Select Committee on Environmental Audit Second Report


Putting the EU ETS into perspective

127. The EU ETS is already a hugely significant development in the global effort to tackle climate change. Although its record so far in actually driving carbon reductions is unproven, it is far and away the largest and most sophisticated mechanism potentially capable of capping international emissions; and, as the Commission's decisions on the Phase II NAPs show, it is moving slowly in the right direction. As such it is providing the inspiration and template for the construction of emissions trading schemes in other countries, and, as the Stern Review notes, has the potential to become the nucleus of a single global carbon market. In this respect, it must aim to become the "gold standard" for all other emissions trading schemes to emulate and be brought through market forces to comply with.

128. From pioneering the early UK Emissions Trading Scheme, to setting tougher National Allocation Plans than other Member States in the EU ETS, to leading the debate on expansion of the Scheme to take in other sectors and countries, the Government has consistently showed international leadership in helping to establish the Scheme and see it fulfil its potential. In its commissioning of the Stern Review, we also hope that it has played an ultimately significant role in persuading other countries, notably the United States, Canada, and Australia, to link to or join the Scheme as soon as practically possible.

129. At the same time, the contribution to be made by the EU ETS on its own ought to be kept in perspective. A strong theme to emerge from our inquiry was of the need to supplement the market mechanism of the EU ETS with other measures in order to ensure it delivers desired outcomes. Appeals for such extra measures came from a wide variety of groups: investors, economists, power companies, industrial lobbies, trade unions, and environmental NGOs. What united these appeals was the concern for certainty and security—over the long term price of carbon, over the fit between the EU ETS and energy policy, over protection from international competition not subject to similar carbon constraints, and over the R&D required to deliver step changes in low carbon technology. Uncertainty over all these issues is clearly impeding investment and the transition to a low carbon economy. The Government must look again at what it can do on its own, and what it can do to influence action at the EU level, to provide the certainty, assistance, and protection required to complement the bare workings of the Scheme itself.

130. Overall, there are perhaps two main and related weaknesses in the Government's statements on emissions trading which it needs to recognise and resolve. The first is the contradiction between the Government's reliance on the EU ETS all by itself to set a price on carbon high enough to incentivise investment in low carbon infrastructure, and its enthusiasm for expanding the Scheme in order to lower the price (and resulting cost impacts on business and consumers), and thus make it more politically and economically acceptable.

131. The second concerns the Government's ambition for relatively tough carbon reduction targets for the UK and EU, which themselves depend on global targets in which the whole of the developed world makes steep cuts, while the whole of the developing world has to meet challenging caps on its growth. The contradiction here lies in the Government's endorsement of and reliance on making up shortfalls in such national targets by buying carbon credits from other countries: if everyone thinks like this, then nobody will reduce any emissions, and nor will there be any surplus credits to buy. Exactly the same applies between different economic sectors; emissions trading cannot be thought of as an excuse for any one sector not to start reducing its actual level of emissions, with the thought that it can simply buy spare allowances from another sector. In order for there to be any spare allowances, all sectors are going to have to make strenuous efforts to push the decarbonisation of their processes as far as possible. The Government must face up to the fact—and start challenging the British population, other governments, and global businesses to do likewise—that ultimately neither the UK, nor any country, nor any industry, can simply buy its way out of meeting its carbon commitments.

132. Above all, the Government must ensure that it is not investing a magical belief in emissions trading as a miracle cure for global warming - something which will , all by itself, necessarily reduce carbon emissions, necessarily lead to a step change in technology, and necessarily achieve this at low cost and without harming productivity. The most important role for emissions trading is to add a cost to carbon. Certainly, it has the potential to do this more efficiently and ultimately at lower overall costs than alternative mechanisms such as a tax on carbon, but still in terms of helping to achieve emissions reductions its primary role is to put a price on carbon. This can help to incentivise low carbon technological development and market transformation, but in doing so it is likely to raise costs and impinge on economic activities in some areas, even if the trading element will help to constrain these costs. Moreover, it cannot guarantee sufficient progress in the timescale required; and if new technologies cannot deliver enough reductions in time, then ultimately we will have to reduce the volume of our carbon-related activities. Emissions trading will not spare us from making difficult decisions and personal or collective sacrifices on the road towards meeting our global carbon reduction targets.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2007
Prepared 1 March 2007