Select Committee on Environmental Audit Minutes of Evidence


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 120-129)

MR DAVID PORTER, MR JOHN MCELROY AND MR ANDY LIMBRICK

28 NOVEMBER 2006

  Q120  Colin Challen: The proportion to be auctioned in Phase 2 is 7%. Do you have any thoughts about Phase 3 and what proportion of allowances should be auctioned in that phase?

  Mr McElroy: I think that is an extremely difficult issue because, ultimately, I think we recognise that the whole point of emissions trading is to internalise the cost of carbon. That is what it is all about, if it is going to work. However, the simple fact of the matter is that Europe cannot act in isolation. There are significant issues in terms of international competition which are associated with auctioning, and I know that other witnesses will be much more able to speak about that than we are. Equally, there are issues regarding security and diversity of energy supplies. Those all have to be taken into account in deciding how you want to move to auctioning and the rate at which you want to move. I think it is important that we see some sort of consensus across Europe about the rate of that transition and that it is managed in a sensible way which has to recognise the competition and security of supply aspects.

  Q121  Chairman: I put it to you that it is an extremely simple issue as far as the electricity industry is concerned. The only way we are going to drive forward a sustainable power price and incentivise investment by the industry in lower carbon electricity generation is to move as quickly as possible to 100% auctions across the whole of Europe.

  Mr McElroy: I actually disagree with that for fundamental economic reasons. It is the scarcity of allowances which drives the market and which drives investment, not the method of allocation. The method of allocation is all about winners and losers. If you talk to economists they will tell you that it is through the cap on the scheme and making certain that we have an efficient and liquid market where all parties are engaged in that market that we will deliver those emission reductions at least cost. The method of allocation is second order in terms of the objectives of the Emissions Trading Scheme.

  Chairman: On the contrary, because 100% auctioning effectively puts a zero allocation and is rather a good way of driving the price forward. Anyway, Desmond?

  Q122  Dr Turner: You are concerned with the post-2012 period and you want a phase after that lasts at least 15 years—this presumably does not have to be a single phase; it could be stepping up as it goes along—because you are concerned that any plant that is already there is going to be running for 40 years, so you want a stable platform. What do you think needs to happen to ensure that the ETS mechanism incentivises investment in lower carbon infrastructure? Is it simply a question of drastically lowering the cap?

  Mr Porter: The cap has to come down, but the most important thing, apart from what level the cap is set at, is seeing what we are calling a trajectory that goes well into the future that all the participants can understand and believe in. The absence of that at the moment is quite serious for the industry. If you were to be contemplating building a new power station today in the UK, you would be looking at it—if it were something reasonably straightforward and you could get planning consent, which is a question for another select committee I think—beginning to produce electricity probably in 2010. At the moment as you sit down to make your investment plans, you have absolutely no idea whatsoever what your CO2 emissions allowances are going to be beyond 2012. Your investment timescale for your new power station, however, will run probably over a period of 15 years and you will be expecting it to have a life of a great deal more than that. Some of our stations still running today are 30 or 40 years old. This mismatch is a cause of quite a bit of uncertainty and increase in business risks at the moment. The Government recognises it and we have had discussions with them in the course of the Energy Review, but the problem is that this is a European scheme and to get an effective solution you have got to get the countries of the European Union around the table to agree on something and the pressure is on; they need to be doing that as quickly as possible.

  Q123  Dr Turner: You still seem to be thinking in the old CEGB mindset of chunks of power station and half a gigawatt here or a gigawatt there. If we are looking to a much more renewable future, it is not going to be like, is it, it is going to distributed maybe 50, 100 or 200, at most, in various places? It is a quite different mindset and a quite different approach, which is possibly quite desirable. Well, it is very desirable from the environmental point of view. What do you think the ETS can deliver to encourage that?

  Mr Porter: I do not think that the ETS at the moment has a very big influence on the type of power station, whether it is small or large. As the renewables sector in the UK grows, given certain regulatory conditions, we may well see large-scale renewables offshore and marine technologies so they may not all be small and widely distributed.

  Q124  Dr Turner: That is my point exactly. But how can you change the ETS to encourage that?

  Mr McElroy: I have to say that the design of the Emissions Trading Scheme is not about picking technologies; it is about providing an efficient market to drive investment. It will be other policy instruments which sit alongside the Emissions Trading Scheme which will influence whether particular technologies come to the market or not, as well as the fundamental issue of economics. I think our concern is that the EU ETS should not be used as a market for picking winners. It is supposed to drive emissions reductions at least cost.

  Q125  Mr Caton: Following on from Dr Turner's question, you mentioned the Energy Review and of course in that the Government describes the EU ETS as "the central element of the UK's emissions reductions policy framework". How well do you think the Government's strategy on climate change and its energy security strategy are working together and can the EU ETS deliver them both?

  Mr Porter: That is a good point and from our position we want the EU ETS to be the main driver. We want to stick with it. People have criticised it in its first two years, but we still see it as valuable and the instrument that we want the politicians to have faith in. The reasons for that are fairly simple. One is that it is about cap and trade and the cap actually ensures that you reduce your emissions, and the trade ensures that within that cap that you deliver it efficiently. We are in the very early stages of the scheme at the moment and if it can be extended long term and people have faith in it, it can be a major instrument of dealing with climate change in Europe. John, would you like to add anything?

  Mr McElroy: Absolutely in the sense that getting a long-term carbon price signal is fundamental to delivering both climate change policy and delivering energy policy but, equally, one of the concerns is that if there is a wider energy policy vacuum it may tend to narrow the range of technologies in the market, which could impact on security of supply. Sitting alongside EU ETS I think the whole area of research and development and demonstration of emerging technologies is just as important in terms of delivering the range of technologies that we might want to see participating in the Emissions Trading Scheme in the longer term. Generators at the moment are developing the options—there are clean coal options for carbon capture and storage being developed, there are marine options being developed, there are offshore wind options, a range of things are there—but, quite honestly, at the moment generators are saying, "We will take these options forward but we cannot take decisions about where we are going to go until we know what the policy framework decision is post-2012," but we are not sitting back and doing nothing.

  Q126  Tim Farron: Looking again at fuel switching, in your memo you say Phase 1 allowance prices do not provide sufficient incentive for generators to switch from coal to gas. What level would allowances need to be at to provide the necessary incentive?

  Mr Porter: That is a good question but, of course, it is not an easy one to answer because you have got three things to consider. You are looking at demand; you are looking at the fuel price; and you are looking at the carbon price, and the relationship between, for example, the price of gas and the price of coal is very significant. You could have circumstances where it might be necessary for the carbon price to be double anything that we have seen so far before anybody would switch, but in other circumstances there could be reasons for a generating company to switch, even if the price was perhaps zero euros per tonne. It is a difficult question to answer because of the dynamics.

  Mr McElroy: The simple fact is that in the first year of the trading scheme for a large part of the time you would have needed to have seen allowance prices of €40 or even €60 per tonne to drive switching. The peak in the allowance price was around €30 per tonne and the average was around €20. The fact is that the difference between coal and gas prices is driven very strongly by the demand for gas, which shows seasonal impacts. Gas prices tend to be highest in the winter and lowest in the summer and they can vary sharply from day-to-day or even hour-to-hour. So whilst the market initially in the first six months seemed to be showing some correlation between carbon price and the annual average cost of switching, the short-term carbon allowance price was not reflecting short-term movements in gas price, so the price was never really sufficient to deliver anything other than a relatively small amount of switching in the first year.

  Q127  Tim Farron: Moving on a little bit, what would be the impact, in your view, of carbon reductions in the UK if carbon allowances did incentivise that kind of switch?

  Mr Porter: You still have to take account of fuel prices and customers' demand and the time of year and so on, but broadly, I suppose it is fair to say, the higher the carbon price the greater the movement over time towards lower carbon technologies. However, I have to be very cautious with the answer because it is not just a question of the carbon price. A great deal is expected of the electricity industry and included in the expectations are things like keeping prices as competitive as they can be and, just as important as that, keeping the lights on.

  Q128  Dr Turner: What is the physical potential in terms of the existing plant in the UK?

  Mr McElroy: It is determined by the capacities of the relative technologies.

  Q129  Dr Turner: You know how much coal plant there is and how much gas plant there is; you must be able to do that calculation.

  Mr McElroy: But the other factor you have got to put in there is demand because ultimately the demand has got to be met and that will ultimately determine the amount of switching that you can do because you can only switch on the slack capacity, the marginal capacity. Yes, we could give you some idea of the switching potential and come back to you on that.

  Dr Turner: That would be very helpful.

  Chairman: That has been quite a helpful and certainly a revealing session. We are grateful to you for coming in and we have managed to wind up just on the dot of five past 11.





 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2007
Prepared 1 March 2007