issue of accreditation, if not regulation, when you have so many, otherwise we will not know whether they are all actually giving us what they say on the tin, to quote you. You say in your submission that "an independent voluntary standard/accreditation scheme should be managed in a transparent manner by an independent organisation responsible for accreditation of verifiers and registries". Who do you suggest should do this?

  Mr Kenber: Under the process that we are developing in the Voluntary Carbon Standard, once the standard is finally launched, we hope in June this year, a new NGO foundation will be created with an independent board drawn from stakeholders from different sectors, which will have no material interest in the carbon market itself. Accreditation of verifiers will be carried out carried out under the new ISO 14065 standard which regulates the accreditation of verifiers of carbon reductions or emissions generally. Accreditation will have to be carried out by a member of the International Accreditation Forum or the UN, so that is a well-known and respected process for accreditation, and the oversight of the standard and its development and implementation will be carried out by this independent body. That is the model that we have chosen. I think there are different approaches you could take.

  Q274  Dr Turner: You say this would be an independent, new NGO set up specifically for the purpose, obviously altruistic but, however altruistic it is, it is still going to need some funding to operate. How is it going to be funded?

  Mr Kenber: We have funding proposals in two foundations. We have received foundation funding for the work we carried out to develop the Voluntary Carbon Standard so far and have proposals which we are very confident will provide the initial seed funding. Then there will be a levy per tonne of carbon dioxide reduction registered within the approved Voluntary Carbon Standard registry, which will provide ongoing running costs.

  Q275  Dr Turner: You can be quite sure, I hope, that the actual cost of accreditation is not going to add an undue amount to the overhead costs of running offsets?

  Mr Kenber: For accrediting the verifiers or certifiers, that is covered by the certifiers themselves. They are paying to be part of a scheme which, we assume, will generate some income for them, otherwise they would not get involved in the first place. The costs the Voluntary Carbon Standard organisation will have to bear are auditing the implementation of the standard, a sample of projects in each year, an annual review and providing an independent website where, separate from the registry, individuals and companies wanting to buy and sell country carbon units will be able to see what projects have been verified, what emission reductions, and the serial numbers associated with them. That will be another job. It is intended to be a fairly streamlined process. The experience of the CDM executive board is suggesting that, given the expertise there is now, which perhaps there was not when the CDM started, a lot of that work can be outsourced.

  Q276  Dr Turner: That is fine; if this works smoothly, we have a mechanism for regulating the actual doers of carbon offsets. What about the people who sell them, the independent operators who sell carbon offset schemes? Do you think they are going to need accreditation or regulation or do you think the existing legislation is sufficient? Is the Trade Descriptions Act, for instance, sufficient to monitor them or not?

  Mr Kenber: This is something I mentioned before. I think the Advertising Standards Authority has a remit to look at whether offers are being falsely advertised. Trading standards officers perhaps may not have the training to look at this quite rarefied market but trade protection overall has an important role to play. The protection of the customer is important in this space because it is such a rapidly growing market, because it is such a thing of the moment. That is where some of the ideas involved in the Defra code of conduct about looking at who is selling the offsets, the retailers themselves, and, as I mentioned before, the Center for Resource Solutions in the US, who have done a similar thing with green electricity retail sales in the US, are also developing a standard for the US but looking not at the offsets themselves. In this one in the US they say any emissions reductions that come from the Voluntary Carbon Standard, the Gold Standard or the CDM are fine; we will accept them as is, but some guarantees for the consumer that they are getting what they are paying for, given that many of the consumers will not even know what they are paying for in the first place, often will not understand the mechanics behind it, have been told that offsetting is a good thing to do as well as other strategies to reduce emissions but do not want to go into a detailed understanding, so some sort of consumer protection or consumer guidance, and it may not need to be a code of conduct per se, but guidance. There have been several publications in the last few months, a consumer guide to offsets and various others published around the world, which do have a checklist of "questions you should ask your provider", which you would do with any sort of financial services that you are being provided.

  Q277  Dr Turner: We have already identified one or two ways in which there can be pressure on overheads for carbon offsets. What is your view on the maximum proportion of money being paid for carbon offsets that should go towards overheads and how do you think it can be restricted?

  Mr Kenber: I am not sure I understand the premise of the question. Should they be restricted at all?

  Q278  Dr Turner: You could reach a point where 95% of the money that people pay goes into overheads and only 5% actually goes towards abating carbon if you are not careful.

  Mr Kenber: A company would only get away with that if they are selling poor-quality offsets that come at a very low price. There is that possibility. I think, looking at what people, what companies at least—there is not so much data on what individuals want to buy but companies are certainly not interested in just low quality—not low quality but basic quality carbon alone. They want to have a guarantee of the basic quality and then make their own decisions. For example, yesterday Barclays Bank announced that it had gone carbon neutral. It certainly did not buy the cheapest tonnes in the market. It bought a mixture of credits from the CDM, CERs, and voluntary emissions reductions and they were certainly above average market price because they wanted to both demonstrate for CSR reasons and also to gain experience in certain types of investments that there was a future in quality offsets. If you slap a 95% overhead on those sort of projects, you will price yourself out of the market quite quickly. The reason I asked the question back is that, apart from in the regulated electricity markets, which we do not have any more, I do not know systems whereby government says this is the maximum profit you are allowed to make.

  Q279  Mr Chaytor: You are now on version 2 of the VCS. What are the main differences between that and version 1?

  Mr Kenber: Let me be clear on this. Version 1 was a prototype standard which was both for consultation and for people to use and then feed back to us the pros and cons of how it had worked. Version 2 was purely a draft for consultation. It does not supersede version 1. Version 1 is still the prototype operating version but it drew some of the comments that we received from the first round of consultation last year. We are now working on version 3, which I hope will also be called version final, because we have been working on it for 18 months, and what we will see there is there will be some change in style, in that version 3—once the policy decisions on additionality, methodologies and so on and so forth have been made by the VCS Steering Committee, which meets on 28 March—will be drawn up by two expert standard setters (one from the Canadian Standards Association, one from Lloyd's Register, who will be formatting in a style that is consistent with the ISO standards), and reviewed by lawyers. ISO standards are designed to be policy neutral; you can apply them to any system, so we are developing the system requirements on the policy issues so they will be adapted to the ISO standard. So there will be a format difference. There will be some much clearer rules about how you deal with permanence with land use change and forestry. Whether they will be completed by June is open to question. There is quite a lot of discussion going on. Because it is a tricky issue both technically and politically, we need to make sure we get it right. The additionality tests have been refined.


2   Footnote inserted by witness 19.03.07: Our hope is that they will see their standards as Voluntary Carbon Standard Plus, ie use the VCS as the basis and then add other attributes as they see fit. Back

3   Footnote inserted by witness 19.03.07 part funded of course through Defra. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2007
Prepared 23 July 2007