Select Committee on Environmental Audit Minutes of Evidence


Memorandum submitted by Climate Change Capital

1.  SUMMARY

    —  Phase 1 of the EU ETS should be regarded as a learning phase. It has been successful because it has placed a value on carbon and enabled a functioning international carbon market to be put in place prior to the Kyoto compliance period. However, the impact of the EU ETS may have been disappointing to some observers, since the major impacts have been:

    —  Higher power prices.

    —  Windfall profits for the utility sector.

    —  Little change in operating behaviour.

    —  No investment in Europe yet.

    —  Large scale investment in developing countries.

  Three are three major drivers for this outcome. First, the over-allocation of allowances, caused by incomplete emissions data at the outset. Second, the availability of low cost allowances from the developing world due to the ability to import allowances created by reducing emissions of exotic gases in the developing world, but not within the European scheme. Third, the lack of any price visibility post-2012.

  These shortcomings may be remedied. The actual emissions data for 2005 should allow better allocation of allowances for Phase 2 and clarity on the post-2012 framework should do much to improve the financial attractions of investments to reduce CO2 emissions, especially as the cheaper exotic gas opportunities are exhausted.

2.  INTRODUCTION TO THE AUTHORS

  Climate Change Capital is a specialist investment banking group that occupies a distinctive position. With access to a substantial and flexible capital base, we focus on businesses created or affected by the convergence of laws and polices on energy and the environment. Our dedicated team of 90 professionals located in London, Washington, Madrid and Beijing are experts in the fields of renewable energy, clean technology, biofuels and emissions reductions markets.

  Kate Hampton is responsible for our relations with the policy community. She is a Sherpa to the EU High Level Group on Competitiveness, Energy and Environment, advising the European Commission. She rejoined the company in January 2006 from a year's secondment as a Senior Policy Advisor to Defra for the UK's G8 and EU Presidencies where she worked on the future of international climate change policy. Before joining CCC, Kate was Head of the Climate Change Campaign for Friends of the Earth International. She is the former Convenor of the Green Globe Network, an expert advisory group funded by the Foreign and Commonwealth Office. She was a research associate at the Institute for Policy Studies in Washington DC and an EU policy consultant for Environmental Resources Management. Kate holds a BSc from the London School of Economics and a Masters in Public Policy from the Kennedy School of Government at Harvard University.

  Dr Tony White, MBE is Climate Change Capital's Head of Advisory. Tony has been involved in almost all aspects of the energy industry, ranging from renewable energy research through to strategy, finance, international development and policy. He has made major contributions to the evolution of the industry during this time. Having been the analyst for the UK Government's broker during the liberalisation and privatisation of the England & Wales electricity industry in 1990, he recognised the different role required of network companies serving competitive power markets. This led to the introduction of the Transmission services scheme in England & Wales and was the driving force behind the UK Government's recent review of distributed generation. During the period 1996 to 2003, he was the head of the pan European Utilities Equity Research team at Kleinwort Benson, then Citigroup. Under his leadership, the team became ranked as the "team of teams" in the Extel survey of equity research and was ranked top European utility team by "Institutional Investor". He has been at the forefront of understanding the impact of liberalisation on the generation sector, correctly forecasting the path of power prices in Europe and the USA. He is a non Executive Director of the New and Renewable Energy Centre at Blyth and a member of the Advisory Boards of the United Kingdom Energy Research Centre and the Energy Centre at Sussex University. He has a BA in Physics and D.Phil in Biophysics from Oxford University and an MBA in Finance from the City University Business School.

3.  DETAILED RESPONSE

3.1  What are the key lessons to learn from Phase 1 of the scheme?

  Phase 1 of the EU ETS has established a price for emissions reductions, which should be regarded as being helpful.

  The first period of the scheme has been set for just three years and, although the outline for the second phase's five years has been determined, the amount of abatement required of the scheme will not be determined until late 2006. This is the fundamental driver of the market. Investors have not regarded the price for the first five years as a firm indicator for the second and so are not taking investment decisions based upon it. The corollary of this is that investments based on savings from emissions reductions alone require a three (now one) year payback. There are not many opportunities that provide such immediate returns.

  This leads to the realisation that most decisions are being taken on the basis of short run marginal cost considerations. As such, the simplest way for the European traded sectors to reduce emissions is for coal-fired stations to cut back their output and for production to be increased at gas stations to compensate. Thus the allowance price should be related to the prices of coal and gas, as well as their associated emission factors and efficiency of conversion to electricity. Figure 1 shows that until verified emissions data was released in May 2005, the "implied price" (ie the price of an allowance that equalises the cost of generating power from coal and gas at particular efficiencies) did follow the observed price of EU allowances. However, the actual price was about one third of the implied price. (With the release of verified data, the correlation became weaker, although it appears have re-established itself.) There are many possible reasons for this discrepancy, but what really matters, from an investment point of view, is that the allowance price is currently driven by fossil fuel prices. For example, the price of gas has fallen in the past month from 101 to 91 p/therm; the price of 2006 allowances has also fallen from €16 to €12 over the same period. Because fossil fuel prices tend to be volatile, so the value of allowances is also likely to continue to be volatile, making investment decisions problematic.

  Layered on top of this, we now know from 2005 verified emissions data that Phase 1 of the EU ETS may be on track to have a 40 Mt excess of allowances. Given this is the case the allowance price should fall to zero. The reason it has not is due to a lack of liquidity in the market. In around half the EU Member States, the power sector was short of allowances along with a handful of industrial installations. Where there is a shortage, there is demand for allowances. The power companies have tended to be the only businesses with the capability to hedge on a month-by-month basis. Their natural trading partners are other industries, with the surplus allowances. However, currently industry tends to have a compliance mentality, so excess allowances have not been released onto the market, contributing to a lack of liquidity. Allowance prices have already started to slide in the past month due to more clement weather and therefore reduced fuel demand and prices. With the release of the next round of verified data in May 2007, the allowance price is likely to decline further as industry players confirm they have enough allowances to cover emissions to the close of Phase 1. An excess of allowances released onto the market will probably make it long, driving the price to zero.

  All these factors are not conducive to stimulating investment and underline the need for tight caps across the EU in Phase 2 and beyond.

Figure 1

PHASE 1 TO AUGUST 2006


Source: CCC analysis

3.2  What have been the effects of the method chosen for allocating allowances in Phase 1?

  Member States have set their own emissions caps. Allocations in Phase 2 were largely made based on a grandfathering basis linked to business as usual (BAU) assessments rather than auctioning. Because historic emissions data had not been collected on a systematic basis for all the installations covered by the EU ETS, many of the Member States had to rely on estimates of BAU emissions data from the installations themselves and trade organisations. Not surprisingly, they tended to overstate their requirements. This has led to an overallocation of allowances and an excess not shortage of allowances in Phase 1.

  But Phase 1 can be regarded as a learning phase, and the published emissions data viewed as a calibration of the baseline data on which to allocate permits for subsequent trading phases. In light of the published information, Member States should be better able to set effective allocations for Phase 2. Domestic agendas have seen some Member States set caps in their Phase 2 NAPs that are far higher than those requested by the European Commission or that their verified data merits, putting the integrity of Phase 2 of the EU ETS at risk. The Commission has a significant role to play in reducing the caps, although their powers are limited.

  Looking forward, a remedy to this situation for Phase 3 will be to set an overall absolute EU cap that is then subdivided among Member States and allocated at sector and installation level through auctioning.

3.3  Has the Government identified the correct proportion of allowances to be auctioned in Phase 2? Should these be drawn solely from the power sector's allocation? What will the effect of this auctioning be on industry and the price of carbon?

  The power sector in the UK is relatively shielded from international competition and therefore best able to pass on the cost of carbon onto customers, thereby minimising the affect on competitiveness. This, combined with the sector's historic overestimation of allowance requirements, provides a reasoned basis for the auctioning of allowances from the power sector's allocation.

  Auctioning even just 7% will be useful in terms of a degree of price discovery. However, its potential effect on the price of carbon will be difficult to determine at least until Phase 2 NAPs across the EU are finalised. In principle, there should be no impact on the price, as it is the total number of allowances in circulation that should determine price, not who holds them initially.

3.4  How well are the EUETS and CDM working together? What needs to be done to better integrate these markets? Is CDM funding the right projects?

  There are two types of carbon abatement:

    —  Low capital cost options involving end-of-pipe solutions, operating behaviour, efficiencies; and

    —  High capital cost options involving long-term technological transformation.

  With respect to the links between the EUETS and the CDM mechanisms, the question should focus less on how well are they working together per se and more on are they working to deliver the desired outcomes? The CDM aims to deliver economically efficient emissions reductions and facilitate technology transfer to developing countries. However, this should not be to the detriment of introducing emission reductions within the EU through, ideally, investment in a low carbon infrastructure, the "supplementarity" concept. Thus far, the first type of carbon abatement is occurring very successfully but the second remains elusive. This issue is discussed further later in this submission.

  On integration—a technical point. CERs (credits from CDM projects) and ERUs (those from JI projects) can only be used in the EUETS if the international transaction log (ITL) is functional. The contract for building the ITL has only been awarded in the last month or so—timely delivery of the log is critical to integration of the two mechanisms.

  On investment in the "right" projects. Investors will wish to maximise returns on their investments and there can be significant overheads to the CDM project approval process. These reasons, combined with the absence of certainty over the post-2012 framework, mean investors will be drawn to the "low-hanging fruit", for example end-of-pipe solutions to emissions of exotic gases from industrial plants. While these projects make a significant contribution to the reduction of GHG emissions globally they are not contributing to the development of a global low carbon infrastructure.

3.5  What work needs to be done now to help design a third phase of the EUETS? How can the experience of the EUETS be used to help the design of the post-2012 Kyoto mechanism?

  Or what needs to be done to ensure the EUETS and other mechanisms catalyse investment in a global low carbon economy?

  The process of investors establishing an internal rate of return (IRR) is highly subjective due to the number of assumptions that need to be made in appraising a new project, particularly when dealing with long-term infrastructure projects in complex risk environments. What is obvious is that increasing the minimum carbon price and the time over which carbon value can be recovered improves project returns. This was always going to be the case. The key question is by how much does price and/or period have to increase? This depends on the asset class.

  With time, as investors and companies become more familiar with the movement of allowance prices, they may be willing to make investments whose return will be determined by allowance prices alone, much in the same way as developers invest in gas and oil fields. However, like gas and oil, investors are unlikely to commit to a project requiring for example a €25/tCO2 allowance price to make a return, much as the petroleum industry makes decisions based on oil prices of around $30/bbl, despite the current spot price being closer to $60/bbl. This has been observed in the carbon market. CDM projects are currently being developed at costs of $0.5-8/tCO2e, despite the current higher allowance price. Moreover, with these projects there are considerably greater delivery risks than associated with corporate oil industry deals.

  The consequence is that, to date, there has been little capital investment in the EU to reduce emissions. This presents a perception that the impacts of the EU ETS are negative—windfall profits for the utilities, rising customer prices, and no investment in Europe. However, it is important to recognise that the windfall profits are a consequence of the free allocations, which was a political construct to improve the palatability of the scheme. This is not a failure of a trading as a means to reduce emissions. With time, investors may become more comfortable with the price behaviour of allowances and so investment may be forthcoming. Initially, we expect that investments are unlikely to be made on the basis of emissions alone but, should a company wish to build new capacity on the basis of demand for its product, the choice of technology may be influenced by emissions values.

  However, recent reports from among others the Tyndall Centre indicate responses to the threat of global warming are required on a timescale more urgent than previously thought. Therefore, some adjustments will be required to the emissions trading scheme beyond 2012 to bring forward the required investment. Essentially, what investors need is greater regulatory certainty from the EUETS in order to establish something like a minimum carbon price that they can plug into spreadsheets for long investment periods when they assess new projects. Whether this needs to be an indication of the level of ambition or an actual price floor depends upon timing in the policy cycle and upon the investor.

  Some of the problems that are being encountered by the current scheme will be easily rectified. For example, the lack of high quality emissions data covering the traded sector has vanished now that verified emissions data have been received for 2005. Furthermore, the uncertainty introduced by the absence of banking between periods will not be repeated between Phases 2 and 3. Moreover, the practice of providing grandfathered allowances to existing installations could be removed for Phase 3, or at the very least for sectors that are not exposed to international competition and so are able to pass on allowance costs to their customers.

  Nevertheless, the climate for investments would be greatly improved were the trading periods extended. Could not the abatement targets be set for 15-30 years, compatible with the investment cycles of the large emitting industries? This is, perhaps, the real crux of the matter. Investment likes certainty, yet democracy requires that politicians can change laws. Is democracy (in the form of frequent changes to legislation) incompatible with trading? We think not. Investors recognise that trading regimes that are not delivering policy objectives will be changed. So a mechanism needs to be developed that allows, on the one hand, investors to be given a framework for trading that could last into the long term, yet may also be altered if these objectives are not being met. For climate change, this requires confidence that the goal of achieving substantial emission reduction targets will be maintained for the long term.

  Finally, the idea of full auctioning in Phase 3 is now gaining acceptance among the large utility companies. The benefits of auctioning are that it will give full price discovery—the full cost of carbon will be incorporated into the market; improved liquidity with the market (which currently trades at only around 10% volume, which is keeping the carbon price artificially high); and would also provide a steady revenue stream for Government. But auctioning must be combined with tighter caps—to create confidence in the carbon value. But with a number of draft NAPs for Phase 2 already published, this prospect is not yet secure.

  Governments will have another chance to address this problem as they design the post-2012 regime. Hopefully, the abatement required for the post-2012 will be greater, suggesting that allowance prices will be higher, all other things being equal. The trouble is that such things are not always "equal". A fall in gas prices, or an increase in coal prices, could cause allowance prices to fall. So it may be necessary for Governments to take action, either unilateral or multilateral, to increase confidence that prices will not fall below a level that would render investments uneconomic. Of course, the most obvious way to increase the market's confidence in the scheme would be to ensure that the scheme is expanded to include the USA and Australia.

October 2006



 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2007
Prepared 1 March 2007