Memorandum submitted by Professor D Harvey
(CAP 09)
SUMMARY
Memorandum 1: Critique of the Vision: The
Defra/Treasury Vision is mis-timed and ill-focused. Following
the EU Budget summit and agreement in December 2005, there is
very little opportunity in the near future to make any substantial
changes to the CAP. The promised review of the European Budget
in 2008 can be treated as being only about the budget, and not
about the underlying policies. Yet the Vision makes virtually
no mention of the budgetary arrangements for the CAP. This vision
is not a serious option for EU agreement in the foreseeable future.
Furthermore, elimination of Pillar 1 support maybe a vision to
some, but to many countryside interest groups, without any transition
provision it will be seen as a nightmare. This is not because
the present uses and management of Pillar 1 support are sensible,
effective or efficientthey are not (at least not for the
UK). Elimination of market support and dedicated farmer support
(unconditional direct payments) may be a worthy aspiration. But
this "vision" does little to help achieve it.
Memorandum 2: An Alternative Vision: Turning
aspiration into reality requires a careful explanation of the
means of achievement, and a more realistic assessment of the benefits
and costs than is managed here. In particular, it needs to explain
more realistically how we might make progress from where we are
now to where we might want to be. Incidentally, such a careful
explanation and more realistic assessment also turns out to be
considerably more sympathetic and sensitive to the critical interests
in the countryside than the present document, and hence more likely
to foster and improve debate, as a precursor to acceptance and
pursuit of the ambition. But even more importantly, the alternative
vision begins with the budget and financial arrangements for the
current CAP, and is thus much more likely to be realisable than
a vision which concentrates on the policy itself.
MEMORANDUM 1: CRITIQUE
OF THE
VISION
1. "This paper sets out a vision for
the future of the European Union's Common Agricultural Policy.
Its aim is to stimulate and help inform debate." Against
these aims, this a disappointing document. There are four major
grounds for this depressing judgement:
2. Firstly, contrary to the title, there
is no real vision of the future here, other than a proposal to
eliminate Pillar 1 support over a 10-15 year time horizon, and
a rehearsal of general principles. These are little more than
platitudes, hardly differing from previously agreed statements
(see below). Otherwise, the "vision" consists largely
of a critique of past policy and a catalogue of its well-documented
shortcomings. Rather than being a vision of "where we want
to be in 10-15 years time, and why" it is focused largely
on where we were 10-15 years ago, and why that was so bad, which
is not at all the same thing. The visiona world without
any Pillar 1 supportmay well please the Treasury and the
taxpayers (who would hardly notice), but it is more like a nightmare
to many countryside interests, and complete anathema to many presently
powerful EU voices. Its chances to being realised on the basis
of this document are smallfundamentally sound though the
aspiration might be.
The UK December 2005 Vision
Our vision for agriculture within the next 10-15
years is for an industry which is fundamentally sustainable and
an integral part of the European economy. It should be:
Internationally competitive without
reliance on subsidy or protection.
Rewarded by the market for its outputs,
not least safe and good quality food, and by the taxpayer only
for producing societal benefits that the market cannot deliver.
Environmentally-sensitive, maintaining
and enhancing landscape and wildlife and tackling pollution.
Socially responsive to the needs
of rural communities.
Producing to high levels of animal
health and welfare.
Non-distorting of international trade
and the world economy.
The EU June 1998 Vision
"All these proposals together have the aim
of giving concrete form to a European model for agriculture in
the years ahead. It is worth listing here what the main lines
of this model should be:
A competitive agriculture sector
which can gradually face up to the world market without being
over-subsidised, since this is becoming less and less acceptable
internationally.
Production methods which are sound
and environmentally friendly, able to supply quality products
of the kind the public wants.
Diverse forms of agriculture, rich
in tradition, which are not just output-oriented but seek to maintain
the visual amenity of our countrysides as well as vibrant and
active rural communities, generating and maintaining employment.
A simpler, more understandable agricultural
policy which establishes a clear dividing line between the decisions
that have to be taken jointly and those which should stay in the
hands of the Member States.
An agricultural policy which makes
clear that the expenditure it involves is justified by the services
which society at large expects farmers to provide."
Source: European Commission, Explanatory
Memorandum, The future for European Agriculture Agenda 2000, Agricultural
Proposals, June 1998
3. Secondly, the critique of the CAP is
substantially out-of-date, referring to previous rather than present
policy, and ignoring future policy trajectories (see 3.c below).
As such, it re-inforces popular myths and misconceptions, rather
than improving understanding of the current issues and problems.
The costs of the current (substantially reformed) CAP are over-stated.
In particular, the OECD's estimates of Producer Subsidy Equivalents
(PSE) are well known to substantially over-state the extent of
policy subsidisation because they are based on current (policy
distorted) world prices. As and when support and protection is
reduced, world prices are expected to rise, in some cases (eg
milk) very substantially (see Colman, 2002). The consequent result
for producer support is then substantially reduced. The implication
that these costs will persist into the future, unless radical
reform is undertaken, is misleading. As a result, the contribution
to genuine and constructive debate is compromised.
4. Thirdly, the premise of the "vision"
is that it does "not set out a route map for getting there.
(Since) That must be the subject of debate across Europe and achieved
through gradual and carefully managed change to give clear signals
and time for farmers to adjust their businesses, not an overnight
upheaval." (ES p1). This premise is fundamentally mistaken,
on three major grounds.
a. From a theoretical point of view, it is
far from clear that "gradual and carefully managed change"
is a sensible recipe for either efficient or effective business
adjustment. The New Zealand case strongly suggests that unambiguous
signals and capacity to adjust are far more important than gradual
change and time to adjust. The necessary incentives and freedom
to adjust are only provided in full on completion of the policy
change. Until this point, any signals for adjustment are necessarily
muted and very possibly noisy, resulting in inappropriate and
costly adjustment. Capacity to adjust depends critically on the
transition provisions. This point is further elaborated in Colman,
2002, chapter 9.
b. From a practical point of view, sensible
debate and negotiation about policy options requires serious consideration
of the means and processes of change. The political problem is
not about where we want to be, as the general agreement on the
objectives (1 above) indicates, but precisely on how to get there
from here (or even whether such a nirvana is possiblesee
4 below). Resistance to change is exactly that: resistance to
change, not necessarily resistance to improvement or objectives.
c. Change is happening anyway, from the already
agreed Single Farm Payments and associated reductions in traditional
market support, to the practically inevitable changes as a consequence
of current WTO negotiations under the Doha round. Although the
details of these changes are not yet known, their general direction
towards less market intervention is guaranteed. Ignoring these
changes and their consequences reduces the relevance of the present
document and further compromises its utility as a platform for
debating and agreeing future policy.
5. Finally, the document ignores the critical
blockage to reform of the policy: the lack of conviction among
either farmers or "pastoralists" (those concerned with
the rural environment, countryside, rural cultures and development)
that the "vision" is achievable or desirable. Both sides
of the countryside debate are far from convinced, though for apparently
very different reasons, that the free market in agricultural products
coupled with largely unspecified central (EU or UK) intervention
can possibly meet the objectives of the vision. Farmers are generally
unconvinced that they can survive in a free market. Pastoralists
are frequently anxious about the potential ravages of commercial
and industrial agriculture (as an apparently inevitable consequence
of free trade farming) on rural environments, landscapes, animal
welfare and biodiversity, or about the adverse consequences for
rural development as businesses and enterprises adapt to elimination
of support.
6. Any attempt to relieve these anxieties
through regulation further frightens farmers, who see their capacity
to compete in a free market being even more restricted. Neither
major interest group is prepared to sign up to reform negotiations
on this basis without a clear idea of exactly what is involved.
They will be even less likely to participate on the basis of a
"vision" which largely ignores the recent hard-won and
substantial reforms to the policy, and hence, by implication,
ignores the interests of those most concerned with earning a living
from and having a life in the countryside. As the EFRA Committee
announcement recognises, there are important, if not critical
questions about "how the reforms proposed in the report could
be achieved in practice, and how these changes relate to the ongoing
debate surrounding the future financing of the CAP. What barriers
might be put in the way of implementing such reforms by other
EU member states?" It might have added, what resistance can
be expected within the UK? We need an alternative vision to provide
answers to these questions.
MEMORANDUM 2: AN
ALTERNATIVE VISION
The shape of an unsupported agriculture
1. What would the countryside look like
without traditional (Pillar 1) CAP support? How competitive would
UK or EU farming be in a free trade world? Would the UK become
totally dependent on food imports? What would happen to food prices?
Would farming retreat to industrial monocultures in the most favoured
lands and leave the rest to become wilderness? Would intensity
increase, with consequent pollution problems? Would farmers eliminate
discretionary spending on the environment, or would they exploit
opportunities to sell their environments, and increase their attention
to such environments?
2. These are all very good questions. But
none are addressed in the current "vision" document,
and none admit of unambiguous or concrete answers. Since European
history does not include such a condition, there is no solid evidence
on which to base any answer. The New Zealand experience (which
is the closest analogy) strongly suggests that agriculture would
quickly adjust to become competitive and profitable, at substantially
similar output levels as under support, but there are reasons
to doubt the relevance to the European condition. The only alternative
is to speculate on the basis of some more or less coherent understanding
of the way the socio-economic world works.
3. Working from first principles, much of
European commercial agriculture would be competitive and profitable
in an unsupported world. We have some of the best land, blessed
with some of the most favourable agro-climatic conditions, embedded
within one of the richest and most populated economies on the
planet. Our farm structure is good, well populated with skilled
and experienced farmers, blessed with fully integrated and modern
supply and marketing chains, and backed up well developed credit
and legal institutions. Why would such an agricultural system
not be competitive with the best in the world, especially for
the home market?
4. Two major reasons are obvious. First,
the shock and trauma associated with elimination of support would
disrupt these favourable conditions to such an extent that it
would take a generation at least to make the most of these fundamental
opportunities. Second, the European population would hedge the
industry with so many environmental, animal welfare, landscape,
planning and employment conditions and regulations that the industry's
costs of compliance would make it uncompetitive. Under either
of these conditions, food supplies would fall and prices would
necessarily rise, since the rest of the world cannot supply Europe
with all its food needs, especially not at prices near current
levels. As prices rise, so some domestic EU production would become
viable and profitable. This would be greater if Europeans are
prepared to pay premium prices in the market for locally produced
(and quality) food. Some farming would be profitable. How much
and where all depends on the evolution of the unsupported market,
but the world food supply/demand balance is such that production
levels would probably be close to present levels (at about 80-90%
on average) and that domestic prices would be enough to make this
level of production commercially viable and economically sustainable.
5. So what would the landscape and countryside
look like? Lowland prairies and upland ranches and ranges (or
wilderness)? Intensive feedlots and animal factories? Huge farms
with no woods and hedgerows? Massive machinery? Or wasteland,
derelict buildings and over-grown scrub? The answer would probably
include examples of all these and more. Some argue that the 1930s
depression, with large areas of British agriculture laid waste
and derelict, would be the most likely outcome. But current conditions
are very different from those of the 1930s. The rest of the economy
is rich and prosperous, and accustomed to being very well fed
with massive choice and secure supplies. Supermarkets and other
food retailers would find that they needed secure supply chains
to meet these demands, which require in turn viable suppliers
and producers. Furthermore, plenty of people would like a place
in the country. Derelict and unoccupied land is not likely to
stay that way for long, unless people really don't want to live
and play on it, rather than trying to make a living from it. People
who want a piece of the countryside will try and make sure that
it looks the way they like it. If hedges, hay meadows and stone
walls are valued, then people can be expected to find ways of
making sure that they are maintained and provided. In other words,
elimination of pillar 1 support would not repeal the basic forces
of supply and demand. These forces would operate to produce the
sorts of food, landscape and rural environment that people are
prepared to pay for, at prices which provide the producers and
their resources with a viable living. One guess would be that
the countryside would not actually end up looking very different
from its present condition. At least, we might expect this to
happen in the long run. The problem, as Keynes memorably said,
is that in the long run we are all dead.
How might we get therea practical vision?
6. A realistic vision needs to envisage
how we might minimise the difficulties of and maximise the opportunities
for such a potentially radical transition. The first and most
obvious difficulty is that elimination of support would bankrupt
a substantial fraction of the present farming businesses, perhaps
as many as 50%. These people have paid prices for the land and
capital (live and deadstock) which presumes a continuation of
support. Remove the support and capital and land values (based
on farming) collapse. The present farmers see their pension funds,
and their capacity to weather commercial difficulties or develop
their businesses, evaporate. They can be expected to make every
effort to resist such a prospectwhich provides the current
CAP support with its most resilient defence. Never mind that the
most indebted ones would probably survive quite wellbanks
are unlikely to foreclose on half or more of their farming clients
when the realisable value of their assets has just collapsed,
so they would take steps to minimise their losses, often writing
off debts and helping existing farmers stay in business (the New
Zealand experience). The farmers who would really suffer are those
without debts, whose wealth would be severely reduced (the real
point of the Defra/Treasury observations on the effects of support).
It is politically impossible, as well as being morally questionable,
to eliminate Pillar 1 without some form of compensation.
7. Compensation: The implicit
compensation offered in the "Vision" document is simply
continuation of single farm payments and other support for a finite,
limited time (10 or 15 years), presumably gradually reducing each
over this period. This is of little comfort or help to farmers.
They need a lump sum, once-and-for-all paymentto protect
their investment value and provide them with the capacity to adjust,
either by changing their business systems or by leaving and letting
someone else do it. Furthermore, they need to know what the new
unsupported market will look like as soon as possible. Gradual
change is much more likely to generate the boiling frog syndromedrop
a frog into a pot of boiling water and it will jump out; put it
in cold water and bring it slowly to the boil and the frog will
die. Sudden, but reliable change will induce rapid and viable
responses; gradual change is much more likely to produce mal-adaptations
and responses. This is even more likely when there is strong political
resistance to the changes anyway, and every effort being made
to slow them down or reverse them. Even assuming that we could
persuade the EU to agree to elimination in the first place.
8. European Level Agreement? Four
central facts strongly suggest a solution to the present European
impasse on CAP and its funding.[9]
i. Fact 1: The CAP is the only European
policy that is both mandatory and 100% funded from the EU budget.
All other policies are subject to member state contributions.
When the CAP was invented, this made sense, but not now.
ii. Fact 2: Decoupled single farm payments,
with environmental compliance, are a radical change from the traditional
CAP, with much lower social costs and market distortion. Neither
the values of environmental care, nor the costs of providing for
it, are uniform across the Unionthere is no logic other
than historical precedent requiring payments to be the same, or
that they be commonly financed. The historical legacy of mandatory
spending, exclusively financed from the EU budget, is no longer
either legitimate or sensible.
iii. Fact 3: The Central European countries,
with large farming populations and low incomes, have joined the
CAP on very unequal termstheir farmers are only paid 25%
of the payment rates to their richer and more fortunate western
cousins, though this proportion is set to rise in the future.
There is neither logic nor justice in this glaring inequity.
iv. Fact 4: The British rebate is only
justified (if at all) on the grounds that Britain contributes
a lot to EU funds (being a large economy), but gets relatively
little back through the CAP (being a densely populated and small
agricultural country). Other, less glaring, budgetary inequities
will persist so long as the EU maintains its present CAP financing
system, which absorbs 40% of an already pitifully small European
budget for the support of farmers.
9. An answer can be distilled from these
facts: let the EU budget pay only a fraction (say 25%) of
the costs of the current CAP, instead of the present 100%. Make
member states separately responsible for the balance for their
own farmers, as they so wish, up to the budgetary ceiling already
agreed. Member states would then be free to decide whether and
how to make these payments, subject to European and international
competition and trade laws and agreements, and subject to the
European freedom of movement of (farm) labour and capital. If
we wanted to provide limited lump sum compensation, we could.
How can France sustain objection? If she wants to continue the
CAP, she can (but at her own rather than our expense). Some policy
competition between member states would be a good thingto
test different options. At the very least, such a solution might
provide some relief from the otherwise destructive British political
battle about the EU, giving the UK (and other member states) more
discretion and control over their own local policies, in the true
spirit of subsidiarity.
10. But what about the environment?[10] Pastoralists,
however, complain (with some justification) that the free market
will not provide the right levels of environmental conservation.
They often argue that biodiversity, landscape quality, and environmental
amenity need government intervention, regulation and support.
Continued single farm payments, or something like them, with cross-compliance
conditions about conserving the environment and natural resource,
seem like a practical and effective way of providing the proper
level of care (conservation, amenity, recreation and environmental)
goods and services.
11. Markets for conservation, amenity, recreation
and environment (care) goods and services fail because the people
responsible for providing them (farmers) cannot get their necessary
reward from the people who are willing to pay for them (pastoralists).
The transaction and negotiation costs are too high. In addition,
many of these countryside care goods are "public" rather
than privateonce we have a pretty landscape or diverse
wildlife for one person, it is available for all, regardless of
whether or not they pay for it. We end up with less care than
we are actually prepared to pay for, because it is in peoples'
self-interest to free-ride on other peoples' contributions. An
answer is to force people to pay (through the tax system) and
for government to be responsible for the care of the countryside.
12. But this answerimplicit but not
explicit in the "Vision"misses the essential
point of the market failurethe difficulties of getting
the beneficiaries of the countryside care to put their money where
their mouths are, and of getting these payments, and their associated
care requirements and demands, to the people responsible for managing
the countryside (the farmers and land users). The care markets
don't work because the effort required is not worthwhile. But,
as we get richer, so the benefits of getting care markets to work
increase, and they do emerge. Voluntary contributions to the RSPB,
the National Trust and wildlife trusts pay land users to do the
right things with their land. But there are free riders. There
would be more and greater voluntary contributions if we could
each be sure that everyone who valued the countryside was making
their full contribution to its care and maintenance. We could
encourage this by a) allowing such voluntary contributions to
be deductible (within limits) from tax bills (rather than simply
allowable against tax); b) making ex gratia payments from the
Treasury to the care trusts to make good the free-rider shortfall
on a pro rata £ for £ basis at some centrally agreed
rate. The trusts would then be responsible for reflecting the
demands and requirements of their members directly to the land
users. Variety and diversity of demands and supplies would be
catered for through the diversity of trusts. If a trust is doing
a good job, it will be supported. If not, its donation flow will
dry up. The consumers/users/enjoyers of the countryside will be
directly connected to the people needed to provide and sustain
it.
13. The alternative of government intervention,
regulation and payments to farmers separates the people willing
to pay from the people who need payment to provide the care by
a maze of procedures, rules, forms and disinterested bystanders
and bureaucrats, which is neither effective nor efficient, and
does nothing to integrate society. It fails for the same reason
that all central planning failsit is not capable of reflecting
the real diversity of the market and it is too rigid to adapt
and adjust to changing and differing circumstances. It fails because
it fails to address the fundamental problems associated with externalities
and public goods. In the end, it threatens to undermine peoples'
faith in government itself.
CONCLUSIONS
14. The "vision" offers limited
hope of genuinely advancing debate or agreement about the future
of the CAP and its funding. This is a pity, because there is a
sensible alternative. The authors of the "vision" might
complain that the devil is in the detail. But, for the problems
of the CAP, the devil is in the conception.
15. We need to reform and develop appropriate
policies to improve the match between those trying to make a living
from and those trying to have a life in the countryside. We need
to remove the existing policies which are not helping and which
are costing more than they deliver. The reforms, however, need
to work with market forces, and not seek to replace or repeal
them. The "vision" presumes that the market will work
for food and farming, but ignores the transition, which in practice
is what much of the policy division is about. It assumes that
government intervention will continue to be necessary for the
environment and rural development, but fails to explore the sorts
of intervention that might work. 60 years ago, policy makers assumed
that government intervention was necessary to secure food supplies
and domestic farming. We are now picking up the pieces of that
assumption. We should be careful that we are not sowing the seeds
for yet another policy rescue problem in the future. At least
the alternative outlined here offers the opportunity for UK governments
to avoid the counter-productive squabbles about the role and place
of the EU in the affairs of the UK, by offering the chance of
tailoring our own policy to our own needs and circumstances.
FURTHER READING
Colman, D (ed.), 2002, Phasing out Milk Quotas
in the EU, Main Report to Defra, Scottish Executive, National
Assembly for Wales and DANI, CAFRA, University of Manchester.
http://statistics.defra.gov.uk/esg/reports/milkquota/default.asp
Chapter 9 of this report examines the practicalities of eliminating
dairy quotas in the EU, and explains the advantages and costs.
Harvey, D R, 2006, "The European Budget
and the CAP: an agenda for reform?" Point-de-vue, EuroChoices,
forthcoming. Available at: http://www.staff.ncl.ac.uk/david.harvey/DRHRootFolder/DRH_research.html
Harvey, D R, 2004, "Policy Dependency and
Reform: Economic gains versus political pains", Agricultural
Economics, 31, 265-275, which examines the difficulties of reforming
traditional farm support policies. Available at: http://www.staff.ncl.ac.uk/david.harvey/DRHRootFolder/DRH_research.html
Harvey, D R, 2003, "Agri-environmental
relationships and multi-functionality: further considerations",
The World Economy, 26 (5), 705-725, which examines single farm
payments as a means of providing countryside care, and explains
the alternative of trusts, with appropriate references, Available
at: http://www.staff.ncl.ac.uk/david.harvey/DRHRootFolder/DRH_research.html
9 These arguments are elaborated in Harvey, 2006. Back
10
These arguments are spelt out in more detail in Harvey, 2003. Back
|