Memorandum from
the Royal Society for the Protection of Birds
Summary
1. Although carbon offsetting is increasingly popular, it is a
highly contentious area of climate change mitigation policy. Not only are there many types of offset of
highly varying quality but there is dispute over whether they are effective in
promoting the types of behavioural change needed to limit climate change. The RSPB thus welcomes the recent Government
initiative to define criteria to bring greater clarity to the offset market and
we are generally supportive of the criteria proposed, i.e. to recognise only
internationally agreed credits.
2. We are, however, concerned that although some offsets deliver
social or biodiversity co-benefits together with carbon savings, there is
currently no way of recognising these benefits. Clearly, it would not be possible to claim extra carbon credit
for projects that have more general sustainability benefits but explicit
identification of such benefits would be advantageous in promoting projects that
are environmentally benign over ones that are adequate solely in carbon terms -
but might be damaging in terms of the broader environment. Currently, for example, the forestry-related
credits recognised by Kyoto do not adequately discriminate between projects
that have both carbon and biodiversity value and those that may save carbon but
could harm wildlife, such as plantations of fast growing monocultures.
Introduction and background: some pros and cons of
offsets
3. The RSPB is Europe's largest wildlife charity with over one
million members. We manage one of the
largest conservation estates in the UK with 196 nature reserves, covering more
than 131,000 hectares. The RSPB is part of the
BirdLife International partnership, a global alliance of independent national
conservation organisations working in more than 100 countries worldwide.
4. The role of offsets in mitigating climate change is the most
hotly disputed area of climate change policy, giving rise to fierce, often
acrimonious disputes amongst those involved in the climate change debate. The RSPB's situation is typical of many
other environmental and nature conservation organisations. On the one hand, many of our nature
conservation activities, both in the UK and abroad, either sequester carbon dioxide
or prevent the degradation of natural land, such as the felling of forests, and
thereby avoid the generation of emissions.
We are thus in a strong position to mitigate climate change by our
conservation activities and hence to generate carbon credits from them, the
proceeds of which could be used both for further mitigation and for nature
conservation.
5. On the other hand, we are concerned about the use of
project-based carbon credits as a tool for the mitigation of climate change
because of the effect that this might have on behavioural change. Whilst it clearly does not matter to the
atmosphere where greenhouse gases are emitted or sequestered, it can matter in
policy terms and begs a number of questions.
If, for example, a core policy objective of an organisation such as the
RSPB is for individuals and nations to reduce emissions at home - because this
is ultimately the only solution to climate change - does it make sense to allow
them to continue to emit, or even increase their personal emissions, and to
purchase cheap offsets from abroad? If
an individual offsets their emissions, will they also try to cut their own
emissions, or lobby government to legislate for emission cuts? Is offsetting a cheap and easy way of
salving the conscience of rich people and rich countries, but not an option for
the poor?
6. Concerns about the use of offsets, both voluntary and officially
sanctioned, also arise in national and international policy-making. For example, both the Kyoto Protocol cap and
trade scheme and the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (EU ETS) allow the use of
Certified Emission Reductions (CERs) from projects conducted under Kyoto's
Clean Development Mechanism (CDM). Yet
if the EU ETS is intended to reduce emissions in the EU, which was clearly the
intention when it was conceived, then should it include emission reductions
from outside the EU, from countries that have no international emission
limitation commitments? Allowing
project-based credits from uncapped countries into the EU ETS not only has the effect
of inflating the EU cap - making the already weak targets even weaker - but it
has implications for the development of the post-2012 climate regime. Under Kyoto and the Climate Convention,
developed countries are obliged to take the lead in reducing emissions, and
developing countries are only likely to take on commitments when the developed
countries have manifestly reduced their own emissions. But, if the developed countries have reduced
their emissions largely, or even partly, by buying emissions reductions from
developing countries, it is debatable whether this constitutes 'taking a lead'.
7. Conversely, proponents of Kyoto-approved credits argue that CDM
projects help developing countries on the path to sustainable development by
providing much needed funding for low carbon projects that would not take place
otherwise. Whilst most of the projects
are in the most developed countries (respectively, India, Brazil, Mexico and
China) rather than the most needy countries they are, on the other hand, being
conducted where emission reductions are most needed. This is in contrast to many 'voluntary' projects which are often
driven by social or environmental factors other than climate change and are
conducted in countries that emit very little - and arguably need to take no
action.
8. It is noteworthy that the volume of credits in the official and
voluntary markets is on a quite different scale. Whilst voluntary markets are said to be booming, they are dwarfed
by the officially sanctioned market where more than 26 million CERs have
already been issued, 710 million will arise from existing projects and more 1.5
billion are expected to be issued by the end of 2012. In our opinion, this trend for the official market to dominate
the voluntary one is likely to continue, if only because the officially
recognised credits have a realisable value, as is outlined below
9. Prices and costs are
markedly different for voluntary and official offsets and the differences are
likely to become more marked when the Kyoto market starts full-scale operation
in 2008 and the value of CDM and Joint Implementation (JI) credits is likely to
rise. This price differential arises
because official credits are required by developed countries to comply with
legally binding emission reduction targets under Kyoto and thus have a value
linked to the cost of meeting those targets - not simply the cost of the
projects. The projects also have to
bear costs associated with formal validation and approval processes. The sole purpose of a voluntary offset,
however, is to provide a lowest cost emission reduction, often with minimal
accreditation costs, and so their sale price is always likely to be lower. (It can be argued that all offsets should be
priced so as to reflect the damage costs of climate change, rather than being
as cheap as possible, but this seems unlikely because it would significantly
raise the price of offsets. DEFRA's
recommended social cost of carbon (damage cost) is £70/tonne carbon but other
estimates range as high as £1,000 tonne C.)
10. On balance, the RSPB considers that only those offsets approved by
the agreed international system, the Kyoto Protocol, should be employed in
'voluntary' markets. These obey rules
which were agreed by experts from nearly all countries in the World and,
although they are deficient in some respects, they are the best that there
are. To use other credits, obeying
other sets of rules, if any, would seem perverse.
11. We recognise, however, that there are certain types of emission
saving activity that are not, at present, recognised by the international
system - notably emissions avoided by not felling tropical forests (so-called
avoided or reduced deforestation) but also emissions from other land-use
change, such as peat extraction.
Halting activities such as deforestation not only has huge value in
terms of combating climate change (20% of global emissions arise from tropical
deforestation) but has a similarly large value in terms of conserving
biodiversity and protecting indigenous people.
We consider that recognising such co-benefits is imperative and we will
therefore strive to bring such activities within the remit of the international
climate regime and participate in pilot projects in order to gain greater
knowledge of the subjects.
In the remainder of this response, we answer the questions
posed by the Committee in the order that they were set in the call for
evidence.
Ought there to be a compulsory UK or European
accreditation scheme for carbon offset projects or companies? If so, how should
this operate?
12. Yes. It should be the same
as that agreed under Kyoto, allowing only those projects approved by Kyoto,
i.e. Certified Emission Reductions (CERs) from the Clean Development Mechanism
(CDM) and Emission Reduction Units (ERUs) from Joint Implementation (JI)
projects in developed countries.
13. There are already mechanisms in place for the approval of projects
under Kyoto; in the case of CDM credits approval is by the CDM's Executive
Board.
14. As avoided deforestation and other land use change activities are
included in Kyoto, they too should be included eligible for accreditation under
any UK or EU scheme.
Should offsetting become mandatory for some of the
more carbon-intensive activities, such as flying?
15. No. The way to reduce
emissions from aviation is to do just that, by managing demand and, making
aircraft more efficient in terms of their greenhouse gas emissions.
16. The key to reducing emissions nationally and internationally is by
means of constantly diminishing carbon budgets covering all emissions, linked,
where possible, to trading schemes that allow personal or institutional choice
over which emissions to cut, as long as overall emissions where reduced. Aviation emissions might then continue to
increase, within limits, so long as commensurate cuts where made elsewhere
within the capped system. A draft
amendment to the EU ETS, issued by the Commission in December 2006, aims at
this type of solution. Aviation
emissions would be opted into the EU ETS, covering about 50% of all EU carbon
dioxide emissions. Emissions from large
combustion plant and aviation would then be capped but emission allowances
could be traded, allowing aviation emissions to rise if aircraft operators
purchased allowances from the operators of large combustion plant that had cut
emissions by more than their target. In
principle, we welcome this type of approach although we have reservations about
the details of the Commission's proposal.
(The key test of the effectiveness of any cap and trade scheme is that
it will cut emissions in line with national and international targets yet, as
it stands, the Commission proposal does not ensure that this occurs.)
17. Offsetting aviation emissions, or emissions from other sources,
with credits from uncapped nations does not, ultimately, solve the problem of
rising emissions in capped countries like the UK. Emissions in most developing countries, especially the rapidly
industrialising ones continue to rise apace and unchecked. A few offset projects, even if they amount
to many millions of tonnes of carbon will do almost nothing to slow this
rise. If we are to tackle the problem
of climate change much more stringent action is needed, perhaps in the form of
commitments to limit the rate of increase of emissions in some sectors in the
most rapidly industrialising developing countries.
Is there enough clarity within the offset market to
allow customers to make informed choices based upon robust information about
different schemes at different prices?
18. No. We have had an interest
in this area for about decade yet we would find it very hard to make a fully
informed choice. For the non-expert it
is a minefield, with some excellent credits delivering climate change,
biodiversity and social co-benefits and others delivering little or no
benefits. There are no reliable,
unbiased sources of information on the subject.
Many offset projects involve afforestation or
reforestation. Is the science sufficiently coherent in this area accurately to
assess overall long-term carbon (or other GHG) gains and losses from such
projects?
19. Whilst there is considerable uncertainty in estimates of the take
up of carbon dioxide by forests and other land use change, this is not
necessarily a severe problem as long as conservative estimates are used when
claiming credit for carbon stored. This
is a standard means of addressing uncertainty.
20. A more intractable problem is the fact that all biological sinks
for carbon can reverse. That is, they
can release the carbon that they have stored.
Carbon sequestration projects are fundamentally dissimilar to emission
avoidance projects, such as those involving energy. Once emissions are avoided, for example by replacing a diesel
generating set with a hydroelectric one, then they are avoided forever, the
emissions never reach the atmosphere and never cause any damage. Forests typically store carbon from the
atmosphere but if it is later released then the initial storage is negated; the
atmosphere is harmed as much as it would have been in the first place. To be effective as a mitigation measure,
sequestration projects thus need to ensure that carbon is stored forever.
21. However, forest fires, pests and climate change can all cause
forests to change from net sinks for carbon to net sources and it is obviously
impossible to forestall all such occurrences indefinitely. The Kyoto Protocol's Clean Development
Mechanism (CDM) circumvents this difficulty by introducing the concept of a
temporary Certified Emission Reductions (tCER) which expires after five years
but can be renewed it is demonstrated that the forest remains unchanged. This 'solution' works in accountancy terms
but does not repair any damage done to the atmosphere if a carbon sink
reverses.
Is there sufficient data available to guarantee
accurate amounts of carbon or other GHG mitigation in the sorts of schemes
which offset projects finance?
22. The voluntary market varies enormously with some offsets being
rigorously scrutinised and others not, according to widely varying sets of
voluntary rules.
23. In the CDM there are suitable provisions, except if a sequestration
project reverses. CDM project
developers have to prepare detailed plans and methodologies that are
scrutinised by the CDM Executive Board of independent experts, and projects are
regularly verified. All estimates of
carbon saved are conservative so that, if anything, the emission savings are
underestimated. Project details and CDM
Executive Board proceedings are published, and Board meetings can be viewed
live on the web.
What impact will the voluntary carbon offset market
have on the compliance market if the former continues to grow as steadily as it
has done over the last few years?
24. Very little or perhaps none.
The market in compliance-related project credits will be increasingly
driven by the need to generate credits that can be used to demonstrate
compliance in the 2008-12 period of both the Kyoto Protocol and EU ETS, for
which voluntary credits are useless.
25. The market in voluntary credits is driven by individuals and
institutions that wish to green their lifestyles or modes of operations and, in
the case of institutions, to publicly demonstrate that they are doing so. However, because of ongoing disputes about
the value of voluntary credits, companies are increasingly using compliance
credits (CERs) to protect their reputations and, because the corporate sector
is potentially so valuable to them, offset companies are tending to do the
same.
26. In the longer term, we consider that the market for voluntary
credits will decline, being substituted largely by official compliance credits
- largely to avoid reputational risk.
This decline is likely to be accelerated by the UK Government proposals
for an accreditation scheme that only recognises compliance-related credits
(CERs, ERUs and EU ETS allowances).
What evidence is there to show that offsetting helps
to change the carbon behaviour of the customer?
27. We are unaware of any definitive evidence. Individuals that employ offsets tend to be
environmentally aware and keen to do something to mitigate their unsustainable
lifestyles, especially flying. They are
probably not, therefore, representative of society as a whole and it is hard to
say whether they would alter their carbon behaviour anyway, because they are
'green', or because they choose to offset.
28. There is a concern that using offsets will tend to prevent
individuals, or institutions, from taking practical action themselves because,
if offsetting is truly effective, why should they alter their behaviour or
encourage others to do so? If, for
example, a company offsets the emissions from flights taken by its staff, would
it also cut back on flying and lobby government to reduce demand for
aviation? We think not.
To what extent are the schemes and projects funded
by offset companies more broadly sustainable, in an environmental, social or
economic sense?
29. Many projects in the voluntary market are specifically designed to
be more broadly sustainable, certainly in the sense of being more generally
environmentally friendly and more socially just. Indeed, voluntary offset projects were originally conceived as
forest conservation projects or schemes to assist poor people in developing
countries and also happen to save carbon.
30. Whilst projects that deliver multiple benefits are clearly highly
desirable, it can be hard to marry the different benefits effectively. For example, one of the longest and most
acrimonious debates in the detailed negotiations on the Kyoto forestry
provisions was around the climate and biodiversity benefits that might accrue
from afforestation and reforestation projects.
On one hand, there was a desire to support projects that would lead to
the regrowth of natural forests in developing countries, with considerable
benefits for biodiversity and indigenous people but sequestering carbon at a
low rate. On the other hand, there was
a desire to maximise carbon sequestration rates, which would be best achieved
by fast-growing monoculture plantations, delivering considerable carbon benefit
but with potentially disastrous effects on biodiversity and indigenous people.
31. In the end, it was not possible to find a way of excluding
monoculture plantations and encouraging the greater environmental and social
good - because the Kyoto Protocol basically deals in carbon saving and not with
more general sustainability as well.
There are thus likely to be more bad than good forestry projects, in
general environmental and social terms, in spite of the best intentions of many
negotiators. This situation clearly
needs to be rectified. Any
accreditation scheme should identify and support projects that bring
biodiversity or social co-benefits whilst ruling out those that have adverse
effects upon sustainable development.
It might, for example, be appropriate for international agreements such
as the Convention on Biological Diversity (CBD) to provide biodiversity
criteria for land use change-related projects conducted under the Kyoto
Protocol.
January 2007