Select Committee on Environmental Audit Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 105-119)

MR SIMON BULLOCK AND DR MICHAEL WARHURST

7 NOVEMBER 2006

  Q105 Mr Chaytor: Good morning. Welcome to the second half of our session devoted to you now. We are interested to hear what you have to say. Would either of you like to make a brief opening statement?

  Mr Bullock: We are happy to go straight to questions.

  Q106  Mr Chaytor: First of all, why do you feel that policy appraisal and RIAs can play such an important role in promoting sustainable development? Do you feel they are working effectively at present?

  Mr Bullock: I think the RIAs have potentially a very large role to play and the clear problem is that they are not embedded in the policy process. I think the BRE are right to say that IAs, as they will be in future, should be involved at a much earlier part in the policy process. We do welcome that. However, we have some major concerns with how RIAs as they currently exist are being implemented. The BRE's consultation is undoubtedly a big opportunity to deal with those concerns, but we feel at the moment it is a missed opportunity. As far as we can see the three broad areas where we think there are big problems with RIAs are made worse by the BRE's proposals. We are really quite concerned at the moment about how this process will evolve.

  Q107  Mr Chaytor: Do you go along completely with the criticism from the NAO or do you go further?

  Mr Bullock: I think the NAO is broadly absolutely right. We see there being three main problems with the process at the moment. The first is that it should cover the full range of impacts. The NAO is quite clear with the full environmental and social impacts particularly it does not do that. The second concern is that the assessment should be fair and balanced; and largely it does not do that. I think the Environmental Industries Commission will have said something about the failure to cover some of the economic benefits of policy. There are other things as well. We think there is a tendency towards inflating the cost estimates of regulation; a tendency to ignore the potential for innovation, for example; and the whole range of issues around how you value environmental impacts which does not get taken into account. The third thing which is pretty fundamental really is that the final reckoning, once you have all this information and it is full and fair, is how you make your decision about whether your policy goes ahead or not. We strongly feel that the cost benefit analysis approach that the Government takes, equating costs with benefits and if the benefits exceed costs then you go ahead, that leads to an underlining of the Government's sustainable development principles. We understand that the Better Regulation Executive want to simplify the process. We have no objection to wanting to make that process understandable and clearer for policymakers. However, with sustainable development you are dealing with what are inherently complex processes and inherently difficult issues between things you can quantify and things you cannot quantify. To attempt to simplify it by saying, "Only consider the quantifiable impact, the monetisable impact, and then tot them up and make a decision based on that", it seems to me a way of institutionalising a trade-off, that this Committee has said that sustainable development really must try and avoid.

  Q108  Mr Chaytor: Do you think the publication of the Stern Report is going to concentrate the minds of the regulators? Presumably you feel that the system of RIAs at present does not reflect the urgency in dealing with climate change particularly that Stern is pressing on this? Will Stern concentrate minds? How can your criticism be advanced by the publication of Stern?

  Mr Bullock: I think there are all sorts of excellent things in Stern. It is a real turning point in the politics of climate change, particularly its two big conclusions, that it is a colossal market failure which requires Government action, and that it is far better for the economy to act now rather than to delay, so turning round the previous economic argument. There are a couple of things that have been so far comparatively overlooked I think. Stern makes a very strong case for international action, which the Government has very rightly taken on board and it will be using Nairobi, and we welcome that. Stern also makes a really strong case for domestic action. It makes a strong case that if you delay then the transition costs are higher economically. It says very clearly that there is no macroeconomic threat to the economy from moving quicker. It says there are major opportunities where the new markets are cutting inefficiencies. So it is very strong for the economy. That narrative has not come out yet but I am sure it will over the months to come. Another really strong thing they do is that they make a clear case for regulation. It sets off and says you have got to deal with carbon price, and that is absolutely right; and you have got to help investment research and development deployment in new technologies. But Chapter 17 is a strong defence of why regulation is also needed and how it can be designed well. It is not saying that all regulation is good, and we would not argue that either; but just that you have to have good, well designed regulation. Finally, and this is relatively buried at the moment, the social cost of carbon. Government currently uses a figure of £70 per tonne of carbon, and the Stern Report is arguing that that figure should roughly triple. It is buried on page 287, and then again on page 302. It is not high up there. They are also clear that that figure is likely to be underestimated too, because they are not covering all the impacts. They have made clear there that some things you cannot value. How do you value 250,000 children dying in 2100—it is almost impossible to do that. The Stern figure for social cost of carbon, if that translates across government that will have a big effect on ensuring that we tackle climate change. Currently so many policies and strategies are dropped because the environmental costs are undervalued—the Aviation White Paper is a clear example of that.

  Q109  Mr Stuart: In memoranda we have received complaints that RIAs are primarily concerned with reducing the regulatory burden. Do you think that is right?

  Mr Bullock: I think there is certainly a feeling that "better regulation" is sometimes a code for "less regulation". You can see that in some of the wording of the document. They do talk about the purpose of assessment to make sure it is not an unnecessary burden, which is a very pejorative way of looking at it; the assessment should be to determine the best way of meeting the policy objective rather than just reducing the burden; and also saying that the case for doing nothing is often not sufficiently well made. We would argue that what Stern is saying is completely the opposite way round in fact for climate change—there is a much stronger case for more action rather than less. Yes, we are concerned that the process of trying to simplify regulatory assessment will lead to worse policy measures simply because of the fact that you are stripping out the complexity, which is so important in telling you what is a good decision.

  Dr Warhurst: To follow up on the question and the link into better regulation, the impression I have had in my work on chemicals and waste, is that the better regulation is interpreted currently as being about simplification for business. What it means is you take a large amount of time reviewing a piece of legislation, you use lots of civil servants' time, you consult people, you involve people and you produce something new. The important thing about that new thing is that it includes no improvement of any environmental objectives. Your aim is simplification. Most better regulation that we see is about simplification and not improving objectives.

  Q110  Mr Chaytor: Are you saying with all the legislative changes, regulatory changes, which have come about following the better regulation guidelines, there has not been a single improvement to the quality of environmental emissions?

  Dr Warhurst: No, I am not saying that as a general point. What I am saying is that the focus of the last few years of better regulation has been focussing on burdens—rather than saying what we actually want to do is we want to move forward in much stronger environmental objectives and make it simpler. I think there is a very interesting example of where that has happened. It is a very big policy, which is REACH, the EU chemicals policy, which I myself was working on for many years; and what happened with REACH was the acceptance that the current regulatory system penalised new chemicals; new chemicals had to have lots of safety information from very low tonnages, whereas chemicals produced before 1981 did not have to have that information. What REACH did was it was basically a deal between the two elements. What we will do is we will deregulate new chemicals by hugely increasing the tonnage threshold and then we will increase the regulation on existing chemicals. What that meant was, as environmental NGOs in the process, we basically accepted that trade-off. We accepted a deregulation in one area because that area was unfairly over-regulated compared with the bulk. That was because that whole proposal was about making a substantial step forward. I think what we see in fact, there is not the idea, we are trying to do more; Stern is saying we should do more so we will do more and at the same time we will simplify where possible.

  Q111  Mr Stuart: Do you think RIAs are truly helping in their making of policy; or do you share the NAO's view that too often they are used as a way of justifying policy decision already made?

  Dr Warhurst: In the example of the Government's England Waste Strategy, in February they came out with a consultation policy—the RIA Environmental Assessment—and what you saw was the RIA there was definitely being used to justify the policy. The RIA actually showed that if you want to have a higher rate of recycling you would actually achieve climate benefits using a range of social costs to carbon. Because the range of climate benefits were similar to the range of costs they said, "We're not doing this because the costs may outweigh the benefits". Their big problem, firstly, is it about whether they do or do not, rather than may, outweigh the benefits; secondly, the social cost of carbon is now substantially higher according to Stern. Suddenly that equation is a different answer. The answer is that we must do more recycling because the benefits outweigh the costs. Thirdly, an issue which I heard raised earlier—the tendency that is happening now is that you only look at carbon benefits and the Waste Strategy Review released in February is explicit, once you get into it, that the only environmental benefits they look at are to climate. They absolutely ignore any other benefits of, for example, recycling, composting or whatever. It is purely climate. They have said, "We're going to ignore the benefits and then we will say what we've got left may not be quite as much as the costs so we will ignore it". Whereas my feeling is that they came into it saying, "We don't want overdo our recycling target, they'll cost us money so let's just make sure that the RIA backs us up".

  Q112  Mr Stuart: How do you think RIAs can be changed, the system can be changed, so that the arm at the front end can help influence the making of policy rather than being just a justification afterwards?

  Dr Warhurst: Fortunately the waste model did include a model with higher recycling rates, which was a start. At least they said it would be more ambitious. At the moment there is another provisional RIA out on the Government's position within the EU negotiations on the Waste Framework Directive and that one is totally focussed on the administrative burden to business and Government. It does not bother to try and examine other scenarios. I think examining other scenarios is very important because then you actually say, "If we did do this what will happen?" You have to incorporate as many benefits as possible. If you are not incorporating benefits—if you are ignoring things—you need to make sure that gets all the way up into the summary. One of the worries when we look at the documentation in the consultation is that the tendency of the summary will be very much bare bones; anything that is not costed will drop out. Any caveats in the costs will drop out. We will end up with things like, "Does the policy comply with sustainable development principles? Yes/No. Summary." It is about looking at the whole area, and it is about being very humble about what you are not looking at. I think at the moment the idea of listing the things you are not doing, that you are not able to cost right upfront in the summary is rather a long way from the minds of most of us.

  Q113  Mr Stuart: As we were asking the last witnesses, a further criticism of RIAs is that they are an intellectual Whitehall exercise removed from the action on the ground. Do you think that is a real concern?

  Mr Bullock: Yes, I think it is. I think one of the difficulties with cost benefit analysis generally is that it does reduce what should be political complex decisions to technical bureaucratic ones. My own personal example of that is going through the Aviation White Paper to find out what were the big economic benefits for each of the runway expansions; and it took me literally months to work it out through the spreadsheets that in fact the large proportion of the economic benefits claimed for the runways are from future passengers who do not fly at the moment being able to fly in the future and valuing that worth at about £20 per flight extra to them which, totalled over millions of people over 30 years, comes up to huge sums of money. That is compared with actual real life climate impacts that affect people's lives. By reducing everything to one figure, and the costs exceed the benefits, that hides that complexity. It should be a very open political discussion. I think that is what we argued for. We do think that Impact Assessment is really crucial. But the idea that to simplify it by quantifying it, the front page is there recommending we just reduce it to a number. What is the number?

  Q114  Mr Stuart: Is there a danger the very nature of Impact Assessment certainly as they are currently constituted could be counterproductive? Inevitably this tension goes on and sustainable development always falls out; as we heard from the previous witnesses on visual amenity, and how they will move to monetise that.

  Mr Bullock: I think that is right. The real danger is that the process will lead to worse policy because, for laudable reasons, they are trying to make it simpler for policymakers; but by doing that it hides the important things. What we would argue for the ministerial sign-off, the chief economist's sign-off, should not be to say, "I'm satisfied that the benefits exceed the costs", but, "I am satisfied that this policy meets the Government's sustainable development principles". To do that you have that list, and there are not that many of them, of sustainable development principles and you assess against the economic criteria, the social criteria and environmental criteria whether that policy does it. That requires a mix of quantified and non-quantified and monetised and non-monetised information. Currently if we have this sort of summary sheet with just numbers on it, you have got to have the numbers but it is not the full story.

  Dr Warhurst: There is another important point. A lot of the most successful policies, and this is particularly true of European policies, have been based around setting quite long timelines, where in 15 years we will have done this. To actually work out costs of that, given the amount of innovation and market change that will happen, and the benefits of that, it is extremely difficult. One of my concerns has been the Impact Assessment push will actually start to remove that sort of policy, even though in fact those policies have been some of the most effective in really changing the market.

  Q115  Dr Turner: The National Audit Office reviewed a selection of our Regulatory Impact Assessments and found that few of them identified all the social and environmental impacts that they might have expected to come. What is your feeling about the range of RIAs in your experience? Do you think this is a fair criticism?

  Dr Warhurst: I think, yes, basically. In our experience, you rarely see most of the environmental and social benefits, the focus is always on the cost to businesses. Apparently it is the easiest thing to measure, even though in reality what you see as soon as you review previous Impact Assessments after implementation is that those costs are usually exaggerated. Just because they are apparently easy to calculate does not mean that they are correct, so you end up with a false certainty on one side and an ignored uncertainty on the other.

  Q116  Dr Turner: The National Audit Office clearly would agree with that because they felt they scoped it in such a way that it inhibits proper discussion of sustainable development aspects. I would anticipate that you agree with that view and I will take that as read. What would you like to see done to the system to ensure that fundamental sustainable policy objectives are properly addressed in Regulatory Impact Assessments?

  Mr Bullock: There are a number of things, and apologies for the repetition because I know I have said a couple of these already. The summary of information that is presented to policymakers has to include quantified and un-quantified information and monetised and non-monetised information and it has to have an assessment of the distribution of the impact, currently it does not have anything like enough, and also, as Michael said, which impacts are ignored, whether that is for uncertainty reasons or simply because the data is unlikely to be able to do it. That is only the coverage of the data, but then, again, the fundamental thing is how you use that data, and the assessment has to be against the sustainable development principles which should be underpinning all government policy. Just to have it based on cost-benefit institutionalises trade-off, in our view.

  Q117  Dr Turner: That clearly raises the difficulties of the assumptions that were put into the economic benefit calculations in any event. I think you will agree they are not terribly reliable as undertaken at present?

  Mr Bullock: Yes.

  Q118  Dr Turner: Do you think we can, in fact, use the regulatory assessment process as a tool in achieving the results that Stern is now demanding of us? For instance, if we turn the assessment on its head compared with present assessments and made the primary requirement to demonstrate that the policy led to carbon reduction, led to environmental cost-benefits as opposed to other cost-benefits, et cetera, do you think that is (a) a workable approach and (b) do you think the assessment system is the best way of delivering that?

  Mr Bullock: I think the assessment system is probably going to be the best place for it. It has a lot of faults at the moment which we are all talking about now about how to reflect that, but it probably will be the best place for it, especially as the government is clearly committed to making it a more important part of the policy process, so yes.

  Dr Warhurst: One of the interesting aspects of the debate is at what level do you do cost-effectiveness assessments and at what level do you do Impact Assessments, because I think there is this element that where you have made a policy decision you need to take a measure, then you may be better off doing cost-effectiveness of how you can most effectively achieve your objective. The message from Stern is not that we can value these things a bit higher and then trade them off against something else, it is that we have to do something. We do have to reduce our CO2, so that ultimately is what we have to do; it is not that we have to trade that off.

  Q119  Dr Turner: If our RIAs of the future are couched in such terms that it is obligatory for every new policy to make a contribution towards addressing climate change we might get somewhere?

  Mr Bullock: I am not sure about that. Climate change is certainly an incredibly pressing problem and we have to tackle it, but for the purpose of policy operation, again it comes back to the sustainable development principles. We would argue that if any policy has a major negative impact on any of the sustainable development principles then it should be sent back and changed so that it did not have that negative impact. With the environmental limits of the sustainable development principle, clearly one of the most important environmental limits is climate change. If a policy was coming into the Impact Assessment process saying, "This will have a major impact on climate change", like, for example, the aviation White Paper, then it should be sent back and say, "In its current form it does not do that and we have to change it". Yes, you are right, but I am not sure that there must be a page on climate change because I think there are other environmental impacts as well. The UN Millennium Ecosystem Assessment is very clearly that there are other really pressing biodiversity issues in environmental terms.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2007
Prepared 5 March 2007