Select Committee on Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Written Evidence


Memorandum submitted by Professor A Swinbank (CAP 07)

THE NEED FOR, AND THE DIRECTION OF, THE NEXT CAP REFORM

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

  A Vision ... is a useful contribution to the debate on CAP reform, and I have no quarrel with the thrust of its argument. In this submission, rather than reiterate the full debate, I outline some of the WTO pressures that are being brought to bear on the CAP, discuss some of the problems associated with the Single Payment Scheme (SPS), and make some suggestions for further reform. With an agreement to the Doha Round, the elimination of export subsidies by 2013, and substantial reductions in import tariffs, will increase the pressure to reduce levels of price support for sugar, dairy, beef, etc. If there is no satisfactory outcome to Doha, a resurgence of litigation can be expected in the WTO that could lead to the piecemeal dismantling of the CAP. Even the new SPS could prove problematic in the WTO. There are other problems with the SPS, particularly as applied in England. CAP reform 2008-2009 should involve significant reduction in the remaining levels of market price support, and an agreement on a phased reduction in the Single Payment. Ideally, the latter would also be decoupled from land. Expenditure on Pillar II should be increased, when this can result in a cost-effective enhancement in environmental provision.

INTRODUCTION

  1.  A Vision for the Common Agricultural Policy, published jointly by Defra and HM Treasury in early December 2005, is a useful contribution to the new debate on CAP reform launched by the European Council on 16 December 2005: the meeting invited "the Commission to undertake a full, wide ranging review covering all aspects of EU spending, including the CAP, and of resources, including the UK rebate, to report in 2008-09" (paragraph 80 of the Final comprehensive proposal from the Presidency on the Financial Perspective 2007-13, emphasis added). There is considerable evidence to suggest that substantial pressures will be building for a new reform of the CAP by 2008-2009. As I am in broad agreement with the Defra/Treasury text, I have chosen in this submission to: first emphasise the WTO pressures that are being brought to bear on the "old" CAP, second outline the problems inherent in the new SPS, and third suggest some issues that have to be addressed in any future reform.

THE "OLD" CAP, AND THE WTO

  2.  By the "old" CAP I mean the market price support measures of high import taxes, intervention buying and other domestic market interventions, and export subsidies.[1] Despite the MacSharry Reforms of 1992, the Fischler Reforms of 2003-2004, and recent changes to the sugar regime, the original market price support measures still form an important part of the CAP, imposing costs upon European consumers and taxpayers, distorting resource use within the EU, disrupting international markets, and producing an uncertain benefit in terms of the long-term sustainability of farm incomes and an acceptable environmental impact. These "old" policies are still very important for sugar, dairy, beef, and other products. Furthermore they are under threat in the WTO.

  3.  The WTO "threat" is two-fold. First, through negotiation (as in the ongoing Doha Round), tighter constraints on domestic farm policies can be agreed. Second, through the Dispute Settlement Process, existing policies can be tested, and found wanting, as the EU discovered in relation to its export subsidies on sugar, and the US for many aspects of its support for upland cotton. The December 2005 WTO Ministerial in Hong Kong was successful in that the Doha Development Agenda talks continue. If these talks are to be successfully concluded, it would seem that a considerable tightening of the constraints embodied in the existing Agreement on Agriculture will need to be agreed.

  4.  If the negotiations fail, the existing agreement will remain in place, but without the special protection of Article 13 (the so-called Peace Clause) that has, in the past, allowed certain elements of farm policies to depart from WTO norms. A more litigious future would ensue, which could result in a piecemeal dismantling of the "old" CAP if the EU is to remain a respected member of a rules-based organisation.

  5.  Reference is frequently made to the three pillars of the existing agreement: market access; domestic support; and export competition. All three raise potential problems for the existing CAP.

  6.  It is already agreed that, in the framework of any new agreement, export subsidies will be eliminated by 2013. This could be problematic for the CAP, as Table 1 suggests (and this is quite apart from any difficulties the EU may face in curbing its exports of sugar as of 22 May 2006, to conform with the WTO sugar panel ruling). For bulk commodity exports, the EU frequently uses a tender mechanism under which traders bid for the export subsidy they are willing to accept to export product. Table 1 reports the results of three tenders held in January 2006 (as reported by Agra Europe). I have then adjusted these figures to allow for the further cuts in the intervention price for butter (agreed in the Fischler Reforms, but not yet implemented) and in the support price for sugar (as agreed in November 2005).

Table 1

MAXIMUM EXPORT REFUNDS (SUBSIDIES) DETERMINED BY TENDER FOR WHEAT, BUTTER AND SUGAR, JANUARY 2006


<lh1>
Maximum refund determined by tender January €/tonne
Implied refund after ongoing reform
€/tonne
Revised refund expressed as a % of the new support price

<lh0>Wheat
19 January
9.00
9.00
8.8
Butter
12 January
985.50
625.00
25.4
Sugar
19 January
359.24
131.74
32.6


  7.  It is a mechanistic calculation, that allows for no increase in world market prices, but the implication is that an export subsidy equivalent to 25% of the new support price for butter (and 33% of the new support price for sugar) would still be necessary if these products were to be exported. Now it may be that as a result of increased consumption (particularly in the new Member States) and the policy measures currently being implemented, the new supply-demand balance of EU-25 will eliminate the need for bulk commodity exports by 2013 (failing which a further tightening of quotas could reduce EU production). But where does that leave the food industry? Manufacturers of processed products, incorporating cereals, dairy products and sugar, qualify for export refunds under the Non-Annex I regime, based on the export subsidies that would have been paid on the raw materials. If all export refunds are to be eliminated by 2013, including those on Non-Annex I goods, whilst EU prices for raw materials remain substantially above those prevailing on world markets, EU-based food manufacturers could see their overseas sales jeopardised.

  8.  In October 2005 the EU offered to make substantial cuts in the "bound" level of domestic support (which of course is not the same as a cut in the actual level of support, given that this is lower that the WTO binding): for example, by reducing the permitted binding on the Aggregate Measurement of Support (AMS) by 70% (Making Hong Kong a Success: Europe's Contribution, Brussels, 28 October 2005, p 3). The complex set of proposals on domestic support is difficult to disentangle and interpret, but it does seem clear that the EU's strategy is based on the premise that the new SPS will qualify for the "green box", and consequently that it will not be subject to expenditure limits. I return to this in paragraph 13 below.

  9.  On market access, the EU has suggested that import tariffs of over 90% (typical for many core CAP commodities) should be subject to a cut of 60%; but that up to 8% of tariff lines should be designated "sensitive", allowing a smaller reduction to apply; and that the special safeguard mechanisms should be retained for "beef, poultry, butter, fruits and vegetables and sugar" (op cit, pp 5-6). My guess is that this proposal is on the edge, but that more ambitious tariff cuts, with fewer sensitive products, and the abandonment of the special safeguard clause, would render untenable the proposed domestic support prices for sugar, butter, beef, ... A group of developing countries are insistent that the Doha Round can only be concluded if more ambitious market access openings are conceded by developed countries.

POTENTIAL PROBLEMS WITH THE SINGLE PAYMENT SCHEME (SPS)

  10.  The Fischler Reforms of 2003-2004 introduced an important decoupling of support with the introduction of the SPS. Potentially it gives farmers greater freedom to farm, enhancing the competitiveness of European agriculture; it could have reduced the administrative burden of the old area and headage payment schemes, paid under the Integrated Administration and Control System (IACS), although Member States seem to have conspired to thwart this ambition; and it moved the EU towards a more WTO-compatible system of support. However, it is not without its problems.

  11.  Article 1 of Regulation 1782/2003 introducing the scheme, calls it an "income support for farmers". Quite why "farmers", as opposed to any other group in society, need an income support funded by taxpayers is unclear; but even within the context of farming its rationale is uncertain. The main beneficiaries of a land-based payment will be existing landowners, rather than tenant farmers or new entrants to the industry (although new business enterprises may emerge, growing crops and raising livestock, and paying a peppercorn rent to the established "farmer" who retains the Single Payment). Furthermore, there is no suggestion that the "income support" is targeted on need or circumstance: instead it is determined, basically, on the area farmed and the country's historic IACS entitlements (under the regionalised scheme) or the farm's historic IACS entitlements. It will be some time before we have data which will show the distribution of Single Payments within and between Member States, but data produced by the European Commission on all direct payments made to producers in 2003 suggests that the distribution is likely to be highly uneven. Figure 1 shows the average payment per claimant in each of the Member States, whilst Figure 2 shows the size distribution of payments in the UK. There are lots of problems associated with this data, and its interpretation, and these distributions will not be replicated under the SPS, but—these caveats apart—it is not immediately apparent why the average payment in Portugal should be a fraction of that in the UK, if this is an "income support" measure; or why 0.7% of claimants in the UK should have been entitled to 11% of the payments made.

Figure 1

AVERAGE DIRECT PAYMENT MADE IN 2003, BY MEMBER STATE

€/CLAIMANT


  Source for Figures 1 and 2: calculated from data in a pdf document (Annex 1. Indicative Figures of the Distribution of Aid, by Size-Class of Aid, Received by the Producers According to Reg (EC) No 1259/1999 (Financial Years 2002 and 2003)), available at http://europa.eu.int/comm/agriculture/fin/index_en.htm (accessed 20 January 2006).

Figure 2

DISTRIBUTION OF DIRECT PAYMENTS, BY SIZE OF PAYMENT, UK 2003


  Source: As Figure 1.

Note, the horizontal axis indicates the size of payment (in €1,000 euros) per claimant. The size categories across the figure are highly uneven. Thus the first category refers to payments per claimant of less than €1,250, the second of payments between €1,250 and €2,000, etc. It shows, for example, that 20.2% of claimants received payments of €1,250 or less, accounting for 0.5% of the monies paid in 2003.

  12.  It is often said, with much justification, that European agriculture is multifunctional: that it supports a cultural and visual landscape, and a fauna and flora, that is manmade having evolved over thousands of years of agricultural (and other land use) practice; and it is pointed out that farmers are not directly reimbursed for any costs that they might incur for the provision of these services. Thus the Single Payment might be thought of as a payment for multifunctionality. However, no attempt has been made to link the size of payment either to the cost of provision of, or to the value society places on, multifunctionality. Under the regionalised scheme, it will be a flat-rate payment per hectare; and under the farm-based, historic, scheme payment rates per hectare vary regardless of the multifunctionality of the land. Cross compliance does of course apply, but apparently Defra figures suggest that "the costs to English farmers of cross-compliance ... is less than 2% of the value of direct payments made to English farmers under the CAP" (A Vision ..., p 33). Furthermore, additional payments are made for multifunctionality: for example "the general expectation in England is that Entry Level Stewardship (ELS) will cover two-thirds or more of English farmland within three or four years" (op cit, p 33).

  13.  As suggested in paragraph 8 above, and despite the EU's best intentions, the SPS may not fit the green box. The overarching requirement is that green box policies must have "no, or at most minimal, trade-distorting effects or effects of production" (Article 1 of Annex 2 of the Agreement on Agriculture), and whilst it might be thought that the SPS (at least in its decoupled form, as applied in the UK)[2] readily satisfies this condition, this could be misleading as a series of policy specific criteria must also be met. For example, paragraph d of Article 6 (the heading that the EU is most likely to use to declare the Single Payment to the WTO) specifies that "The amount of such payments in any given year shall not be related to, or based on, the factors of production employed in any year after the base period". As the Single Payment is an annual payment, paid to farmers, on the basis of the area farmed (or kept in good environmental condition) in that year, and cross compliance applies, it seems that, from a strictly legal perspective, the SPS fails to comply.[3] Although there has been some talk about revising the green box criteria in the ongoing Doha Round, this has not yet happened; and many participants would be very reluctant to see the criteria weakened. Thus there is a danger (slight, maybe) that the cornerstone of the post-Fischler CAP could be challenged in the WTO.

CAP REFORM 2008-09

  14.  The foregoing discussion has suggested that a further reform of the "old" CAP must be undertaken in the near future, in order to comply with any likely outcome to the Doha Round. This could involve substantial reductions in the support prices for sugar, dairy, beef, and other products, to make an elimination of export subsidies by 2013 a feasible objective, and permit a substantial reduction in import barriers. If the EU is unable to reach such an agreement in the Doha Round, then the prospect is that of unplanned and piecemeal dismantling of the "old" CAP as the provisions of various commodity regimes are attacked in dispute settlement cases.

  15.  Reform will doubtless lead to calls for financial compensation for the producers so affected, and the creation of new Single Payment entitlements. The logic of the budget ceiling agreement in Brussels in 2002, reaffirmed last December, is that the money for these new entitlements must come from the existing Pillar I budget. This implies some reduction in the funding of existing Single Payment entitlements, in order to release funds for the new compensation schemes. In England and Germany, under the regionalised scheme, a rather bizarre readjustment of entitlements could occur, as first monies will have to be released from existing entitlements to fund the nominal compensation payments of the new commodity specific reform, but then these monies will be used to augment everyone's Single Payment on a flat-rate basis (further complications arise if this rebalancing takes place at EU, rather than the national, level). Thus, most claimants will be left with more-or-less the same level of payment (despite the reduction in the level of existing payments to fund the new scheme) whilst producers of the affected product will experience a fall in support prices, but receive no product-specific compensation.

  16.  In passing it might be noted that, although doubtless adopted in good faith, the regionalised system of payment does seem flawed. It is strategically, economically and socially problematic. Strategically, because it undermines the UK's negotiating position in the EU's Council of Ministers. The regionalised scheme was justified as a more defensible income support measure in the longer run, and with an enhanced environmental impact over a larger farmed area. But this long-term justification fits uneasily with a vision in which "production-linked support and the Single Farm Payment had effectively disappeared" (A Vision ... p 15). Economically, because the SPS is not fully decoupled, it has brought more land and more producers into the subsidy net. Finally, within agriculture, it is socially problematic because it gives landowners enhanced power (than would be the case under the historic, farm-based, scheme) in negotiation with tenants over the appropriation of the financial benefits conferred.

  17.  If the SPS is phased out, recipients must be given a clear indication of the timescale involved, rather than the uncertain message that the financial mechanism might be applied after 2007, that modulation can now be applied at 20%, etc, with each "expert" touting their own vision of the future.

  18.  It would also be beneficial to further decouple payments from land: A Vision ... (p 17) suggests that "time-limited payments to producers to compensate for income foregone, or to compensate for reduced asset values could be considered. In both cases, de-linking such payments from land would better facilitate adjustment." In essence this is the bond scheme, articulated by Professor Stefan Tangermann in the early 1990s.[4] Under such a scheme, compensation payments would not be linked to farmers, land, or farming, but would be completely decoupled (and, I believe, accepted as such in the WTO).

  19.  A phasing out of the SPS does, however, imply a loss of the limited environmental benefits secured by cross-compliance. However it would release funds for an enhanced and reinvigorated, but cost-effective and WTO-compliant, programme of environmental protection under Pillar II.

January 2006






1   The WTO refers to an export subsidy; the CAP uses the term export refund. Back

2   Where partial decoupling applies-for example, linking 25% of the former arable area aid to cropped land-the green box criteria are almost certainly not satisfied. Back

3   For further discussion see: Alan Swinbank and Richard Tranter, "Decoupling EU Farm Support: Does the New Single Payment Scheme Fit within the Green Box?", The Estey Centre Journal of International Law and Trade Policy, 6(1): 47-61, 2005. Back

4   See Alan Swinbank & Richard Tranter (editors), A Bond Scheme for Common Agricultural Policy Reform, CABI Publishing: Wallingford, 2004. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2007
Prepared 24 May 2007