Select Committee on Environmental Audit Minutes of Evidence


Memorandum submitted by EEF, the Manufacturers' Organisation

INTRODUCTION

  1.  EEF is the representative voice of manufacturing, engineering and technology-based businesses with a membership of 6,000 companies employing around 800,000 people. Comprising 11 regional EEF Associations, the Engineering Construction Industries Association (ECIA) and UK Steel, EEF is one of the leading providers of business services in employment relations and employment law, health, safety and environment, manufacturing performance, education, training and skills.

  2.  This note is a submission in response to the Environmental Audit Committee's call for evidence on the role and adequacy of emissions forecasting and cost-effectiveness analysis in climate change policy. The note has been structured around the ten questions posed.

1.  In light of the issues raised by the NAO briefing on emissions projections, is the Government's current approach to forecasting "fit for purpose"? If not, what steps should it take to ensure that future forecasts are robust?

  3.  EEF notes that a recent UN review gave the government's emissions forecasting methodology a largely positive assessment and welcomes the improvements made to the methodology in the 2006 Climate Change Programme Review. However, the NAO[1] rightly identifies a number of areas in which further improvements could be made.

  4.  The forthcoming Climate Change Bill aims to create a flexible long-term framework for climate change policy. The central element will be a long-range emissions reduction target for 2050. The government's approach to emissions forecasting will need to adjust to this longer time horizon and the greater level of uncertainty which will have to be dealt with as a consequence. The main changes that will need to be introduced are:

    —  more regular and frequent forecasting; and

    —  a broader range of modelling scenarios.

  Essentially, forecasting will need to move away from being a short-term tool used to assess a relatively narrow range of policies and more towards being a rolling long-range forecast which can be used to measure progress towards emission reduction targets over a time horizon spanning several decades rather than years.

2.  In developing its approach, how should the Government deal with the following issues:

    —  whether there can be a greater role for independent assurance;

    —  how the Government should respond to the unavoidable uncertainties in forecasting; and

    —  whether or not future domestic targets and forecasts should include international aviation and shipping?

  5.  EEF notes that the EAC has previously expressed an opinion that emissions forecasting should be undertaken by an independent "sustainable energy agency".[2] However, we are cautious about investing assurance of emissions forecasts with a single organisation. Doing so might imbue forecasts with an unrealistic sense of accuracy. Instead, "assurance" (ie validation of the assumptions and methodology used to generate forecasts) might be better achieved through consultation on forecasts with as wide a range of experts and stakeholders as possible.

  6.  Uncertainty is inherent in forecasting. Developing and reporting a wider range of scenarios, preferably with probabilities attached to each, would better reflect this uncertainty. A broader range of scenarios would be especially valuable in the case of future fuel prices—a key assumption in emissions forecasting. Fuel prices are notoriously unpredictable and what later transpired to be unwarranted optimism over fuel prices in the 2000 Review was largely responsible for the misleading forecasts that that exercise generated. A further measure available for addressing uncertainty is testing of the upper and lower bounds of fuel price scenarios with market data—(eg forward prices for fuels such as gas, electricity and crude).

  7.  Government should produce two sets of forecasts—one covering "domestic" emissions alone and one providing a more complete picture of emissions (ie including contributions from international aviation and shipping). Whilst current Kyoto targets and the longer-range targets anticipated in the Climate Change Bill are based on domestic emissions, there would be value in monitoring emissions from international shipping and aviation. Tracking all major sources of emissions would provide a more complete picture of the UK's contribution to climate change and build up a historic data set that would enable emissions from international aviation and shipping to be included in the EU ETS at a future date. Government has already decided that all emissions savings attributable to the UK's EU ETS NAPs will count towards domestic targets—whether or not they are achieved in this country.

3.  As projections against the 2020 and 2050 targets are less well developed than those for 2010 but are becoming increasingly important, what improvements are needed in their production and use?

  8.  Improvement in long-range emissions forecasting is essential because, over the longer-term, the potential for error in the assessment of costs and benefits becomes greater.

  9.  Uncertainty increases as forecasts become more long range. Assumptions must be made about how a host of complex economic (eg GDP growth), demographic (eg population growth) and technological variables (eg innovation rates) will develop over several decades. Such uncertainty is best addressed through more regular and frequent reporting (ie regular annual reports on emissions forecasts) and developing wider range of scenarios (see above).

  10.  However, just as emissions forecasting must be more flexible to cope with the uncertainties resulting from longer time horizons, so must emission reduction targets. Rigid targets can be counter-productive and lead policy-makers to introduce more costly policies than is necessary. For example, the 2006 Review's focus on the 2010 target may have resulted in it overlooking longer-term policies that might have delivered more cost-effective emissions reductions over time. Long-range forecasts can be used to validate distant targets (eg as forecasts become more robust they may start to suggest that targets are either set too high or too low).

  11.  A balance needs to be struck between focusing on targets which are so close that a policy response is not a practical option and those which are so distant as to be shrouded in significant uncertainty. Medium-term targets which are in keeping with the investment horizon and allow sufficient lead-time for policies to be introduced that can induce behavioural change are the most relevant.

4.  Given the uncertainties associated with the social cost of carbon, is it an appropriate basis for future policy appraisal? What should the Government's policy on its use now be, particularly in the significant increase in its value which Stern recommends?

  12.  The "Social Cost of Carbon" (SCC) is a value which aims to quantify the damage to society (eg to public health, the environment and the economy) caused by each tonne of carbon dioxide emitted. Therefore, an accurate and comprehensive SCC would provide a very valuable yardstick against which to assess the cost-benefit of climate change policy. However, the National Audit Office (NAO), the Stern Review and the academic literature on the subject all rightly emphasise the great uncertainty over to the value of the SCC. Research to narrow the range of estimates and improve understanding of the SSC should be a high priority. Until such time as there is broad consensus over the SCC, its role in policy appraisal should be limited.

  13.  The 2006 Review measured the cost-effectiveness of policy by assessing its "cost per tonne of carbon saved". Whilst a useful tool for comparing the relative cost-effectiveness of policies, it is far from a complete measure of the cost-benefit of a policy. As well as supplementing the assessment with a comparison of cost versus the expected emissions savings priced according to the best estimate of the SCC, the impact of climate change policy on the competitiveness of business is a crucial element of cost-benefit analysis.

5.  Has the Government's approach to evaluating cost-effectiveness in the context of the Climate Change Programme Review been too short-term in focussing on the 2010 target? Has this adversely affected the assessment of new policy ideas which might only be more cost-effective in the long-term?

  14.  Evaluation of climate change policy should not be restricted to the short-term and should be in keeping with any long-range targets set by government. In particular, assessment should include the potential scale and timing of policy. Given the long-term nature of government targets, the latter is especially important to ensure that policies are introduced at the most opportune and cost-effective moment. Longer-term policies may have little impact in the near-term, but prove cost-effective in the longer-run (ie when assessed over the full time horizon of government climate change policy). For example, phasing in energy efficiency policies over time may be both more cost-effective and more environmentally effective as technology develops over time expanding abatement opportunities and reducing abatement costs.

  15.  The 2006 Review assessed climate change policy on the basis of an average cost per unit of benefit (ie emissions reduction) over the life of individual policies. However, an aggregate measure such as this conceals the fact that costs may increase (eg as most efficient abatement opportunities are exploited) or decrease (eg as technology development expands abatement options) over time. EEF believes that government's approach to cost-effectiveness should attempt to capture this complexity because it could play a significant role in controlling the costs of climate change policy.

6.  The NAO briefing has also raised a number of other issues, including:

    —  the failure to explore sufficiently different scales of policy intervention;

    —  the balance between expanding existing measures and introducing new ones;

    —  the range of policy options considered and the criteria for appraising them; and

    —  the timing and scope of future cost-effectiveness evaluations.

In light of such concerns, how should Government improve its approach to the use of cost-effectiveness evaluation?

  16.  Government should assess the relative costs and benefits of different scales of policy intervention by subjecting policy scale to sensitivity analysis in the same way as other variables such as fuel prices. The recent impact assessment for the Energy Performance Commitment offers an example—the impact of different eligibility thresholds, which translates into different sized emission trading schemes, were assessed in terms of their costs and emissions reduction potential.

  17.  As with emissions forecasting, given the potential significance of the threat posed by climate change and the resources required to address that threat, the cost-effectiveness of climate change policies should be reviewed regularly and frequently—ideally this should be done on an annual basis. Analysis should cover both existing policies and new policies under consideration.

  18.  Cost-effective analysis of each policy, as far as possible, should be carried out according to the same methodology and by the same group policies to ensure consistency. However, EEF notes that fiscal measures were excluded from the 2006 Review and considered instead by HM Treasury. Furthermore, the NAO report noted that fiscal measures were not subject to the same "quality assurance" as other elements of the climate change policy package.

  19.  The 2006 Review decided to retain several policies that government analysis concluded were not cost effective (eg the Renewables Obligation (RO)). Where such policies are retained, any alternative, qualitative, measures (eg security of supply) used to justify then should be defined as clearly as possible and the assessment against them made publicly available. In fact, it could be argued that where the implied cost of carbon associated with a climate change policy significantly exceeds the working definition of the SCC employed by government (as in the case is the RO) then there is a strong case for reforming or replacing that policy to deliver emissions reductions more cost-effectively. Even if considerable uncertainty exists around the value of the SCC any policy purportedly designed, at least in part, to address climate change should be seriously scrutinised if its implied cost of carbon is in the uppermost range of SCC estimates.

  20.  Finally, the Better Regulation Commission (BRC), in its response to the Stern Review, proposed seven policy principles which the government should be mindful of when proposing, developing and assessing climate change policies. Three of which are particular pertinent from the perspective of value of cost-effectiveness.

  21.  First, policy should be tested against a carbon price benchmark. Even in the absence of an accurate SCC around which there is a broad consensus, the cost of climate change policy must still be consistently assessed against a carbon price the government believes represents value for money. Failure to do so runs the risk of imposing unnecessary costs.

  22.  Second, carbon pricing policies must be "efficient". Specifically, overregulation whereby by the same carbon emissions are, explicitly or implicitly, priced by two different policies. Arguably this is the case with the Climate Change Levy, directly, and the EU ETS, indirectly, which both price emissions associated with energy consumption.

  23.  Third, government should reform or discontinue climate change policies which transpire to be inefficient or ineffective. Climate change is a relatively new challenge and government must guard against inertia stemming from reliance on the revenue of an ineffectual policy or concern over the political consequences of discontinuing an ineffectual policy in an atmosphere in which mitigation of climate change is seen as urgent. The priority should always be implementation of the most cost-effective policy option.

7.  What additional reporting and monitoring arrangements are required to support the aim of a transparent framework for emissions reduction?

  24.  Government should publish the models (including assumptions) and, where not commercially sensitive, the data sets it uses to produce its emission forecasts. This would strengthen the assurance framework by allowing stakeholders to replicate the forecasts. It would also address the concern, highlighted by the NAO, that the DTI model was subject to "little detailed peer review".[3]

  25.  Regular reporting of emissions forecasts and on the cost-effectiveness of climate change policies should include a measure of the relative contributions of and impact on each sector of the economy (ie the trend in emissions from each sector and how the burden of climate change policy is spread across the economy is reported).

8.  What should be the roles and responsibilities of the Interdepartmental Analysts Group, the newly created Office for Climate Change, and the Proposed Carbon Committee? In particular, how should the carbon committee be constituted, and what should be its powers and remit?

  26.  There is limited information available in the public domain regarding the roles of the Interdepartmental Analysts Group (IAG) and the recently created Office for Climate Change (OCC) (ie the body established in September 2006 to coordinate climate change policy across government). However, an obvious principle is that overlap between the activities and responsibilities of these two cross-departmental bodies should be minimised. In fact, a clear case needs to be made for the continuing involvement of both in the assessment of climate change policy. For example, an alternative might be for the OCC to be endowed with sufficient analytical capability to review climate change policy without the need for involvement of the IAG.

  27.  The role of the Carbon Committee should be to provide independent advice to government on climate change policy, to provide independent scrutiny of progress towards emissions targets and to provide independent assessment of the cost-effectiveness of policies implemented and proposed to meet emissions targets. In this role, the Carbon Committee should be mindful of the climate change policy principles recommended by the BRC in its response to the Stern Review.

  28.  To ensure independence and effective decision-making, the constitution of the Carbon Committee should be based on relevant expertise rather than stakeholder representation. Its members must possess the scientific, economic, legal and technological expertise to assess climate change policy. Explicitly stakeholder-based membership could undermine the independence of the Carbon Committee. However, the membership must possess sufficient understanding of all sectors of the economy impacted by climate change policy.

9.  The Government wishes to "ensure that the [Carbon] Committee's advice is transparent, equitable and mindful of sectoral and competitiveness impacts, including the need for secure energy supplies at competitive prices". What use should the Carbon Committee make of cost-effectiveness analysis and what difficulties might it face in doing so?

  29.  Ensuring that the burden of climate change policy is as evenly spread across the economy as possible will be a key role for the Carbon Committee.

  30.  EEF is concerned to note that the "competitiveness" impact of climate change policy on industry is considered "non-quantifiable" in the IAG guidelines. At the very least, this seems at odds with the quantitative analysis of the impact of climate change policy as part of the Stern Review. Policies that result in higher energy prices or increase the cost of industrial emissions can significantly affect the profitability of manufacturers whose margins are already under pressure. EEF believes that the potential impact of ill-conceived climate change policy on industrial competitiveness is significant and that quantitative analysis in this area is essential. We would be happy to work with government or the Carbon Committee in developing an approach.

10.  What approach should the Government take towards setting short-term targets as a means of ensuring progress towards its long-term goal of a 60% reduction in carbon emissions?

  31.  If, as is anticipated under the forthcoming Climate Change Bill, long-range domestic emission targets are introduced through legislation, then flexible interim targets should be established to guide climate change policy and measure progress. Short-term targets should be flexible enough to accommodate unforeseen events (eg extreme weather patterns, rapid economic growth and technological breakthroughs) and their frequency should take account of investment cycles and be compatible with the timescales of international agreements (eg the five-year phases of the EU ETS or the 15-year time horizon of the Kyoto Protocol).

March 2007







1   National Audit Office, Emissions Projections in the 2006 Climate Change Programme Review, December 2006. Back

2   Environmental Audit Committee, Sixth Report of Session 2005-06, Keeping the Lights On: Nuclear, Renewables and Climate Change, HC 584. Back

3   National Audit Office, Emissions Projections in the 2006 Climate Change Programme Review, December 2006, p 5. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2007
Prepared 30 July 2007