Select Committee on Environmental Audit Minutes of Evidence


Memorandum submitted by the Energy Saving Trust

FORECASTING

1.  In the light of the issues raised by the NAO briefing on emissions projections, is the Government's current approach to forecasting "fit for purpose"? If not, what steps should it take to ensure that future forecasts are robust?

  The UK Government's approach to forecasting emissions has evolved largely from DTI's energy model, the primary purpose of which is to project energy supply and demand. From this, it is relatively straightforward to compute carbon emissions, and add in non-energy sources of greenhouse gases (GHGs) from other models. Over the last few years, there have been a large number of updates and refinements that will have helped improving modelling expertise as a result.

  However, given the importance of climate change as, to quote the Prime Minister, "...probably the greatest long-term challenge facing the human race", we suggest that Government should consider whether a "next generation" bespoke single model, with a primary focus on the vitally important task of forecasting future greenhouse gas emissions, is required. In this respect we note that the DTI energy model was not designed to undertake the long term forecasting that is required for GHGs. Any such model will need to interface closely with the existing historic emissions database led by Defra and required for IPCC reporting purposes.

2.  In developing its approach, how should the Government deal with the following issues

Whether There can be a Greater Role for Independent Assurance

  There is a clear need for greater independent assurance. The detailed workings of the model are known by a small handful of officials. We believe it would be an appropriate role for the Carbon Committee to make available the assumptions and calculation methodology, and to host periodic (eg annual) gatherings of renowned experts and other interested parties for expert scrutiny. In our view, we believe that the information should also be available on the internet, in a format that would allow a wide variety of interested parties to examine the forecasts, both for the whole economy and for specific sectors/end uses that may be of interest to them.

How the Government Should Respond to the Unavoidable Uncertainties in Forecasting

  It is recognised that forecasting is an imprecise discipline, and good practice dictates that a range of scenarios is produced. However, the tendency is to use a "central" estimate of the outcome—which is again understandable as it provides a single figure to work with. However, the recent track record in forecasts has shown they tend to err towards an optimistic outcome. Until such a time as modelling improves to the extent of providing more accurate forecasts of the future, we advocate that it would be prudent to take a more cautious view (ie a higher carbon forecast) as the basis for policy making. It is also important to distinguish between uncertainties external to the Government (eg world prices) and those under Government control eg taxes and regulations.

Whether or not Future Domestic Targets and Forecasts should include International Aviation and Shipping?

  Yes—unequivocally.

  Aviation in particular is an important, and rapidly growing, sector of emissions which contribute to global CO2 and other greenhouse gas emissions. It is particularly important to take full account of radiative forcing. However, we accept that reporting against the Kyoto Protocol targets requires aviation and shipping emissions to be excluded.

3.  As projections against the 2020 and 2050 targets are less well developed than those for 2010 but are becoming increasingly important, what improvements are needed in their production and use?

  As noted above, the existing DTI model was not designed with the kind of timeframes in mind that need to be considered for climate change purposes. This reinforces the argument of the need for a bespoke greenhouse gas projection model.

COST-EFFECTIVENESS ANALYSIS

4.  Given the uncertainties associated with the social cost of carbon, is it an appropriate basis for future policy appraisal? What should the Government's policy on its use now be, particularly in the significant increase in its value which Stern recommends?

  We believe that there is an urgent need for Government to reappraise the social cost of carbon (SCC), in the light of Stern, the latest IPCC report and other evidence. The current dual system (Stern/Government) is unhelpful as it results in uncertainty and provides an excuse for inaction.

  SCC reflects the externalities associated with the emission of greenhouse gas pollutants. As such, it sets a benchmark cost against which to consider emission abatement options. Put simply, policies that have negative cost effectiveness, but which are above the SCC, should be pursued, along with all policies with positive cost effectiveness.

  While there is inevitable uncertainty about the level of SCC, the prudent approach, noted earlier, dictates that the more pessimistic end of the range of SCCs should be used as the benchmark. This is because, as the Stern review points out, the SCC is only low if the worst outcomes of climate change are avoided, which will only be likely if there is concerted international action.

5.  Has the government's approach to evaluating cost-effectiveness in the context of the Climate Change Programme Review been too short-term in focussing on the 2010 target? Has this adversely affected the assessment of new policy ideas which might only be more cost-effective in the long-term?

  Yes.

  Although at the time the Review was announced, it was probably appropriate to focus on meeting the 2010 CO2 goal, as this was, and still is, a stated government objective. It is also worth noting that the Kyoto targets also imply a short-term approach. However, given the length of time taken to undertake the review, the growing recognition that the 2010 goal was unattainable, and the increasingly strong evidence base of the damage that climate change will cause, there is now an urgent need to establish a structured approach to policy appraisal, implementation, evaluation and review, with a view to meeting 2020, 2050 and all interim goals.

  Inevitably this resulted in a more short-term approach rather than the longer policy review that is ultimately required for instance it does not allow for the incorporation of new technologies. However, the Energy Review has provided indications that a longer-term approach is now being considered. Clearly long-term post Kyoto targets are also required.

6.  The NAO briefing has also raised a number of other issues, including: the failure to explore sufficiently different scales of policy intervention; the balance between expanding existing measures and introducing new ones; the range of policy options considered and the criteria for appraising them; and the timing and scope of future cost-effectiveness evaluations. In the light of such concerns, how should the Government improve its approach to the use of cost-effectiveness evaluation?

  The Interdepartmental Analysts Group (IAG) undertook what can only be described as a mammoth task in evaluating and appraising the range of existing and potential new policies. Inevitably, though, officials operated under existing constraints.

  To our knowledge, no additional resources of note were made available to undertake the additional work. As a result, most input was on the basis of existing or planned policies, for which, at least within individual departments, there was already a set of working assumptions, given existing budgetary and other constraints, about the size, scope and timing of policies, including whether they would be rolled out/extended. The mindset and resources of the group, while open to challenges and suggestions on policies, was therefore not one where vastly different scales of activity or of approach could readily be contemplated. This inevitably served as a major constraint on policy development.

  Specific mention must be made of fiscal options. As noted in the NAO report, these were not subject to the same level of scrutiny as other policies. The Energy Saving Trust firmly believes that the absence of discussion and challenge on fiscal measures was one of the most significant failings of the Climate Change Programme review process. Put simply, it is not possible to take a holistic UK-wide perspective of how to tackle the problem of climate change without due consideration of all potential fiscal measures, including taxation. This is clearly evident as the most efficient response to the known externalities of GHG pollution is to reflect this in the price of the commodity.

  Clearly, taxation alone cannot be relied upon to solve a problem on the scale of that posed by climate change. However, it can and should work in conjunction with other policy initiatives, including emissions trading and direct subsidy schemes. A shift towards a higher proportion of environmental tax, while at the same time reducing taxes elsewhere, will send the right signals throughout the economy as to the direction in which the UK needs focus its priorities.

  The consumer cost of a full "carbon tax", while significant, is not prohibitive. Assuming a SCC of £100/tC (within the range of both Stern and Government estimates) equates to 1.2p/kWh on the price of electricity and 0.5 p/kWh on the price of gas. Although measures will be required to mitigate social impact, these levels are within the range of increases that consumers have witnessed in response to changes in world energy prices within the last two years and which have begun to fall again. Of course, the resulting revenue raised can then be at least partially recycled into climate change mitigation policies.

  The benefit of setting this as a baseline "carbon price" is that it gives all players a clear signal and benchmark against which to plan long term. By incorporating the full SCC a cost/benefit analysis emerges which provides a fuller picture of the outcome of a particular policy. Alternative pricing signals, notably from emissions trading schemes, may be subject to high levels of volatility and reflect an abatement cost, not necessarily a social cost. In addition, at times like the present, the price can be artificially low reflecting the short-term economics of supply and demand, rather than any fundamental considerations.

ACCOUNTABILITY, TARGETS, AND REPORTING

7.  What additional reporting and monitoring arrangements are required to support the aim of a transparent framework for emissions reduction?

  As noted earlier, the Carbon Committee should be given a remit to report and publish monitoring results on a regular (say, annual) basis, for open and widespread public scrutiny. It is important to ensure a robust evaluation process of each implemented policy measure. Regular reviews based on actual observations from a variety of sources are needed to evaluate whether the policy is still effective. Such reviews should be transparent; and have input from all parties affected by the policy.

8.  What should be the roles and responsibilities of the Interdepartmental Analysts Group, the newly created Office of Climate Change, and the proposed Carbon Committee? In particular, how should the Carbon Committee be constituted, and what should be its powers and remit?

  The scale of the challenge, and the experience of the CCPR process, indicates that IAG, in its current form, is not the right vehicle going forward to provide the analytical evidence base to underpin Government's climate change objectives.

  In our view, the role of the Carbon Committee is that of a separate, dedicated body, independent of Government similar to the Bank of England's Monetary Policy Committee (MPC). It should be responsible for overseeing the analysis, reporting and forecasting on matters pertaining to meeting a series of carbon targets (see 10 below) and to help ensure Government remains on track with its climate change objectives. Consequently, Government should be obliged to formally respond to any recommendations that the Committee might make.

  The Office of Climate Change, which must be independent of any individual department or policy area, would then be a cross-departmental body supporting the work of the Committee by undertaking the policy analysis, appraisal and forecasting roles directly, and by interfacing with policy officials in each department, including HM Treasury and HMRC. The IAG could then be stood down.

  The Energy Saving Trust would welcome the opportunity of being represented on the Carbon Committee.

9.  The Government wishes to "ensure that the [Carbon] Committee's advice is transparent, equitable and mindful of sectoral and competitiveness impacts, including the need to secure energy supplies at competitive prices" [see Note 3] What use should the Carbon Committee make of cost-effectiveness analysis and what difficulties might it face in doing so?

  Robust cost effectiveness analysis should be the cornerstone of the Committee's analysis and evidence base in deciding on the mix of policies needed to meet the CO2 targets. Key to this is having good data. In this context, existing policies have a clear advantage over new ones—witness the CCPR process, where a number of policies were rejected either for timing reasons or because it was not possible to undertake a full appraisal. It is therefore essential that bold new policies are not disadvantaged by virtue of a simple lack of data. Likewise, reaching the key long term targets will require innovation so short term cost effectiveness is not the sole criterion.

10.  What approach should the Government take towards setting short-term targets as a means of ensuring progress towards its long-term goal of a 60% reduction in carbon emissions?

  The experience of the CCPR has shown that the focus on a particular timeframe (in this case 2010) results in a sub-optimal analysis of options, including rejection of policies that have minimal impact in the given timeframe. The Energy Saving Trust believes that a regular series of targets needs to be set from now to 2050 although we do not believe that annual targets are practical, due to changes in weather or economic activity. Conversely, targets over a five-year timeframe, or longer, are too infrequent to assess progress towards the 60% goal.

  The Energy Saving Trust therefore proposes a series of rolling five-year average targets. These would be set every year, from now to 2050, on the basis of an equal percentage reduction each year towards the 60% goal. So, while there would be a nominal target for each year between now and 2050, actual targets would be set for the end of each rolling five-year period. The target would be the average of the five nominal annual targets up to and including the given year. The annual percentage reduction required to achieve the 60% goal is 1.7%.

  This is illustrated in the table below. 2005 emission levels were 656 M tonnes of CO2 equivalent (MtCO2e),[1] while a 60% reduction from the 1990 baseline gives a 2050 target of 310 MtCO2e. The first full five-year target period would end in 2009, for which the five-year average target would be as shown in the middle column, ie 635 MtCO2. The target for 2010 would then be 624 MtCO2, and so on. The final column shows that greater absolute reductions in emissions are required in the earlier part of the period than later. We believe this percentage reduction approach is better than a straight line approach since the scope for absolute savings now is higher than it will be once emissions approach the target figure.

  Of course, detailed targets need to be informed by economic analysis of long-term options.


Straight-line
nominal annual
target emissions
Rolling five-year
average target
emissions
Actual
year-on-year
reduction
Year
MtCO2 equivalent
MtCO2 equivalent
MtCO2 equivalent

2005
656
2006
645
11
2007
635
11
2008
624
10
2009
614
635
10
2010
604
624
10
2011
594
614
10
2012
584
604
10
2013
574
594
10
2014
565
584
9
2015
556
574
9
2016
546
565
9
2017
537
556
9
2018
528
546
9
2019
520
537
9
2020
511
529
9
2021
503
520
8
2022
494
511
8
2023
486
503
8
2024
478
495
8
2025
470
486
8
2026
463
478
8
2027
455
470
8
2028
447
463
8
2029
440
455
7
2030
433
447
7
2031
426
440
7
2032
419
433
7
2033
412
426
7
2034
405
419
7
2035
398
412
7
2036
392
405
7
2037
385
398
6
2038
379
392
6
2039
372
385
6
2040
366
379
6
2041
360
373
6
2042
354
366
6
2043
348
360
6
2044
343
354
6
2045
337
349
6
2046
331
343
6
2047
326
337
5
2048
321
332
5
2049
315
326
5
2050
310
321
5

March 2007






1   http://www.defra.gov.uk/news/2007/070131a.htm Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2007
Prepared 30 July 2007