Select Committee on Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Written Evidence


Memorandum submitted by the RSPCA (CAP 13)

  The RSPCA agrees with the strategy in the Vision for the Common Agricultural Policy that the CAP needs to be reformed to provide support to farmers more efficiently and be responsive to consumer demands. It also agrees that funding should shift from Pillar I to Pillar II if a future CAP is to match developments on improving animal welfare in species specific sectors. However, during the next 10 years agriculture will become more open to global competition as tariffs are reduced. Improving animal welfare standards has clear financial implications. Many studies show the theoretical consequences but there have been few actual models that show what will happen to livestock sectors once decreased support occurs. The examples used in the Vision report are not typical of what would happen if trade is liberalised and welfare standards continue to be raised. So, it is important that social factors such as animal welfare are built into the Rural development programmes in the UK and that it is accepted that the market alone cannot deliver a strong competitive agriculture system with higher animal welfare and health standards.

  1.  The RSPCA has long felt that the support systems of the CAP have not kept pace with developments to improve the welfare of farmed animals through other mechanisms such as species specific standards primarily laid down under Directives. Many of these Directives have started to phase out certain close confinement methods of farming (eg Directive 1999/74 and Regulation 2001/88 phasing out the battery cage system and the sow stall respectively and Directive 97/2 whose prohibition of the veal crate system is finally fully enacted at the end of this year.

  2.  The RSPCA agrees with the premise of the Vision for the Common Agricultural Policy that radical change is required to deliver support to farmers more efficiently and reduce the negative impact on the environment and animal welfare. In January 2006 the EU agreed its Animal Welfare Strategy which lays down for the first time where the EU sees animal welfare developing in the 2007-12 period. Defra is also considering, for the first time, an animal welfare component within the Animal Health and Welfare strategy. So there is a real opportunity to align the rural development incentives for farmers and producers with high level strategic goals and ensure that the same strategic goals built into previous ERDP programmes for the environment are now applied to improving the welfare and health of farm animals. This response looks at the main vision drivers of the Treasury paper to assess their impact on improving animal welfare under a CAP in 10-15 years timescale.

  3.  The RSPCA agrees with the position paper that agriculture should be a sustainable industry and rewarded for its outputs by the taxpayer where these are producing societal benefits that cannot be delivered in the market place. The RSPCA would include animal welfare in these benefits. The RSPCA also agrees that the industry should be producing to higher levels of animal welfare. However the two goals as set out in the paper of producing high welfare standards and being internationally competitive in all sectors without subsidy or protection are often incompatible. There is a causal relationship between raising animal welfare standards (within many instances, an explicit increase in costs) and the risk of being undermined by imports from third countries where standards maybe at a lower level. This will lead to the industry becoming uncompetitive in its own market place let alone in the export market. It is unclear how the Treasury report will ensure that this relationship will be effectively addressed.

  4.  This relationship has been acknowledged by the Commission and Member States in the WTO Doha Development Agenda (DDA) negotiations by the inclusion in the EU's negotiating mandate to seek clarification as to whether the Green Box includes payments for animal welfare. This mechanism has also been incorporated as new rural assistance measures under Regulation 8688/2005. This allocates many new animal welfare measures for inclusion in the Rural Development Programmes including paying farmers for meeting higher animal welfare standards and to adapt to demanding standards based on EU legislation.

  5.  There are a number of studies showing this relationship and its effect on competitiveness. In the egg sector, there will be an economic consequence of raising welfare standards under Directive 1999/74. Moving from the standard in 1999 this equates to a price differential of about 11p/dozen eggs moving to the enriched cage system, 15p moving to a barn multi-tier system or 36 p/dozen eggs moving to a free range system.[21] Economic research on laying hen standards in the third countries expected to export to the EU shows that standards are more intensive than the 750 cm2 space allowance per bird that will apply from 2012 in the EU. It reveals a competitive advantage from the main exporting countries. Those using a standard of 350 cm2 would have a price advantage in the trade in dried eggs of 3p before any changes in the DDA are enacted. Any agreed changes in tariff reduction will decrease the competitiveness of the EU egg industry.

  6.  Similar economic analysis has occurred in the broiler sector[22] and the pig sector.[23] In the broiler sector, where a Directive is currently being negotiated, economic analysis shows that there will be a 11% increase in cost of production from the present broiler stocking density of 38 kg live wt/2 to a reduced stocking density of 30 kg lw/m2. This equates to an annual cost to UK industry of £101 million. Even keeping the present stocking density but not allowing the practice of thinning the birds (taking out birds during the growth cycle as the maximum stocking density is reached) would cost the industry in the UK £42 million annually. In the pig sector analysis of the difference between sow production under a higher welfare scheme in Germany and the baseline standards shows a difference of £8.45 in production costs per weaner.

  7.  The market place can recoup some of these additional costs but without compulsory labelling and retailers adopting their own standards that ensure they import only products produced at baseline EU standards the market cannot reward entirely for higher welfare products. At present there is only mandatory labelling for shell eggs, and no labelling for egg products where the majority of the competition will occur from third countries. Labelling is proposed for broiler chickens under the current EU draft, but no political agreement has been reached yet.

  8.  There have not been any long term review studies on the economic consequences on a livestock industry of adjusting to lower levels of support whilst moving from a less intensive system. The four examples in the Vision paper look at the overall effect on farming but not specifically on animal welfare consequences. However in Sweden, used in the Vision paper, moves to outlaw the battery cage system which were agreed prior to Sweden joining the EU were abandoned post accession due to the fears about the effects on competitiveness against other EU Member States. In New Zealand, Australia and Canada, other examples used, moves to prohibit the battery cage system for laying hens have been rebuffed by the industry and Government on grounds of competitiveness. All three countries use laying hen systems that will be prohibited in the EU from 2012. All three countries also permit standards for use in pig production that will be phased out in the EU by 2013.

  9.  The RSPCA agrees with the Vision for agriculture that the case for continued CAP reform has been made both in terms of reducing the CAP budget and diverting the budget from Pillar I to Pillar II. However, despite agreement in the recent EU Council that the Commission will produce a paper in 2008 to prepare for a new CAP, the agreed budget for the period up to 2013 will see a 22% cut from the Pillar 2 budget, equating to a loss of some €19 billion over the budgetary period that will now not be available for rural development issues. This will have a direct effect on the four RDPs in the UK where financial constraints will mean that new issues under the RDR such as animal welfare will not necessarily get the funding required to ensure that the EU's agriculture remains competitive. For instance, although Scotland has agreed to put in three animal welfare funding streams under its current RDP, it is likely that England will not prioritise animal welfare as a funding incentive. This will not only penalise English farmers compared to Welsh and Scottish producers, it may mean impact on the competitiveness of sectors against mainland European farmers that will continue to get rural development funding to produce higher welfare products.

  10.  In Germany, the present RDP provides incentives of grants for investment costs in nine sectors (laying hens, turkeys, pigs, beef and dairy cattle, broilers, suckler cows, goats and sheep) providing certain higher welfare standards are met (eg a stocking density of 25 kg/m2 for broiler chickens as opposed to the proposed 38 kg/m2 under the draft Directive). There has not yet been a comprehensive economic analysis of the effect of these different rural development incentive programmes in the different Member States (or indeed with devolution within the Member States) on the competitiveness of different livestock sectors.

  11.  So the RSPCA agrees with the Vision that social and welfare benefits should be available to farmers on the same basis as other Member States and that Pillar II would support these objectives with a consequent reduction in Pillar I payments. However, if Member States have discretion in determining agri-environment payments it is unclear how this will also involve also precluding unfair competition between Member States.

  12.  The RSPCA welcomes the cross-compliance measures that will apply for three animal welfare laws from 2007 (the general standards for farm animals and specific ones for pigs and calves). This should ensure that a farmer can only receive a CAP payment if they are applying and meeting animal welfare legislation in these areas. The framework is there for the animal welfare pyramid incentive scheme to become a reality.


  13.  Agreement on the EU budget in December 2005 and the reduction in Pillar II budget means it is important that any incentives under the RDPs not only have win-win consequences for more than one issue but also deliver measurable goals against the national agricultural strategy. It is not clear that this is being applied in the draft RDPs in the UK.






21   The Case against Cages 2005 RSPCA, Hard boiled Reality 2001 RSPCA. Back

22   The economic consequences for the broiler industry of legislatively enforced reductions in maximum stocking density. Centre for Rrual Research, Exeter Univeristy 2005. Back

23   Effect of higher welfare standards on the costs of producing beef and pork in the EU. Bondt et al 2004 Agricultural Economics Research Institute The Hague. Back


 
previous page contents next page

House of Commons home page Parliament home page House of Lords home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2007
Prepared 24 May 2007